1
COMMITTEE PRINT REPORT
" !
117 Congress
2d Session
CP 117–8
PART I
INVESTIGATION OF COMPETITION IN
DIGITAL MARKETS
MAJORITY STAFF REPORT AND
RECOMMENDATIONS
SUBCOMMITTEE ON ANTITRUST,
COMMERCIAL, AND ADMINISTRATIVE LAW
OF THE COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY OF
THE HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
PART I
JERROLD NADLER, CHAIR, COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY
DAVID N. CICILLINE, CHAIR, SUBCOMMITTEE ON ANTITRUST,
COMMERCIAL, AND ADMINISTRATIVE LAW
ORIGINALLY RELEASED OCTOBER 2020
ADOPTED BY COMMITTEE APRIL 2021
PUBLISHED JULY 2022
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00001 Fmt 6012 Sfmt 6012 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
C:\Graphics\CONGRESS.#13
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
INVESTIGATION OF COMPETITION IN DIGITAL MARKETS
PART I
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00002 Fmt 6019 Sfmt 6019 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
U
.
S
.
GOVERNMENT PUBLISHING OFFICE
WASHINGTON
:
1
47–832
COMMITTEE PRINT REPORT
" !
117 Congress
2d Session
CP 117–8
PART I
2022
INVESTIGATION OF COMPETITION IN
DIGITAL MARKETS
MAJORITY STAFF REPORT AND
RECOMMENDATIONS
SUBCOMMITTEE ON ANTITRUST,
COMMERCIAL, AND ADMINISTRATIVE LAW
OF THE COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY OF
THE HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
PART I
JERROLD NADLER, CHAIR, COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY
DAVID N. CICILLINE, CHAIR, SUBCOMMITTEE ON ANTITRUST,
COMMERCIAL, AND ADMINISTRATIVE LAW
ORIGINALLY RELEASED OCTOBER 2020
ADOPTED BY COMMITTEE APRIL 2021
PUBLISHED JULY 2022
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00003 Fmt 5012 Sfmt 5012 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
C:\Graphics\CONGRESS.#13
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
2
MAJORITY STAFF
SUBCOMMITTEE ON ANTITRUST, COMMERCIAL,
AND ADMINISTRATIVE LAW
SLADE BOND
Chief Counsel
LINA KHAN
Counsel
PHILLIP BERENBROICK
Counsel
ANNA LENHART
Technologist
JOSEPH EHRENKRANTZ
Special Assistant
AMANDA LEWIS
Counsel on Detail
MARY HELEN WIMBERLY
Counsel on Detail
JOSEPH VAN WYE
Legislative Aide
CATHERINE LARSEN
Special Assistant
COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY
PERRY APELBAUM
Staff Director and Chief
Counsel
AARON HILLER
Deputy Chief Counsel
SHADAWN REDDICK-
SMITH
Communications
Director
JESSICA PRESLEY
Director of Digital
Strategy
MADELINE STRASSER
Chief Clerk
AMY RUTKIN
Chief of Staff
JOHN WILLIAMS
Parliamentarian
DANIEL SCHWARZ
Director of Strategic
Communications
MOH SHARMA
Director of Member
Services and Outreach
& Policy Advisor
JOHN DOTY
Senior Advisor
DAVID GREENGRASS
Senior Counsel
ARYA HARIHARAN
Deputy Chief Oversight
Counsel
MATTHEW ROBINSON
Counsel
KAYLA HAMEDI
Deputy Press Secretary
NATHAN ADAL
Legal Fellow
KARNA ADAM
Legal Fellow
WILLIAM BEKKER
Legal Fellow
KYLE BIGLEY
Legal Fellow
MICHAEL ENSEKI-
FRANK
Legal Fellow
BENJAMIN FEIS
Legal Fellow
CORY GORDON
Legal Fellow
ETHAN GURWITZ
Legal Fellow
DOMENIC POWELL
Legal Fellow
ARMAN RAMNATH
Legal Fellow
REED SHOWALTER
Legal Fellow
JO
¨
EL THOMPSON
Legal Fellow
KURT WALTERS
Legal Fellow
KRYSTALYN WEAVER
Legal Fellow
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00004 Fmt 5012 Sfmt 6602 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
(III)
CONTENTS
PART I
I. INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................. 1
A. Chairs’ Foreword ............................................................................................. 1
B. Executive Summary ........................................................................................ 4
1. Subcommittee’s Investigation ...................................................................... 4
2. Findings ........................................................................................................ 5
3. Recommendations ......................................................................................... 13
II. THE INVESTIGATION OF COMPETITION IN DIGITAL MARKETS ........ 14
A. Requests for Information and Submissions ................................................... 14
1. First-Party Requests for Information ......................................................... 14
2. Process for Obtaining Responses to First-Party Requests ........................ 18
3. Third-Party Requests for Information ........................................................ 18
4. Antitrust Agencies Requests for Information ............................................ 20
B. Hearings ........................................................................................................... 21
C. Roundtables ..................................................................................................... 23
D. Prior Investigations ........................................................................................ 24
III. BACKGROUND ................................................................................................ 27
A. Overview of Competition in Digital Markets ................................................ 27
1. The Role of Competition Online .................................................................. 27
2. Market Structure .......................................................................................... 28
3. Barriers to Entry .......................................................................................... 30
B. Effects of Platform Market Power .................................................................. 35
1. Innovation and Entrepreneurship .............................................................. 35
2. Privacy and Data Protection ....................................................................... 39
3. The Free and Diverse Press ........................................................................ 44
4. Political and Economic Liberty ................................................................... 58
IV. MARKETS INVESTIGATED ............................................................................ 61
A. Online Search .................................................................................................. 61
B. Online Commerce ............................................................................................ 68
C. Social Networks and Social Media ................................................................. 71
1. Social Networks Are Distinguishable from Social Media ......................... 73
2. Market Concentration .................................................................................. 74
D. Mobile App Stores ........................................................................................... 75
E. Mobile Operating Systems .............................................................................. 82
F. Digital Mapping ............................................................................................... 88
G. Cloud Computing ............................................................................................ 91
H. Voice Assistant ................................................................................................ 100
I. Web Browsers ................................................................................................... 105
J. Digital Advertising ........................................................................................... 107
V. DOMINANT ONLINE PLATFORMS ................................................................ 110
A. Facebook ........................................................................................................... 110
1. Overview ....................................................................................................... 110
2. Social Networking ........................................................................................ 111
3. Digital Advertising ....................................................................................... 141
B. Google ............................................................................................................... 144
1. Overview ....................................................................................................... 144
2. Search ............................................................................................................ 146
3. Digital Advertisements ................................................................................ 173
4. Android and Google Play Store ................................................................... 177
5. Chrome .......................................................................................................... 186
6. Maps .............................................................................................................. 193
7. Cloud ............................................................................................................. 205
C. Amazon ............................................................................................................. 207
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00005 Fmt 5904 Sfmt 5904 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
Page
C. Amazon—Continued
1. Overview ....................................................................................................... 207
2. Amazon.com .................................................................................................. 212
3. Fulfillment and Delivery ............................................................................. 254
4. Alexa’s Internet of Things Ecosystem ......................................................... 256
5. Amazon Web Services .................................................................................. 265
D. Apple ................................................................................................................ 277
1. Overview ....................................................................................................... 277
2. iOS and the App Store ................................................................................. 281
3. Siri Intelligent Voice Assistant ................................................................... 314
VI. RECOMMENDATIONS .................................................................................... 317
A. Restoring Competition in the Digital Economy ............................................ 318
1. Reduce Conflicts of Interest Through Structural Separations and Line
of Business Restrictions ............................................................................... 319
2. Implement Rules to Prevent Discrimination, Favoritism, and Self-
Preferencing .................................................................................................. 322
3. Promote Innovation Through Interoperability and Open Access ............. 324
4. Reduce Market Power Through Merger Presumptions ............................. 326
5. Create an Even Playing Field for the Free and Diverse Press ................ 328
6. Prohibit Abuse of Superior Bargaining Power and Require Due Proc-
ess ................................................................................................................... 329
B. Strengthening the Antitrust Laws ................................................................. 330
1. Restore the Antimonopoly Goals of the Antitrust Laws ........................... 330
2. Invigorate Merger Enforcement .................................................................. 331
3. Rehabilitate Monopolization Law ............................................................... 334
4. Additional Measures to Strengthen the Antitrust Laws ........................... 337
C. Strengthening Antitrust Enforcement ........................................................... 337
1. Congressional Oversight .............................................................................. 337
2. Agency Enforcement ..................................................................................... 339
3. Private Enforcement .................................................................................... 341
VII. APPENDIX: MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS BY DOMINANT PLAT-
FORMS ................................................................................................................. 343
A. Amazon ............................................................................................................. 344
B. Apple ................................................................................................................ 346
C. Facebook ........................................................................................................... 349
D. Google ............................................................................................................... 351
VIII. APPENDIX: ADDITIONAL VIEWS OF MEMBERS OF JUDICIARY
COMMITTEE ....................................................................................................... 357
A. The Honorable Eric Swalwell ......................................................................... 358
B. The Honorable Zoe Lofgren ............................................................................ 359
C. The Honorable Jim Jordan ............................................................................. 362
PART II
IX. APPENDIX: TRANSCRIPTS OF HEARINGS IN ‘‘ONLINE PLATFORMS
AND MARKET POWER’’ SERIES
A. Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 1: The Free and Diverse
Press .................................................................................................................. 367
B. Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 2: Innovation and Entrepre-
neurship ............................................................................................................ 589
C. Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 3: The Role of Data and
Privacy in Competition ..................................................................................... 1204
D. Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 4: Perspectives of the Anti-
trust Agencies ................................................................................................... 1419
PART III
E. Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 5: Competitors in the Digital
Economy ............................................................................................................ 1573
F. Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 6: Examining the Dominance
of Amazon, Apple, Facebook, and Google ....................................................... 1709
G. Proposals to Strengthen the Antitrust Laws and Restore Competition
Online ................................................................................................................ 2695
VerDate Sep 11 2014 17:56 Jul 05, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00006 Fmt 5904 Sfmt 5904 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
(1)
I. INTRODUCTION
A. Chairs’ Foreword
In June 2019, the Committee on the Judiciary initiated a bipar-
tisan investigation into the state of competition online, spear-
headed by the Subcommittee on Antitrust, Commercial, and Ad-
ministrative Law. As part of a top-to-bottom review of the market,
the Subcommittee examined the dominance of Amazon, Apple,
Facebook, and Google, and their business practices to determine
how their power affects our economy and our democracy. Addition-
ally, the Subcommittee performed a review of existing antitrust
laws, competition policies, and current enforcement levels to assess
whether they are adequate to address market power and anti-
competitive conduct in digital markets.
Over the course of our investigation, we collected extensive evi-
dence from these companies as well as from third parties—totaling
nearly 1.3 million documents. We held seven hearings to review the
effects of market power online—including on the free and diverse
press, innovation, and privacy—and a final hearing to examine po-
tential solutions to concerns identified during the investigation and
to inform this Report’s recommendations.
A year after initiating the investigation, we received testimony
from the Chief Executive Officers of the investigated companies:
Jeff Bezos, Tim Cook, Mark Zuckerberg, and Sundar Pichai. For
nearly six hours, we pressed for answers about their business prac-
tices, including about evidence concerning the extent to which they
have exploited, entrenched, and expanded their power over digital
markets in anticompetitive and abusive ways. Their answers were
often evasive and non-responsive, raising fresh questions about
whether they believe they are beyond the reach of democratic over-
sight.
Although these four corporations differ in important ways, study-
ing their business practices has revealed common problems. First,
each platform now serves as a gatekeeper over a key channel of
distribution. By controlling access to markets, these giants can pick
winners and losers throughout our economy. They not only wield
tremendous power, but they also abuse it by charging exorbitant
fees, imposing oppressive contract terms, and extracting valuable
data from the people and businesses that rely on them. Second,
each platform uses its gatekeeper position to maintain its market
power. By controlling the infrastructure of the digital age, they
have surveilled other businesses to identify potential rivals, and
have ultimately bought out, copied, or cut off their competitive
threats. And, finally, these firms have abused their role as inter-
mediaries to further entrench and expand their dominance. Wheth-
er through self-preferencing, predatory pricing, or exclusionary con-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00007 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
2
duct, the dominant platforms have exploited their power in order
to become even more dominant.
To put it simply, companies that once were scrappy, underdog
startups that challenged the status quo have become the kinds of
monopolies we last saw in the era of oil barons and railroad ty-
coons. Although these firms have delivered clear benefits to society,
the dominance of Amazon, Apple, Facebook, and Google has come
at a price. These firms typically run the marketplace while also
competing in it—a position that enables them to write one set of
rules for others, while they play by another, or to engage in a form
of their own private quasi regulation that is unaccountable to any-
one but themselves.
The effects of this significant and durable market power are cost-
ly. The Subcommittee’s series of hearings produced significant evi-
dence that these firms wield their dominance in ways that erode
entrepreneurship, degrade Americans’ privacy online, and under-
mine the vibrancy of the free and diverse press. The result is less
innovation, fewer choices for consumers, and a weakened democ-
racy.
Nearly a century ago, Supreme Court Justice Louis Brandeis
wrote: ‘‘We must make our choice. We may have democracy, or we
may have wealth concentrated in the hands of a few, but we cannot
have both.’’ Those words speak to us with great urgency today.
Although we do not expect that all of our Members will agree on
every finding and recommendation identified in this Report, we
firmly believe that the totality of the evidence produced during this
investigation demonstrates the pressing need for legislative action
and reform. These firms have too much power, and that power
must be reined in and subject to appropriate oversight and enforce-
ment. Our economy and democracy are at stake.
As a charter of economic liberty, the antitrust laws are the back-
bone of open and fair markets. When confronted by powerful mo-
nopolies over the past century—be it the railroad tycoons and oil
barons or Ma Bell and Microsoft—Congress has acted to ensure
that no dominant firm captures and holds undue control over our
economy or our democracy. We face similar challenges today. Con-
gress—not the courts, agencies, or private companies—enacted the
antitrust laws, and Congress must lead the path forward to mod-
ernize them for the economy of today, as well as tomorrow. Our
laws must be updated to ensure that our economy remains vibrant
and open in the digital age.
Congress must also ensure that the antitrust agencies aggres-
sively and fairly enforce the law. Over the course of the investiga-
tion, the Subcommittee uncovered evidence that the antitrust agen-
cies failed, at key occasions, to stop monopolists from rolling up
their competitors and failed to protect the American people from
abuses of monopoly power. Forceful agency action is critical.
Lastly, Congress must revive its tradition of robust oversight
over the antitrust laws and increased market concentration in our
economy. In prior Congresses, the Subcommittee routinely exam-
ined these concerns in accordance with its constitutional mandate
to conduct oversight and perform its legislative duties. As a 1950
report from the then-named Subcommittee on the Study of Monop-
oly Power described its mandate: ‘‘It is the province of this sub-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00008 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
3
1
H. R
EP
. N
O
. 82–255, at 2 (1951) (Aluminum: Report of the Subcomm. on Study of Monopoly
Power of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
committee to investigate factors which tend to eliminate competi-
tion, strengthen monopolies, injure small business, or promote
undue concentration of economic power; to ascertain the facts, and
to make recommendations based on those findings.’’
1
Similarly, the Subcommittee has followed the facts before it to
produce this Report, which is the product of a considerable evi-
dentiary and oversight record. This record includes: 1,287,997 docu-
ments and communications; testimony from 38 witnesses; a hear-
ing record that spans more than 1,800 pages; 38 submissions from
60 antitrust experts from across the political spectrum; and inter-
views with more than 240 market participants, former employees
of the investigated platforms, and other individuals totaling thou-
sands of hours. The Subcommittee has also held hearings and
roundtables with industry and government witnesses, consultations
with subject-matter experts, and a careful—and at times pains-
taking—review of large volumes of evidence provided by industry
participants and regulators.
In light of these efforts, we extend our deep gratitude to the staff
of the Subcommittee and Full Committee for their diligent work in
this regard, particularly during the COVID–19 pandemic and other
challenging circumstances over the past year.
Finally, as an institutional matter, we close by noting that the
Committee’s requests for information from agencies and any non-
public briefings were solely for the purpose of carrying out our con-
stitutionally based legislative and oversight functions. In par-
ticular, the information requested was vital to informing our as-
sessment of whether existing antitrust laws are adequate for tack-
ling current competition problems, as well as in uncovering poten-
tial reasons for under-enforcement. The Report is based on the doc-
uments and information collected during its investigation, and the
Committee fully respects the separate and independent decisional
processes employed by enforcement authorities with respect to such
matters.
Although the companies provided substantial information and
numerous documents to the Subcommittee, they declined to
produce certain critical information and crucial documents we re-
quested. The material withheld was identified by the Committee as
relevant to the investigation and included, primarily, two cat-
egories of information: (1) documents the companies claimed were
protected by common law privileges; and (2) documents that were
produced to antitrust authorities in ongoing investigations, or that
related to the subject matter of these ongoing investigations.
Institutionally, we reject any argument that the mere existence
of ongoing litigation prevents or prohibits Congress from obtaining
information relevant to its legislative and oversight prerogatives.
We strongly disagree with the assertion that any requests for such
materials and any compliance with those requests interfere with
the decisional processes in ongoing investigations. Furthermore,
while Congress is fully subject to constitutional protections, we can-
not agree that we are bound by common law privileges as asserted
by the companies. While we determined that insufficient time ex-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00009 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
4
2
Press Release, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, House Judiciary Committee Launches Bipartisan
Investigation into Competition in Digital Markets (June 3, 2019), https://judiciary.house.gov/
news/press-releases/house-judiciary-committee-launches-bipartisan-investigation-competition-
digital.
3
We extend our sincere thanks to Peter Karafotas, Rich Luchette, and Francis Grubar, in
the Office of Congressman David N. Cicilline, for their relentless work and selfless devotion
throughout the investigation. We would also like to recognize the following staff for their signifi-
cant contributions during the investigation: Dick Meltzer, Michael Tecklenburg, Kenneth
DeGraff, and Victoria Houed in the Office of the Speaker of the U.S. House of Representatives;
Daniel Flores, former Minority Chief Counsel, Subcommittee on Antitrust, Commercial, and Ad-
ministrative Law; Danny Johnson, former Minority Counsel, Committee on the Judiciary; Jacqui
Kappler, Legislative Director, the Honorable Henry ‘‘Hank’’ Johnson, Jr.; Devon Ombres, Legis-
lative Counsel, the Honorable Jamie Raskin; Elly Kugler, Senior Counsel, the Honorable
Pramila Jayapal; Jennifer Chan, Legislative Director, the Honorable Pramila Jayapal; Stuart
Styron, Senior Legislative Assistant, the Honorable Val Demings; Keanu Rivera, Legislative As-
sistant, the Honorable Mary Gay Scanlon; Lindsey Garber, Legislative Counsel, the Honorable
Joe Neguse; Miya Patel, former Legislative Assistant, the Honorable Joe Neguse; and Natalie
Knight, Legislative Counsel, the Honorable Lucy McBath. Staff would also like to thank Mat-
thew Bisenius in the Office of Congressman F. James Sensenbrenner, as well as Garrett Ventry
in the Office of Congressman Ken Buck, for their commitment to bipartisan cooperation. We also
thank Hillary Marston, Legal Intern for the Committee on the Judiciary, for her assistance. Fi-
nally, we thank Clare Cho and Mari Lee at the Congressional Research Service for their sup-
port, as well as graphics and data visualization used within this Report.
4
Press Release, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, House Judiciary Committee Launches Bipartisan
Investigation into Competition in Digital Markets (June 3, 2019), https://judiciary.house.gov/
news/press-releases/house-judiciary-committee-launches-bipartisan-investigation-competition-
digital.
5
See, e.g., Meehreen Khan, EU Targets Tech Giants over Unfair Business Practices, F
IN
.
T
IMES
(Apr. 25, 2018), https://www.ft.com/content/d7228bec-4879-11e8-8ee8-cae73aab7ccb;
Adam Satariano, Google Is Fined $57 Million Under Europe’s Data Privacy Law, N.Y. T
IMES
(Jan. 21, 2019), https://www.nytimes.com/2019/01/21/technology/google-europe-gdpr-fine.
html; Richard Waters et al., Global Regulators’ Net Tightens Around Big Tech, F
IN
. T
IMES
(June
5, 2019), https://www.ft.com/content/973f8b36-86f0-11e9-97ea-05ac2431f453.
ists to pursue these additional materials during this Congress, the
Committee expressly reserves the right to invoke other available
options, including compulsory process, to obtain the requested in-
formation in the future.
B. Executive Summary
1. Subcommittee’s Investigation
On June 3, 2019, the House Judiciary Committee announced a
bipartisan investigation into competition in digital markets,
2
led by
the Subcommittee on Antitrust, Commercial, and Administrative
Law.
3
The purpose of the investigation was to: (1) document com-
petition problems in digital markets; (2) examine whether domi-
nant firms are engaging in anticompetitive conduct; and (3) assess
whether existing antitrust laws, competition policies, and current
enforcement levels are adequate to address these issues.
4
The Com-
mittee initiated the investigation in response to broad-ranging in-
vestigative reporting, and activity by policymakers and enforcers,
that raised serious concerns about the platforms’ incentives and
ability to harm the competitive process.
5
As part of the investigation, the Subcommittee held seven over-
sight hearings that provided Members of the Subcommittee with an
opportunity to examine the state of competition in digital markets
and the adequacy of existing antitrust laws. A diverse group of wit-
nesses offered testimony on topics related to the effects of market
power on the free and diverse press, on innovation, and on privacy.
Other witnesses who testified included executives from businesses
with concerns about the dominance of the investigated firms. The
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00010 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
5
hearings also provided an opportunity for key executives from
Facebook, Google, Amazon, and Apple—including the Chief Execu-
tive Officers of these firms—to address evidence that was uncov-
ered during the investigation in a public-facing venue. After each
of the hearings, Members of the Subcommittee submitted questions
for the record (QFRs) to the witnesses.
The Committee requested information from the dominant plat-
forms, from market participants, from the Federal antitrust agen-
cies, and from other relevant parties, for the purpose of obtaining
information that was not otherwise publicly available but was im-
portant to assembling a comprehensive record. The Committee also
sent requests for submissions to various experts in the field, includ-
ing academics, representatives of public interest groups, and prac-
ticing antitrust lawyers. The responses to these requests were in-
dispensable to staff’s ability to complete this Report and its rec-
ommendations for congressional oversight of the antitrust agencies
and legislative action.
This Report is intended to provide policymakers, antitrust enforc-
ers, market participants, and the public with a comprehensive un-
derstanding of the state of competition in the online marketplace.
The Report also provides recommendations for areas of legislative
activity to address the rise and abuse of market power in the dig-
ital economy, as well as areas that warrant additional congres-
sional attention.
2. Findings
(a) Overview. The open internet has delivered significant benefits
to Americans and the U.S. economy. Over the past few decades, it
has created a surge of economic opportunity, capital investment,
and pathways for education. The COVID–19 pandemic has under-
scored the importance of internet access that is affordable, competi-
tive, and widely available for workers, families, and businesses.
The online platforms investigated by the Subcommittee—Ama-
zon, Apple, Facebook, and Google—also play an important role in
our economy and society as the underlying infrastructure for the
exchange of communications, information, and goods and services.
As of September 2020, the combined valuation of these platforms
is more than $5 trillion—more than a third of the value of the S&P
100. As we continue to shift our work, commerce, and communica-
tions online, these firms stand to become even more interwoven
into the fabric of our economy and our lives.
Over the past decade, the digital economy has become highly con-
centrated and prone to monopolization. Several markets inves-
tigated by the Subcommittee—such as social networking, general
online search, and online advertising—are dominated by just one
or two firms. The companies investigated by the Subcommittee—
Amazon, Apple, Facebook, and Google—have captured control over
key channels of distribution and have come to function as gate-
keepers. Just a decade into the future, 30 percent of the world’s
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00011 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
6
6
Catherine Fong et al., Prime Day and the Broad Reach of Amazon’s Ecosystem, M
C
K
INSEY
&
C
O
. (Aug. 2, 2019), https://www.mckinsey.com/business-functions/marketing-and-sales/our-
insights/prime-day-and-the-broad-reach-of-amazons-ecosystem (‘‘This ecosystem strategy in par-
ticular has significant competitive implications because McKinsey estimates that in ten years,
30 percent of the world’s gross economic output will be from companies that operate a network
of interconnected businesses, such as those run by Amazon, Alibaba, Google, and Facebook.’’).
7
Colleen Cunningham, Florian Ederer & Song Ma, Killer Acquisitions 1 (Yale Sch. of Mgmt.,
Working Paper, Mar. 2019), https://perma.cc/L6YL-YL8K (describing the practice of
‘‘acquir[ing] innovative targets solely to discontinue the target’s innovative projects and preempt
future competition’’). See also C. Scott Hemphill & Tim Wu, Nascent Competitors, 168 U. P
A
.
L. R
EV
. 1879, 1880 (2020), https://perma.cc/62HH-34ZL (‘‘A nascent competitor is a firm whose
prospective innovation represents a serious future threat to an incumbent.’’).
8
See infra Section V.
gross economic output may lie with these firms, and just a handful
of others.
6
In interviews with the Subcommittee, numerous businesses de-
scribed how dominant platforms exploit their gatekeeper power to
dictate terms and extract concessions that no one would reasonably
consent to in a competitive market. Market participants indicated
that their dependence on these gatekeepers to access users and
markets requires concessions and demands that carry significant
economic harm, but that are ‘‘the cost of doing business’’ given the
lack of options.
This significant and durable market power is due to several fac-
tors, including a high volume of acquisitions by the dominant plat-
forms. Together, the firms investigated by the Subcommittee have
acquired hundreds of companies just in the last ten years. In some
cases, a dominant firm evidently acquired nascent or potential com-
petitors to neutralize a competitive threat or to maintain and ex-
pand the firm’s dominance. In other cases, a dominant firm ac-
quired smaller companies to shut them down or discontinue under-
lying products entirely—transactions aptly described as ‘‘killer ac-
quisitions.’’
7
In the overwhelming number of cases, the antitrust agencies did
not request additional information and documentary material
under their pre-merger review authority in the Clayton Act to ex-
amine whether the proposed acquisition may substantially lessen
competition or tend to create a monopoly if allowed to proceed as
proposed. For example, of Facebook’s nearly 100 acquisitions, the
Federal Trade Commission (FTC) engaged in an extensive inves-
tigation of just one acquisition: Facebook’s purchase of Instagram
in 2012.
During the investigation, the Subcommittee found evidence of
monopolization and monopoly power. For example, the strong net-
work effects associated with Facebook has tipped the market to-
ward monopoly such that Facebook competes more vigorously
among its own products—Facebook, Instagram, WhatsApp, and
Messenger—than with actual competitors.
As demonstrated during a series of hearings held by the Sub-
committee and as detailed in this Report,
8
the online platforms’
dominance carries significant costs. It has diminished consumer
choice, eroded innovation and entrepreneurship in the U.S. econ-
omy, weakened the vibrancy of the free and diverse press, and un-
dermined Americans’ privacy.
These concerns are shared by the majority of Americans. On Sep-
tember 24, 2020, Consumer Reports (CR) published a survey titled
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00012 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
7
9
C
ONSUMER
. R
EPS
., P
LATFORM
P
ERCEPTIONS
: C
ONSUMER
A
TTITUDES ON
C
OMPETITION AND
F
AIRNESS IN
O
NLINE
P
LATFORMS
(2020), https://advocacy.consumerreports.org/wp-content/
uploads/2020/09/FINAL-CR-survey-report.platform-perceptions-consumer-attitudes-.september-
2020.pdf.
10
Id.
11
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00045388 (Feb.
18, 2014), https://judiciary.house.gov/uploadedfiles/0004538800045389.pdf (‘‘[W]e are going to
spend 5–10% of our market cap every couple years to shore up our position . . . I hate the word
‘land grab’ but I think that is the best convincing argument and we should own that.’’).
12
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00067600 (Apr. 9, 2012), https://judiciary.house.gov/uploadedfiles/
0006760000067601.pdf.
13
Id.
14
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00049006 (Apr. 18, 2012) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Network effects
make it very difficult to compete with us—In every country we’ve tipped we are still winning.’’).
15
Id.
16
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00111406 (Oct. 2018) [hereinafter Cunningham Memo] (‘‘Facebook
has high reach and time-spent in most countries. User growth is tracking internet growth: glob-
al reach is roughly stable.’’).
17
Id.
18
Id. at 11.
‘‘Platform Perceptions: Consumer Attitudes on Competition and
Fairness in Online Platforms.’’
9
Among its findings:
Eighty-five percent of Americans are concerned—either very concerned or
somewhat concerned—about the amount of data online platforms store about
them, and eighty-one percent are concerned that platforms are collecting and
holding this data in order to build out more comprehensive consumer profiles.
Fifty-eight percent are not confident that they are getting objective and unbi-
ased search results when using an online platform to shop or search for infor-
mation.
Seventy-nine percent say Big Tech mergers and acquisitions unfairly under-
mine competition and consumer choice.
10
Sixty percent support more government regulation of online platforms, includ-
ing mandatory interoperability features, to make it easier for users to switch
from one platform to another without losing important data or connections.
(b) Facebook. Facebook has monopoly power in the market for so-
cial networking. Internal communications among the company’s
Chief Executive Officer, Mark Zuckerberg, and other senior execu-
tives indicate that Facebook acquired its competitive threats to
maintain and expand its dominance. For example, a senior execu-
tive at the company described its acquisition strategy as a ‘‘land
grab’’ to ‘‘shore up’’ Facebook’s position,
11
while Facebook’s CEO
said that Facebook ‘‘can likely always just buy any competitive
startups,’’
12
and agreed with one of the company’s senior engineers
that Instagram was a threat to Facebook.
13
Facebook’s monopoly power is firmly entrenched and unlikely to
be eroded by competitive pressure from new entrants or existing
firms. In 2012, the company described its network effects as a
‘‘flywheel’’ in an internal presentation prepared for Facebook at the
direction of its Chief Financial Officer.
14
This presentation also
said that Facebook’s network effects get ‘‘stronger every day.’’
15
More recent documents produced during the investigation by
Facebook show that it has tipped the social networking market to-
ward a monopoly, and now considers competition within its own
family of products to be more considerable than competition from
any other firm. These documents include an October 2018 memo-
randum by Thomas Cunningham, a senior data scientist and econo-
mist at Facebook,
16
for Mr. Zuckerberg and Javier Olivan,
Facebook’s Director of Growth.
17
Among other things, the
Cunningham Memo found that the network effects of Facebook and
its family of products as ‘‘very strong’’
18
and that there are strong
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00013 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
8
19
Id. at 9.
20
Id.
21
Interview with Former Instagram Employee (Oct. 2, 2020).
tipping points in the social networking market that create competi-
tion for the market, rather than competition within the market.
19
According to a former senior employee at Instagram who was in-
volved in the preparation of this document for review by Mr.
Zuckerberg and Mr. Olivan, the Cunningham Memo guided
Facebook’s growth strategy, particularly with regard to Insta-
gram.
20
They explained:
The question was how do we position Facebook and Instagram to not compete
with each other. The concern was that Instagram would hit a tipping point ....
There was brutal in-fighting between Instagram and Facebook at the time. It
was very tense. It was back when Kevin Systrom was still at the company. He
wanted Instagram to grow naturally and as widely as possible. But Mark was
clearly saying ‘‘do not compete with us.’’ . . . It was collusion, but within an inter-
nal monopoly. If you own two social media utilities, they should not be allowed
to shore each other up. It’s unclear to me why this should not be illegal. You
can collude by acquiring a company.
21
Facebook has also maintained its monopoly through a series of
anticompetitive business practices. The company used its data ad-
vantage to create superior market intelligence to identify nascent
competitive threats and then acquire, copy, or kill these firms.
Once dominant, Facebook selectively enforced its platform policies
based on whether it perceived other companies as competitive
threats. In doing so, it advantaged its own services while weak-
ening other firms.
In the absence of competition, Facebook’s quality has deterio-
rated over time, resulting in worse privacy protections for its users
and a dramatic rise in misinformation on its platform.
(c) Google. Google has a monopoly in the markets for general on-
line search and search advertising. Google’s dominance is protected
by high entry barriers, including its click-and-query data and the
extensive default positions that Google has obtained across most of
the world’s devices and browsers. A significant number of entities—
spanning major public corporations, small businesses, and entre-
preneurs—depend on Google for traffic, and no alternate search en-
gine serves as a substitute.
Google maintained its monopoly over general search through a
series of anticompetitive tactics. These include an aggressive cam-
paign to undermine vertical search providers, which Google viewed
as a significant threat. Documents show that Google used its
search monopoly to misappropriate content from third parties and
to boost Google’s own inferior vertical offerings, while imposing
search penalties to demote third-party vertical providers. Since
capturing a monopoly over general search, Google has steadily pro-
liferated its search results page with ads and with Google’s own
content, while also blurring the distinction between paid ads and
organic results. As a result of these tactics, Google appears to be
siphoning off traffic from the rest of the web, while entities seeking
to reach users must pay Google steadily increasing sums for ads.
Numerous market participants analogized Google to a gatekeeper
that is extorting users for access to its critical distribution channel,
even as its search page shows users less relevant results.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00014 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
9
A second way Google has maintained its monopoly over general
search has been through a series of anticompetitive contracts. After
purchasing the Android operating system in 2005, Google used con-
tractual restrictions and exclusivity provisions to extend Google’s
search monopoly from desktop to mobile. Documents show that
Google required smartphone manufacturers to pre-install and give
default status to Google’s own apps, impeding competitors in search
as well as in other app markets. As search activity now migrates
from mobile to voice, third-party interviews suggest Google is again
looking for ways to maintain its monopoly over search access points
through a similar set of practices.
Since capturing the market for online search, Google has ex-
tended into a variety of other lines of business. Today, Google is
ubiquitous across the digital economy, serving as the infrastructure
for core products and services online. Through Chrome, Google now
owns the world’s most popular browser—a critical gateway to the
internet that it has used to both protect and promote its other lines
of business. Through Google Maps, Google now captures over eight
percent of the market for navigation mapping services—a key input
over which Google consolidated control through an anticompetitive
acquisition and which it now leverages to advance its position in
search and advertising. And through Google Cloud, Google has an-
other core platform in which it is now heavily investing through ac-
quisitions, positioning itself to dominate the ‘‘Internet of Things,’’
the next wave of surveillance technologies.
Internal communications also reveal that Google exploits infor-
mation asymmetries and closely tracks real-time data across mar-
kets, which—given Google’s scale—provide it with near-perfect
market intelligence. In certain instances, Google has covertly set
up programs to more closely track its potential and actual competi-
tors, including through projects like Android Lockbox.
Each of its services provides Google with a trove of user data, re-
inforcing its dominance across markets and driving greater mone-
tization through online ads. Through linking these services to-
gether, Google increasingly functions as an ecosystem of inter-
locking monopolies.
(d) Amazon. Amazon has significant and durable market power
in the U.S. online retail market. This conclusion is based on the
significant record that the Subcommittee collected and reviewed,
including testimonials from third-party sellers, brand manufactur-
ers, publishers, former employees, and other market participants,
as well as Amazon’s internal documents. Although Amazon is fre-
quently described as controlling about forty percent of U.S. online
retail sales, this market share is likely understated, and estimates
of about 50 percent or higher are more credible.
As the dominant marketplace in the United States for online
shopping, Amazon’s market power is at its height in its dealings
with third-party sellers. The platform has monopoly power over
many small- and medium-sized businesses that do not have a via-
ble alternative to Amazon for reaching online consumers. Amazon
has 2.3 million active third-party sellers on its marketplace world-
wide, and a recent survey estimates that about 37 percent of
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00015 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
10
22
J
UNGLE
S
COUT
, T
HE
S
TATE OF THE
A
MAZON
S
ELLER
2020, at 4 (2020), https://www.
junglescout.com/wp-content/uploads/2020/02/State-of-the-Seller-Survey.pdf.
them—about 850,000 sellers—rely on Amazon as their sole source
of income.
22
Amazon achieved its current dominant position, in part, through
acquiring its competitors, including Diapers.com and Zappos. It has
also acquired companies that operate in adjacent markets, adding
customer data to its stockpile and further shoring up its competi-
tive moats. This strategy has entrenched and expanded Amazon’s
market power in e-commerce, as well as in other markets. The
company’s control over and reach across its many business lines
enable it to self-preference and disadvantage competitors in ways
that undermine free and fair competition. As a result of Amazon’s
dominance, other businesses are frequently beholden to Amazon for
their success.
Amazon has engaged in extensive anticompetitive conduct in its
treatment of third-party sellers. Publicly, Amazon describes third-
party sellers as ‘‘partners.’’ But internal documents show that, be-
hind closed doors, the company refers to them as ‘‘internal competi-
tors.’’ Amazon’s dual role as an operator of its marketplace that
hosts third-party sellers, and a seller in that same marketplace,
creates an inherent conflict of interest. This conflict incentivizes
Amazon to exploit its access to competing sellers’ data and informa-
tion, among other anticompetitive conduct.
Voice assistant ecosystems are an emerging market with a high
propensity for lock-in and self-preferencing. Amazon has expanded
Alexa’s ecosystem quickly through acquisitions of complementary
and competing technologies, and by selling its Alexa-enabled smart
speakers at deep discounts. The company’s early leadership in this
market is leading to the collection of highly sensitive consumer
data, which Amazon can use to promote its other business, includ-
ing e-commerce and Prime Video.
Finally, Amazon Web Services (AWS) provides critical infrastruc-
ture for many businesses with which Amazon competes. This cre-
ates the potential for a conflict of interest where cloud customers
are forced to consider patronizing a competitor, as opposed to se-
lecting the best technology for their business.
(e) Apple. Apple has significant and durable market power in the
mobile operating system market. Apple’s dominance in this market,
where it controls the iOS mobile operating system that runs on
Apple mobile devices, has enabled it to control all software dis-
tribution to iOS devices. As a result, Apple exerts monopoly power
in the mobile app store market, controlling access to more than 100
million iPhones and iPads in the U.S.
Apple’s mobile ecosystem has produced significant benefits to app
developers and consumers. Launched in 2008, the App Store revo-
lutionized software distribution on mobile devices, reducing bar-
riers to entry for app developers and increasing the choices avail-
able to consumers. Despite this, Apple leverages its control of iOS
and the App Store to create and enforce barriers to competition and
discriminate against and exclude rivals while preferencing its own
offerings. Apple also uses its power to exploit app developers
through misappropriation of competitively sensitive information
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00016 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
11
23
Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 1: The Free and Diverse Press: Hearing Before
the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
116th Cong. 71–73 (2019) [hereinafter Free and Diverse Press Hearing] (statement of David
Pitofsky, Gen. Couns., News Corp).
24
Submission from Source 53, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 7 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.). Although Apple News and Apple News Plus are increasingly popular news aggregators,
most market participants that the Subcommittee received evidence from during the investiga-
tion do not view it as a critical intermediary for online news at this time. Some publishers
raised competition concerns about the tying of payment inside Apple’s news product. Others,
however, did raise concerns about Apple News and Apple News Plus, noting that it is ‘‘not cre-
ating any original journalism itself’’ and competes ‘‘against publishers’ news products . . . for sub-
scription revenues.’’ Id. at 6.
25
Submission from Source 52, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 12 (Oct. 30, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
26
Free and Diverse Press Hearing at 20 (statement of David Chavern, President & CEO,
News Media All.) (‘‘In effect, a couple of dominant tech platforms are acting as regulators of
the digital news industry.’’).
27
Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 2: Innovation and Entrepreneurship: Hearing Be-
fore the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
116th Cong. 76 (2019) [hereinafter Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing] (statement of
Timothy Wu, Julius Silver Prof. of Law, Columbia Law Sch.); Online Platforms and Market
Power, Part 3: The of Role of Data and Privacy in Competition: Hearing Before the Subcomm.
on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 116th Cong. 58–
Continued
and to charge app developers supra-competitive prices within the
App Store. Apple has maintained its dominance due to the pres-
ence of network effects, high barriers to entry, and high switching
costs in the mobile operating system market.
Apple is primarily a hardware company that derives most of its
revenue from sales of devices and accessories. However, as the
market for products like the iPhone has matured, Apple has
pivoted to rely increasingly on sales of its applications and services,
as well as collecting commissions and fees in the App Store. In the
absence of competition, Apple’s monopoly power over software dis-
tribution to iOS devices has resulted in harm to competitors and
competition, reducing quality and innovation among app devel-
opers, and increasing prices and reducing choices for consumers.
(f) Effects of Market Power. The Subcommittee also examined the
effects of market power in digital markets on the free and diverse
press, innovation, privacy and data, and other relevant matters
summarized below for ease of reference.
As part of this process, the Subcommittee received testimony and
submissions showing that the dominance of some online platforms
has contributed to the decline of trustworthy sources of news,
which are essential to our democracy.
23
In several submissions,
news publishers raised concerns about the ‘‘significant and growing
asymmetry of power’’ between dominant platforms and news orga-
nizations, as well as the effect of this dominance on the production
and availability of trustworthy sources of news. Other publishers
said that they are ‘‘increasingly beholden’’ to these firms, and in
particular, to Google and Facebook.
24
Google and Facebook have an
outsized influence over the distribution and monetization of trust-
worthy sources of news online,
25
undermining the quality and
availability of high-quality sources of journalism.
26
This concern is
underscored by the COVID–19 pandemic, which has laid bare the
importance of preserving a vibrant free press in both local and na-
tional markets.
The rise of market power online has also materially weakened in-
novation and entrepreneurship in the U.S. economy.
27
Some ven-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00017 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
12
60 (2019) [hereinafter Data and Privacy Hearing] (statement of Jason Furman, Prof. of the Prac.
of Econ. Pol’y, Harvard Kennedy Sch.).
28
Raghuram Rajan, Sai Krishna Kamepalli & Luigi Zingales, Kill Zone (Univ. of Chi., Becker
Friedman Inst. for Econ., Working Paper No. 2020–19, Apr. 2020), https://ssrn.com/abstract
=3555915.
29
See generally U.S. Dep’t of Justice Antitrust Div., Public Workshop on Venture Capital and
Antitrust (Feb. 12, 2020) [hereinafter Venture Capital and Antitrust Workshop], https://
www.justice.gov/atr/page/file/1255851/download; C
HI
. B
OOTH
S
TIGLER
C
TR
.
FOR THE
S
TUDY
OF
E
CON
.
&
S
TATE
, S
TIGLER
C
MTE
.
ON
D
IG
. P
LATFORMS
, F
INAL
R
EPORT
, 9 (2019) [herein-
after Stigler Report], https://www.chicagobooth.edu/-/media/research/stigler/pdfs/digital-
platforms---committee-report---stigler-center.pdf.
30
See Interview with Source 146 (May 28, 2020).
31
Howard A. Shelanski, Information, Innovation, and Competition Policy for the Internet, 161
U. P
A
. L. R
EV
. 1663, 1689 (2013) (‘‘One measure of a platform’s market power is the extent to
which it can engage in [privacy exploitation] without some benefit to consumers that offsets
their reduced privacy and still retain users.’’).
32
Data and Privacy Hearing at 60 (statement of Jason Furman, Prof. of the Prac. of Econ.
Pol’y, Harvard Kennedy Sch.); Data and Privacy Hearing at 54–55 (statement of Tommaso
Valletti, Prof. of Econ., Imperial Coll. Bus. Sch.)
33
D
IG
. C
OMPETITION
E
XPERT
P
ANEL
, U
NLOCKING
D
IGITAL
C
OMPETITION
43 (2019) (‘‘[T]he mis-
use of consumer data and harm to privacy is arguably an indicator of low quality caused by
a lack of competition.’’) [hereinafter Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report]; Dina Srinivasan,
The Antitrust Case Against Facebook: A Monopolist’s Journey Towards Pervasive Surveillance
in Spite of Consumers’ Preference for Privacy, 16 B
ERKELEY
B
US
. L.J. 39, 88 (2019) (‘‘Consumers
effectively face a singular choice—use Facebook and submit to the quality and stipulations of
Facebook’s product or forgo all use of the only social network.’’).
ture capitalists, for example, report that there is an innovation ‘‘kill
zone’’ that insulates dominant platforms from competitive pressure
simply because investors do not view new entrants as worthwhile
investments.
28
Other investors have said that they avoid funding
entrepreneurs and other companies that compete directly or indi-
rectly with dominant firms in the digital economy.
29
In an inter-
view with the Subcommittee, a prominent venture capital investor
explained that due to these factors, there is a strong economic in-
centive for other firms to avoid head-on competition with dominant
firms.
30
Additionally, in the absence of adequate privacy guardrails in the
United States, the persistent collection and misuse of consumer
data is an indicator of market power online.
31
Online platforms
rarely charge consumers a monetary price—products appear to be
‘‘free’’ but are monetized through people’s attention or with their
data.
32
In the absence of genuine competitive threats, dominant
firms offer fewer privacy protections than they otherwise would,
and the quality of these services has deteriorated over time. As a
result, consumers are forced to either use a service with poor pri-
vacy safeguards or forgo the service altogether.
33
Finally, the market power of the dominant platforms risks un-
dermining both political and economic liberties. The Subcommittee
encountered a prevalence of fear among market participants that
depend on the dominant platforms, many of whom expressed
unease that the success of their business and their economic liveli-
hood depend on what they viewed as the platforms’ unaccountable
and arbitrary power. Additionally, courts and enforcers have found
the dominant platforms to engage in recidivism, repeatedly vio-
lating laws and court orders. This pattern of behavior raises ques-
tions about whether these firms view themselves as above the law,
or whether they simply treat lawbreaking as a cost of business.
Lastly, the growth in the platforms’ market power has coincided
with an increase in their influence over the policymaking process.
Through a combination of direct lobbying and funding think tanks
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00018 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
13
34
Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of
the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Keynote Address at American Antitrust Institute’s 20th Annual
Policy Conference (June 20, 2019), https://cicilline.house.gov/press-release/cicilline-delivers-
keynote-address-american-antitrust-institute%E2%80%99s-20th-annual-policy.
and academics, the dominant platforms have expanded their sphere
of influence, further shaping how they are governed and regulated.
3. Recommendations
As part of the investigation of competition in digital markets, the
Subcommittee conducted a thorough examination of the adequacy
of current laws and enforcement levels. This included receiving
submissions from experts on antitrust and competition policy who
were selected on a careful, bipartisan basis to ensure the represen-
tation of a diverse range of views on these matters. The Sub-
committee also received other submissions from leading experts—
including Executive Vice President Margrethe Vestager of the Eu-
ropean Commission and Chair Rod Sims of the Australian Com-
petition and Consumer Commission—to inform this inquiry. Most
recently, on October 1, 2020, the Subcommittee held an oversight
hearing on ‘‘Proposals to Strengthen the Antitrust Laws and Re-
store Competition Online’’ to examine potential solutions to con-
cerns identified during the investigation to further inform the Re-
port’s recommendations.
Based on this oversight activity, Subcommittee Chair Cicilline re-
quested that staff provide a menu of reforms to Members of the
Subcommittee for purposes of potential legislative activity during
the remainder of the 116th Congress and thereafter. As he noted
in remarks to the American Antitrust Institute in June 2019:
[I]t is Congress’ responsibility to conduct oversight of our antitrust laws and
competition system to ensure that they are properly working and to enact
changes when they are not. While I do not have any preconceived ideas about
what the right answer is, as Chair of the Antitrust Subcommittee, I intend to
carry out that responsibility with the sense of urgency and serious deliberation
that it demands.
34
In response to this request, the Subcommittee identified a broad
set of reforms for further examination by the Members of the Sub-
committee for purposes of crafting legislative responses to the find-
ings of this Report. These reforms include proposals to: (1) address
anticompetitive conduct in digital markets; (2) strengthen merger
and monopolization enforcement; and (3) improve the sound admin-
istration of the antitrust laws through other reforms. We intend
these recommendations to serve as a complement to vigorous anti-
trust enforcement. Consistent with the views expressed by Chair
Nadler and Subcommittee Chair Cicilline in the Foreword to this
Report, we view these recommendations as complements, and not
substitutes, to forceful antitrust enforcement.
For ease of reference, these recommendations for further exam-
ination are summarized below.
(a) Restoring Competition in the Digital Economy
Structural separations and prohibitions of certain dominant platforms from op-
erating in adjacent lines of business;
Nondiscrimination requirements, prohibiting dominant platforms from engag-
ing in self-preferencing, and requiring them to offer equal terms for equal
products and services;
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00019 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
14
35
In 2015, Google reorganized under a new name and parent company, Alphabet, separated
various businesses, and placed Sundar Pichai as chief executive of Google. Larry Page, Chief
Executive of Google, became head of Alphabet with Sergey Brin. See Conor Dougherty, Google
to Reorganize as Alphabet to Keep Its Lead as an Innovator, N.Y. T
IMES
(Aug. 10, 2015), https://
www.nytimes.com/2015/08/11/technology/google-alphabet-restructuring.html.
Interoperability and data portability, requiring dominant platforms to make
their services compatible with various networks and to make content and in-
formation easily portable between them;
Presumptive prohibition against future mergers and acquisitions by the domi-
nant platforms;
Safe harbor for news publishers in order to safeguard a free and diverse press;
and
Prohibitions on abuses of superior bargaining power, proscribing dominant
platforms from engaging in contracting practices that derive from their domi-
nant market position, and requirement of due process protections for individ-
uals and businesses dependent on the dominant platforms.
(b) Strengthening the Antitrust Laws
Reasserting the anti-monopoly goals of the antitrust laws and their centrality
to ensuring a healthy and vibrant democracy;
Strengthening Section 7 of the Clayton Act, including through restoring pre-
sumptions and bright-line rules, restoring the incipiency standard and pro-
tecting nascent competitors, and strengthening the law on vertical mergers;
Strengthening Section 2 of the Sherman Act, including by introducing a prohi-
bition on abuse of dominance and clarifying prohibitions on monopoly
leveraging, predatory pricing, denial of essential facilities, refusals to deal,
tying, and anticompetitive self-preferencing and product design; and
Taking additional measures to strengthen overall enforcement, including
through overriding problematic precedents in the case law.
(c) Reviving Antitrust Enforcement
Restoring robust congressional oversight of the antitrust laws and their en-
forcement;
Restoring the federal antitrust agencies to full strength, by triggering civil
penalties and other relief for ‘‘unfair methods of competition’’ rules, requiring
the Federal Trade Commission to engage in regular data collection on con-
centration, enhancing public transparency and accountability of the agencies,
requiring regular merger retrospectives, codifying stricter prohibitions on the
revolving door, and increasing the budgets of the FTC and the Antitrust Divi-
sion of the U.S. Department of Justice (DOJ); and
Strengthening private enforcement through elimination of obstacles such as
forced arbitration clauses, limits on class action formation, judicially created
standards constraining what constitutes an antitrust injury, and unduly high
pleading standards.
II. THE INVESTIGATION OF
COMPETITION IN DIGITAL MARKETS
A. Requests for Information and Submissions
1. First-Party Requests for Information
On September 13, 2019, the Committee sent bipartisan requests
for information (RFIs) to each of the four investigated platforms:
Alphabet,
35
Amazon, Apple, and Facebook. For each company, the
RFI asked for a comprehensive set of information about each of the
company’s products and services. In addition, the RFI asked the
company to submit communications among high-level executives
relating to various potentially anticompetitive acquisitions and con-
duct. The Committee requested that the platforms respond to the
RFIs by October 14, 2019.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00020 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
15
36
Letter from Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Doug Collins,
Ranking Member, H. Comm on the Judiciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Anti-
trust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James Sensen-
brenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.
Comm. on the Judiciary to Larry Page, CEO, Alphabet Inc. (Sept. 13, 2019) [hereinafter Com-
mittee Request for Information, Alphabet], https://judiciary.house.gov/sites/democrats
.judiciary.house.gov/files/documents/alphabet%20inc.%20rfi%20-%20signed%20(003).pdf.
37
Id. at 1–4.
38
The Alphabet RFI defines the term ‘‘Relevant Executives’’ as Larry Page, Sergey Brin, Ruth
Porat, David Drummond, Eric Schmidt, Sundar Pichai, Susan Wojcicki, Philipp Schindler,
Prabhakar Raghavan, Thomas Kurian, Hiroshi Lockheimer, Rishi Chandra, Keith Enright, and
Kent Walker. See id. at 4.
39
Id. at 4–9.
40
Letter from Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Doug Collins,
Ranking Member, H. Comm on the Judiciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Anti-
trust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James Sensen-
brenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.
Comm. on the Judiciary to Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc. (Sept. 13, 2019) [hereinafter Com-
mittee Request for Information, Amazon], https://judiciary.house.gov/sites/democrats
.judiciary.house.gov/files/documents/amazon%20rfi%20-%20signed.pdf.
(a) Alphabet. The Committee’s RFI to Alphabet, the parent com-
pany of Google, asked for information necessary to understand how
the company operates and its role in the digital marketplace.
36
For
example, in Request A, the RFI asked for detailed financial state-
ments and a description of Alphabet’s relevant products and serv-
ices, including Google Ads, Google Search, YouTube, and Waze. In
addition, the RFI asked for information helpful for determining
whether Alphabet has monopoly power for any of its products or
services, including for each product or service: (i) a list of Alpha-
bet’s top ten competitors; and (ii) internal or external analyses of
Alphabet’s market share relative to its competitors. Request A also
asked for copies of documents and information that Alphabet had
submitted to any U.S. or international antitrust enforcement agen-
cy for antitrust investigations that took place in any of those agen-
cies within the past decade.
37
Request B asked for all communications from high-level execu-
tives, including former CEO Larry Page and current CEO Sundar
Pichai, relating to a number of Alphabet’s key acquisitions and po-
tentially anticompetitive conduct, most of which have been widely
reported in the news.
38
The RFI asked for communications, includ-
ing, but not limited to, discussions relating to the deal rationale
and any competitive threat posed by the acquired company for the
following acquisitions: Google/Android in 2005, Google/YouTube in
2006, Google/DoubleClick in 2007, Google/AdMob in 2009, and
Google’s acquisition of a minority stake in Vevo in 2013. Request B
of the Alphabet RFI also requested executive communications relat-
ing to certain categories of potential anticompetitive conduct.
39
In response to this request, Alphabet produced 1,135,398 docu-
ments, including strategy memoranda, presentations, and mate-
rials produced in prior investigations. Although Google produced a
significant amount of material, the Subcommittee did not view this
volume as a proxy for quality.
(b) Amazon. The Committee’s RFI to Amazon asked for similar
types of information helpful for understanding the competitive dy-
namics of the digital marketplace and the company’s role.
40
For ex-
ample, in Request A, the RFI asked for detailed financial state-
ments and a description of Amazon’s relevant products and serv-
ices, including Alexa, Amazon Marketplace, Amazon Prime, and
Amazon Web Services (AWS). In addition, the RFI asked for infor-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00021 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
16
41
Id. at 1–3.
42
The Amazon RFI defines the term ‘‘Relevant Executives’’ as Jeff Bezos, Jeff Wilke, Andy
Jassy, Jeff Blackburn, Dave Limp, Brian Olsavsky, David Zapolsky, and Jay Carney. See id.
at 3.
43
Amazon acquired ‘‘Quidsi, the e-commerce company that runs Diapers.com’’ in 2010. Claire
Cain Miller, Amazon Has a Reported Deal to Buy Parent of Diapers.com, N.Y. T
IMES
(Nov. 7,
2010), https://www.nytimes.com/2010/11/08/technology/08amazon.html.
44
Committee Request for Information, Amazon at 3–7.
45
Letter from Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Doug Collins,
Ranking Member, H. Comm on the Judiciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Anti-
trust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James Sensen-
brenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the
H. Comm. on the Judiciary to Tim Cook, CEO, Apple, Inc. (Sept. 13, 2019) [hereinafter Com-
mittee Request for Information, Apple], https://judiciary.house.gov/sites/democrats.judiciary
.house.gov/files/documents/apple%20rfi%20-%20signed.pdf.
46
Id. at 1–3.
mation helpful for determining whether Amazon has monopoly
power for any of its products or services, including for each product
or service: (i) a list of Amazon’s top ten competitors; and (ii) inter-
nal or external analyses of Amazon’s market share relative to its
competitors. Request A also asked for copies of documents and in-
formation that Amazon had submitted to any U.S. or international
antitrust enforcement agency for antitrust investigations that took
place in any of those agencies within the past decade.
41
Request B asked for all communications from high-level execu-
tives, including CEO Jeff Bezos and Jay Carney, Senior Vice Presi-
dent for Global Corporate Affairs, relating to a number of Amazon’s
key acquisitions and potentially anticompetitive conduct, most of
which have been widely reported in the news.
42
The RFI asked for
communications, including, but not limited to, discussions relating
to the deal rationale and any competitive threat posed by the ac-
quired company for the following acquisitions: Amazon/Audible in
2008, Amazon/Zappos in 2009, Amazon/Quidsi (Diapers.com) in
2010,
43
Amazon/Whole Foods in 2017, and Amazon/Ring in 2018.
Request B of the Amazon RFI also requested executive communica-
tions relating to certain categories of potential anticompetitive con-
duct.
44
In response to the Committee’s requests, Amazon produced
24,299 documents, including internal emails among the company’s
senior executives, memoranda, presentations, and other materials.
(c) Apple. The Committee’s RFI to Apple also asked for informa-
tion helpful for understanding the company’s role in the digital
marketplace. For example, in Request A, the RFI asked for detailed
financial statements and a description of Apple’s relevant products
and services, including the iPhone, App Store, and Apple Pay.
45
In
addition, the RFI asked for information helpful for determining
whether Apple has monopoly power for any of its products or serv-
ices, including for each product or service: (i) a list of Apple’s top
ten competitors; and (ii) internal or external analyses of Apple’s
market share relative to its competitors. Request A also asked for
copies of documents and information that Apple had submitted to
any U.S. or international antitrust enforcement agency for anti-
trust investigations that took place in any of those agencies within
the past decade.
46
Request B asked for all communications from high-level execu-
tives, including CEO Tim Cook and Eddy Cue, Senior Vice Presi-
dent of Internet Software and Services, relating to potentially anti-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00022 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
17
47
The Apple RFI defines the term ‘‘Relevant Executives’’ as Tim Cook, Katherine Adams,
Eddy Cue, Philip Schiller, Johny Srouji, Dan Riccio, Jonathan Ive, Craig Frederighi, Luca
Maestri, Jeff Williams, Steve Dowling, Tor Myhren, Lucas Maestri, and Jane Horvath. See id.
at 3.
48
Id. at 3–6.
49
Letter from Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Doug Collins,
Ranking Member, H. Comm on the Judiciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Anti-
trust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James Sensen-
brenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.
Comm. on the Judiciary to Mark Zuckerberg, CEO, Facebook, Inc. (Sept. 13, 2019) [hereinafter
Committee Request for Information, Facebook], https://judiciary.house.gov/sites/democrats
.judiciary.house.gov/files/documents/facebook%20rfi%20-%20signed.pdf.
50
See id. at 1–2.
51
The Facebook RFI defines the term ‘‘Relevant Executives’’ as Mark Zuckerberg, Sheryl
Sandberg, Jennifer Newstead, Javier Olivan, Chris Cox, Mike Schroepfer, David Wehner, Colin
Stretch, Will Cathcart, Adam Mosseri, Stan Chudnovsky, Fidji Simo, Chris Daniels, Erin Egan,
and Kevin Martin. See id. at 2–3.
52
See id. at 2–5.
competitive conduct, most of which has been widely reported in the
news.
47
The RFI asked for communications, including, but not lim-
ited to, discussions relating to certain categories of potentially anti-
competitive conduct.
48
In response to the Committee’s requests, Apple produced 2,246
documents. These documents include internal communications
among the company’s senior executives describing governance of
the App Store, as well as the company’s internal deliberations and
strategy responding to recent controversies.
(d) Facebook. The Committee’s RFI to Facebook also asked for in-
formation helpful for understanding how the company operates and
its role in the digital marketplace.
49
For example, in Request A,
the RFI asked for detailed financial statements and a description
of Facebook’s relevant products and services, including Facebook,
Instagram, and WhatsApp. In addition, the RFI asked for informa-
tion helpful for determining whether Facebook has monopoly power
for any of its products or services, including for each product or
service: (i) a list of Facebook’s top ten competitors; and (ii) internal
or external analyses of Facebook’s market share relative to its com-
petitors. Request A also asked for copies of documents and informa-
tion that Facebook had submitted to any U.S. or international anti-
trust enforcement agency for antitrust investigations that took
place in any of those agencies within the past decade.
50
Request B asked for all communications from high-level execu-
tives, including Founder and CEO Mark Zuckerberg and Sheryl
Sandberg, Chief Operating Officer, relating to a number of
Facebook’s key acquisitions and potentially anticompetitive con-
duct, most of which have been widely reported in the news.
51
The
RFI asked for communications, including, but not limited to, dis-
cussions relating to the deal rationale and any competitive threat
posed by the acquired company for the following acquisitions:
Facebook/Instagram in 2012, Facebook/Onavo in 2013, and
Facebook/WhatsApp in 2014. Request B of the Facebook RFI also
requested executive communications relating to certain categories
of potentially anticompetitive conduct.
52
In response to the Committee’s requests, Facebook produced
41,442 documents, including documents produced in response to
prior investigations into Facebook’s acquisitions and into whether
it had abused its dominance. Facebook also produced 83,804 docu-
ments in connection with litigation in an ongoing matter. Among
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00023 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
18
53
See, e.g., Letter from Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Doug
Collins, Ranking Member, H. Comm on the Judiciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm.
on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James
Sensenbrenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the
H. Comm. on the Judiciary to Mark Zuckerberg, CEO, Facebook, Inc. (Dec. 4, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
other items, these documents include internal communications
among the company’s senior executives describing Facebook’s ac-
quisition and overall competition strategy. In response to supple-
mental requests by the Subcommittee, Facebook produced internal
market data over a multi-year period, as well as a memorandum
prepared by a senior data scientist and economist at the company
related to competition among Facebook’s family of products and
other social apps.
2. Process for Obtaining Responses to First-Party Requests
After sending the RFIs, Subcommittee staff invested considerable
time and resources in making themselves available for calls with
the platforms to answer any questions the platforms had about re-
sponding to the requests, on a nearly weekly basis from October
2019 through March 2020. On these calls, staff addressed a range
of issues, including clarifying the meaning and intent of language
in the request; maintaining the confidentiality of sensitive business
information; and, where appropriate, narrowing requests in an ef-
fort to balance the Committee’s need for relevant information
against the platforms’ burden of production. Each of the inves-
tigated platforms failed to meet the October 14, 2019 deadline, cit-
ing various difficulties.
On December 4, 2019, nearly three months after the deadline for
submitting the RFI responses, the Committee sent a letter to the
platforms’ CEOs pointing out their failure to comply. The Com-
mittee stated its expectation that the platforms would complete
production by December 18, 2019 for Request A and January 2,
2020 for Request B, to avoid the need to invoke other processes and
procedures to obtain the requested materials.
53
After the platforms failed to meet the revised deadlines, in early
February 2020, staff asked for the companies’ outside counsel to at-
tend in-person meetings to discuss the substantial gaps in produc-
tion that remained, and to identify ways to address any obstacles
the platforms identified to filling those gaps. Despite the Commit-
tee’s best efforts to address those obstacles—and allowing substan-
tial time for the platforms to navigate delays relating to the
COVID–19 pandemic—staff again had to reach out to the platforms
regarding the deficiency of their responses. On June 9, 2020, in a
final effort to avoid resorting to issuing subpoenas to the platforms
to compel the production of documents and information, staff re-
quested that the platforms voluntarily provide information respon-
sive to a reduced list of targeted requests by June 22, 2020.
3. Third-Party Requests for Information
As part of the investigation, the Subcommittee collected a large
amount of information from market participants, including cus-
tomers and competitors of Amazon, Apple, Facebook, and Google.
Staff also received information and analysis from other third par-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00024 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
19
54
Submission from Source 685, to Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
Hon. Doug Collins, Ranking Member, H. Comm on the Judiciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair,
Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon.
F. James Sensenbrenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin.
Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary (July 11, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
55
Submission from Source 147, to Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
Hon. Doug Collins, Ranking Member, H. Comm on the Judiciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair,
Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon.
F. James Sensenbrenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin.
Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary (July 15, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
ties, including academics, former antitrust government officials,
public interest organizations, and trade associations.
(a) Market Participants. In September, the Committee sent a re-
quest for information to over 80 market participants. The RFI
asked the recipient to voluntarily provide information regarding
the state of competition in the digital marketplace for various prod-
ucts and services, including the number and identity of market
participants, market shares, and barriers to entry. These third-
party RFIs also asked for a description of any conduct by Amazon,
Apple, Facebook, or Google that raises competition concerns, and
the impact of such conduct on the recipient’s business. The Com-
mittee also sought to gather information through these RFIs re-
garding broader questions based on the recipient’s experience in
the digital marketplace, including (i) whether market participants
are able to compete on the merits of their goods and services; (ii)
the adequacy of antitrust enforcement relating to merger review
and anticompetitive conduct; (iii) the adequacy of current antitrust
law to address anticompetitive mergers and anticompetitive con-
duct; and (iv) suggestions for improving enforcement of antitrust
law and making changes to antitrust law itself, statutory or other-
wise.
On January 7, 2020, the Committee sent a second round of RFIs
to 29 market participants. These RFI recipients consisted of addi-
tional businesses and individuals that staff had identified during
the first half of the investigation as likely to have relevant informa-
tion and an interest in sharing that information with the Com-
mittee. These RFIs asked for similar information to the September
RFIs and provided staff with additional valuable information and
insights into the functioning and challenges of operating in the dig-
ital marketplace.
Unfortunately, some market participants did not respond to sub-
stantive inquiries due to fear of economic retaliation. These market
participants explained that their business and livelihoods rely on
one or more of the digital platforms. One response stated, ‘‘Unfortu-
nately, [the CEO] is not able to be more public at this time out of
concern for retribution to his business,’’ adding, ‘‘I am pretty cer-
tain we are not the only ones that are afraid of going public.’’
54
An-
other business that ultimately declined to participate in the inves-
tigation expressed similar concerns, stating, ‘‘We really appreciate
you reaching out to us and are certainly considering going on the
record with our story .... Given how powerful Google is and their
past actions, we are also quite frankly worried about retalia-
tion.’’
55
Stacy Mitchell, Co-Director of the Institute for Local Self-
Reliance, similarly testified that many businesses have a fear of
speaking out about Amazon, stating, ‘‘I spend a lot of time inter-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00025 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
20
56
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 250 (statement of Stacy F. Mitchell, Co-Dir.,
Inst. for Local Self-Reliance).
57
Government Oversight, H. C
OMM
.
ON THE
J
UDICIARY
, https://judiciary.house.gov/issues/
government-oversight/.
58
R
ULES OF
T
HE
H
OUSE OF
R
EPRESENTATIVES
, 116th Cong., lst Sess., Rule X, cl. 1(l)(2)
(2019), http://clerk.house.gov/legislative/house-rules.pdf.
viewing and talking with independent retailers, manufacturers of
all sizes. Many of them are very much afraid of speaking out pub-
licly because they fear retaliation.’’
56
(b) Antitrust Experts. The Committee’s final round of outreach to
third parties involved sending letters on March 13, 2020, soliciting
insights and analysis from several dozen antitrust experts who
were identified on a bipartisan basis and whose submissions rep-
resent a diverse range of experience and perspectives. In support
of the investigation’s objective to assess the adequacy of existing
antitrust laws, competition policies, and current enforcement lev-
els, the Committee invited submissions on three main topics. The
first topic covered the adequacy of existing laws—case law and
statutes—that prohibit monopolization and monopolistic conduct.
The second topic similarly dealt with the adequacy of existing law,
but focused on its sufficiency to address anticompetitive mergers
and acquisitions, including vertical and conglomerate mergers, se-
rial acquisitions, data acquisitions, and strategic acquisitions of po-
tential competitors. Third, the Committee sought feedback on
whether the institutional structure of antitrust enforcement is ade-
quate to promote the robust enforcement of the antitrust laws, in-
cluding current levels of appropriations to the antitrust agencies,
existing agency authorities, and congressional oversight of enforce-
ment.
(c) Additional Outreach and Submissions. In addition to sending
the RFIs in September and January, the Subcommittee engaged in
extensive outreach to additional third parties based on public re-
ports and non-public information gathered throughout the inves-
tigation, suggesting that such entities had relevant information.
The Subcommittee also received submissions from numerous in-
dividuals and businesses throughout the course of the investiga-
tion. These submissions came from a wide range of sources and in
a variety of forms. For example, an anonymous source sent thumb
drives to the Committee’s main office in the Rayburn House Office
Building. Other examples included former or current employees
submitting tips to the Subcommittee’s investigation email address,
or through the form for anonymous submissions posted on the Sub-
committee’s investigation website.
4. Antitrust Agencies Requests for Information
As part of the Committee’s September 2019 efforts to gather in-
formation, the Committee also sent requests for information to the
Federal Trade Commission (FTC) and the Department of Justice
(DOJ). In part, the Committee sought this information to carry out
its function as the principal oversight authority for the DOJ, in-
cluding its component agencies, its personnel, and its law enforce-
ment activities.
57
Similarly, the Committee’s jurisdiction extends
to the FTC’s antitrust-related work, and to administrative practice
and procedure, including at the FTC.
58
The Committee’s RFIs re-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00026 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
21
59
The Subcommittee recognizes that publication of these documents could cause competitive
injury to firms that cooperated with prior investigations or in ongoing investigations. Where pos-
sible, this Report summarizes or draws conclusions from these sources without reproducing
them.
60
Free and Diverse Press Hearing, https://judiciary.house.gov/legislation/hearings/online-
platforms-and-market-power-part-1-free-and-diverse-press.
61
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing, https://judiciary.house.gov/legislation/hear-
ings/online-platforms-and-market-power-part-2-innovation-and-entrepreneurship.
quested documents relating to the agencies’ decisions to open or
close investigations into potential violations of antitrust law in dig-
ital markets, decisions to challenge mergers or conduct in Federal
district court or in administrative action, and decisions to forego
litigation in favor of a settlement agreement.
59
Senior officials
from the FTC and the Antitrust Division also provided several
briefings to Members of the Subcommittee and staff in response to
the requests of the Subcommittee Chair and Ranking Member.
These briefings served as an opportunity for Members to obtain in-
formation and updates about the current state of antitrust law and
enforcement in digital markets.
B. Hearings
On June 11, 2019, the Subcommittee held part one of its series
of investigation hearings titled ‘‘Online Platforms and Market
Power, Part 1: The Free and Diverse Press.’’ At this hearing, the
Subcommittee heard testimony from the following Majority wit-
nesses: David Chavern, President of the News Media Alliance;
Gene Kimmelman, President and CEO of Public Knowledge; Sally
Hubbard, Director of Enforcement Strategy at Open Markets Insti-
tute (OMI); and Matthew Schruers, Vice President for Law and
Policy at Computer and Communications Industry Association
(CCIA). The Minority witnesses were David Pitofsky, General
Counsel for News Corp; and Kevin Riley, Editor of The Atlanta
Journal-Constitution.
60
On July 16, 2019, the Subcommittee held its second hearing, a
two-paneled hearing titled ‘‘Online Platforms and Market Power,
Part 2: Innovation and Entrepreneurship.’’ On the first panel, the
Subcommittee heard testimony from the following: Adam Cohen,
Director of Economic Policy at Google; Nate Sutton, Associate Gen-
eral Counsel, Competition, at Amazon; Matt Perault, Head of Glob-
al Policy Development at Facebook; and Kyle Andeer, Vice Presi-
dent and Corporate Law and Chief Compliance Officer at Apple.
On the second panel, the Subcommittee heard testimony from the
following Majority witnesses: Timothy Wu, Julius Silver Professor
of Law, Science and Technology at Columbia Law School; Fiona
Scott Morton, Theodore Nierenberg Professor of Economics at Yale
University School of Management; and Stacy Mitchell, Co-Director
of the Institute for Local Self-Reliance. On the second panel, the
Minority witnesses were Maureen Ohlhausen, Partner at Baker
Botts and former Commissioner and Acting Chair of the Federal
Trade Commission; Morgan Reed, Executive Director of The App
Association; and Carl Szabo, Vice President and General Counsel
at NetChoice.
61
On October 18, 2019, the Subcommittee held its third hearing ti-
tled ‘‘Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 3: The Role of Data
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00027 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
22
62
Data and Privacy Hearing, https://judiciary.house.gov/calendar/eventsingle.aspx?Event
ID=2248.
63
Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 4: Perspectives of the Antitrust Agencies: Hearing
Before the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judici-
ary, 116th Cong. (2019) [hereinafter Antitrust Agencies Hearing], https://judiciary.house
.gov/calendar/eventsingle.aspx?EventID=2287.
64
Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 5: Competitors in the Digital Economy: Hearing
Before the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judici-
ary, 116th Cong. (2020) [hereinafter Competitors Hearing], https://judiciary.house.gov/
calendar/eventsingle.aspx?EventID=2386.
65
Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 6: Examining the Dominance of Amazon, Apple,
Facebook, and Google: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law
of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 116th Cong. (2020) [hereinafter CEO Hearing], https://
judiciary.house.gov/calendar/eventsingle.aspx?EventID=3113.
and Privacy in Competition.’’ At this hearing, the Subcommittee
heard testimony from the following Majority witnesses: The Honor-
able Rohit Chopra, Commissioner at the Federal Trade Commis-
sion; Dr. Jason Furman, Professor of the Practice of Economic Pol-
icy at Harvard Kennedy School and former Chair of the Council of
Economic Advisers (CEA); and Dr. Tommaso Valletti, Professor of
Economics and Head of the Department of Economics & Public Pol-
icy at Imperial College Business School and former Chief Competi-
tion Economist of the European Commission’s Directorate General
for Competition (DG–Comp). The Minority witness at the hearing
was Dr. Roslyn Layton, Visiting Scholar at the American Enter-
prise Institute.
62
On November 13, 2019, the Subcommittee held its fourth hearing
titled ‘‘Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 4: Perspectives of
the Antitrust Agencies.’’ At this hearing, the Subcommittee heard
testimony from the following witnesses: The Honorable Makan
Delrahim, Assistant Attorney General for the Antitrust Division at
the Department of Justice; and the Honorable Joseph J. Simons,
Chair of the Federal Trade Commission.
63
On January 17, 2020, the Subcommittee held its fifth hearing ti-
tled ‘‘Field Hearing: Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 5:
Competitors in the Digital Economy.’’ At this hearing, which took
place in the congressional district of Subcommittee Vice-Chair Joe
Neguse (D–CO) at the University of Colorado School of Law, the
Subcommittee heard testimony from the following Majority wit-
nesses: Patrick Spence, Chief Executive Officer of Sonos; David
Barnett, Founder and Chief Executive Officer of PopSockets; and
Kirsten Daru, Vice President and General Counsel at Tile. The Mi-
nority witness at the hearing was David Heinemeier Hansson, Co-
founder and Chief Technology Officer of Basecamp.
64
On July 29, 2020, the Subcommittee held its sixth hearing titled
‘‘Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 6: Examining the Domi-
nance of Amazon, Apple, Facebook, and Google.’’ At this hearing,
the Subcommittee heard testimony from the following witnesses:
Jeff Bezos, Chief Executive Officer at Amazon; Sundar Pichai,
Chief Executive Officer at Alphabet and Google; Tim Cook, Chief
Executive Officer at Apple; and Mark Zuckerberg, Chief Executive
Officer at Facebook.
65
On October 1, 2020, the Subcommittee held its seventh hearing
titled ‘‘Proposals to Strengthen the Antitrust Laws and Restore
Competition Online.’’ The Majority witnesses at the hearing in-
cluded: William Baer, Visiting Fellow, Brookings Institution, and
former Associate Attorney General, Department of Justice; Zephyr
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00028 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
23
66
Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 7: Proposals to Strengthen the Antitrust Laws
and Restore Competition Online: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and
Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 116th Cong. (2020) [hereinafter Remedies Hear-
ing], https://judiciary.house.gov/calendar/eventsingle.aspx?EventID=3367.
67
This roundtable was originally scheduled to take place physically as a field hearing in Prov-
idence, Rhode Island, but was held virtually due to the COVID–19 pandemic.
Teachout, Associate Professor of Law, Fordham University School
of Law; Michael Kades, Director of Markets and Competition Pol-
icy, Washington Center for Equitable Growth; Sabeel Rahman, As-
sociate Professor of Law, Brooklyn Law School and President,
Demos; and Sally Hubbard, Director of Enforcement Strategy,
Open Markets Institute. The Minority witnesses at the hearing
were Christopher Yoo, John H. Chestnut Professor of Law, Commu-
nication, and Information Science, University of Pennsylvania
Carey Law School; Rachel Bovard, Senior Director of Policy, Con-
servative Partnership Institute; and Tad Lipsky, Antonin Scalia
Law School, George Mason University.
66
C. Roundtables
In addition to holding public hearings, the Subcommittee also
held a series of bipartisan roundtables for Members of the Sub-
committee and staff to provide Members with an opportunity to
conduct further oversight of: (1) the state of competition and prob-
lems in digital markets; (2) whether dominant firms have engaged
in anticompetitive conduct; and (3) if antitrust laws, competition
policies, and current enforcement levels are adequate to address
these issues. In total, the Subcommittee held twelve briefings and
roundtables in Washington, DC; four roundtables in Boulder, Colo-
rado; and a virtual roundtable with stakeholders from Rhode Is-
land and elsewhere in New England.
67
The Subcommittee hosted multiple briefings and roundtables
with experts on the digital economy on a range of topics. Experts
included state antitrust enforcers, former officials from the Anti-
trust Division of the DOJ and the FTC, former technology industry
executives, small business owners, representatives from the news
industry, entrepreneurs, antitrust scholars, representatives from
civil society, and representatives from libraries.
The briefings and roundtables covered a broad array of topics re-
lated to competition in the digital marketplace. These topics in-
cluded:
The effect that small algorithm changes by dominant platforms can have on
small businesses that rely on the platform;
The data advantages that dominant online platform companies have over
smaller competitors and startups, and how those data advantages can rein-
force dominance and serve as a barrier to entry;
The effect of dominant online platform company power and practices on a free
and diverse press, local newsgathering and reporting;
The impact of dominant online platform company power and practices on in-
vestment in startups by venture capital firms;
The fear of economic retaliation by dominant platforms against smaller compa-
nies that raise concerns about anticompetitive conduct in the digital market-
place;
Other features of digital markets—including, but not limited to, network ef-
fects, economies of scale and scope, and barriers to entry—that make them
prone to high concentration and monopolization;
Enforcement of the antitrust laws; and
Modernization of antitrust statutes and competition policy.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00029 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
24
68
H. R
EP
. N
O
. 82–255, at 2 (1951) (Aluminum: Report of the Subcomm. on Study of Monopoly
Power of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
69
See, e.g., H. R
EP
. N
O
. 87–1419, at 2 (1962) (The Ocean Freight Industry: Report of the Anti-
trust Subcomm. of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary) [hereinafter 1962 Ocean Freight Industry
Report] (describing how Subcommittee staff spent more than nine months examining ‘‘tens of
thousands of documents in the files of over 50 ocean-freight conferences’’ and other materials).
70
R
ULES OF THE
H
OUSE OF
R
EPRESENTATIVES
, 116th Cong., lst Sess., Rule X, cl. 1(l)(2) (2019),
http://clerk.house.gov/legislative/house-rules.pdf.
Additionally, the Subcommittee held briefings that also allowed
representatives from Google, Amazon, Facebook, and Apple to
make their own presentations to the Subcommittee and to answer
questions and provide details regarding their companies’ business
practices, structures, and strategies in the marketplace.
D. Prior Investigations
The Subcommittee’s current review of competition in the digital
marketplace continues a long oversight tradition. Over many dec-
ades, the House Judiciary Committee and its antitrust sub-
committee have conducted careful, fact-based inquiries into indus-
trial sectors showing signs of undue concentration and anticompeti-
tive conduct. As a 1951 report from the then-named Subcommittee
on the Study of Monopoly Power described its mandate, ‘‘It is the
province of this subcommittee to investigate factors which tend to
eliminate competition, strengthen monopolies, injure small busi-
ness, or promote undue concentration of economic power; to ascer-
tain the facts, and to make recommendations based on those find-
ings.’’
68
The Subcommittee followed the same process ‘‘to ascertain the
facts’’ in this investigation. It has included hearings with industry
and government witnesses, consultations with subject-matter ex-
perts, and a careful—and at times painstaking—review of large
volumes of evidence provided by industry participants and regu-
lators. Recognizing that antitrust investigations are by their nature
fact-dependent, teams of investigators invested significant re-
sources to study the structure of the relevant markets and the im-
portant firms in those markets.
69
The purpose of these exercises was not to supersede the activities
of antitrust enforcers such as the FTC and the DOJ, but to compile
the Committee’s own record about current market conditions; to as-
sess how antitrust laws and principles are being applied in the cur-
rent business environment; and to determine whether revised laws,
or new laws, or better enforcement are needed to protect competi-
tion.
While the Committee’s investigations were not intended to inter-
fere with the enforcement activities of antitrust enforcers or regu-
lators, they often conducted inquiries into the same sectors and
issues that the DOJ, the FTC, the Federal Communications Com-
mission (FCC), and other agencies with authority over competition
policy or enforcement were also examining. As Members and staff
of the Committee charged with the ‘‘protection of trade and com-
merce against unlawful restraints and monopolies,’’
70
these inves-
tigators exercised their legislative authority to probe any aspect of
antitrust that they deemed warranted attention.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00030 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
25
71
H. R
EP
. N
O
. 102–850, at 15 (1992) (Report on Antitrust Reform Act of 1992, H. Comm.
on the Judiciary) [hereinafter Antitrust Reform Act of 1992].
72
H. R
EP
. N
O
. 82–1217, at 1 (1951) (The Mobilization Program: Report of the Subcomm. on
Study of Monopoly Power of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
73
Id. at 2.
74
H. R
EP
. N
O
. 85–1328, at 1 (1958) (The Airlines Industry: Report of the Antitrust Subcomm.
of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary) [hereinafter Airlines Industry Report].
75
1962 Ocean Freight Industry Report at 394.
76
Antitrust Reform Act of 1992 at 10.
77
Airlines Industry Report at 268–69.
78
Id. at 272.
79
Id. at 278.
80
H. R
EP
. N
O
. 85–607, at 143 (1957) (The Television Broadcasting Industry: Report of the
Antitrust Subcomm. of the Comm. on the Judiciary).
These investigations were guided by the principle that ‘‘[h]istory
has proven that the most conducive environment for innovation
and new product availability is a competitive market,’’
71
and that
a ‘‘free competitive economy’’ is an important American value.
72
It
was a value that had been formally embedded in our economy and
society by the Sherman Act of 1890, ‘‘the peculiarly American char-
ter of economic freedom.’’
73
In a 1958 report on the airline indus-
try, the then-named Antitrust Subcommittee explained that Ameri-
cans’ social and political freedoms depended on ‘‘opportunity for
market access and market rivalries in a private-enterprise econ-
omy.’’
74
The ‘‘freedom of entry into any industry or field of endeav-
or,’’ a 1962 Subcommittee report explained, is a cornerstone of U.S.
antitrust policy that has ‘‘encouraged extensive individual propri-
etorship . . . and has made our free enterprise system great and
strong.’’
75
A 1992 Committee report recommended restrictions on
the monopolistic Regional Bell Operating Companies (RBOCs) ‘‘[f]or
the sake of the democratic economic and political values which de-
pend on the preservation of free markets.’’
76
In some cases, antitrust investigations exposed antitrust prob-
lems that the Committee concluded required attention from regu-
lators. For example, a 1958 Antitrust Subcommittee report on the
rapidly growing domestic airline industry exposed the behind-the-
scenes anticompetitive campaign that incumbent air carriers and
their advocacy group, the Air Transport Association of America
(ATA), had been waging to prevent the Civil Aeronautics Board
(CAB) from approving market entry by new air carriers (known at
the time as ‘‘nonskeds’’).
77
The Committee found the conduct of the
ATA so egregious that it recommended an investigation by the DOJ
Antitrust Division.
78
As for international air transportation, the re-
port concluded that Pan American’s dominance in the market was
the ‘‘result of its use of devices to foreclose competition in order to
secure and maintain control over markets in which it does busi-
ness,’’ and recommended that the CAB undertake a broad inves-
tigation of the company.
79
In other cases, the Committee investigated matters that were
currently under review by antitrust enforcers. In a 1957 report on
the broadcast television industry, which was quickly reshaping
Americans’ consumption of news and entertainment, the then-
named Antitrust Subcommittee described the anticompetitive tac-
tics CBS and NBC were using to promote their own content at the
expense of independent content producers.
80
According to the re-
port, networks were improperly using their power as vertical dis-
tributors of content to extract financial concessions from inde-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00031 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
26
81
Id.
82
Id.
83
Id.
84
Antitrust Reform Act of 1992 at 39 (‘‘The FCC, while claiming boldly to be a forum where
complaints about monopolistic practices would be received and vigorously pursued had, instead,
become a regulatory ‘graveyard’ for telecommunications competition policy, characterized by in-
action and equivocation.’’).
85
Id. at 45.
86
Id. at 51.
87
Id. at 10. The report explained that the RBOCs’ bottleneck, in antitrust terminology, func-
tioned as an ‘‘essential facility,’’ which gave them ‘‘an inherent ability and—for activities in
which they are engaged themselves—a natural incentive to impede competition in lines of busi-
ness dependent upon that essential facility.’’ Id. at 13.
88
H.R. 5096 (102nd Cong.); H.R. 3626 (103rd Cong.); see H. R
EP
. N
O
. 103–559, pt. II, at 25
(1994) (Report on Antitrust and Communications Reform Act of 1994, H. Comm. on the Judici-
ary) (‘‘The Judiciary Committee has resolved that the Government not lose its nerve once again
and allow an industry born in monopoly to be reborn in monopoly.’’). The procompetitive policies
proposed in this legislation later became law, in modified form, as part of the Telecommuni-
cations Act of 1996. See Pub. L. No. 104–104, §151(a), 110 Stat. 56, 86–107 (codified at 42
U.S.C. 271–276).
pendent competitors seeking to place their programming on net-
work affiliates.
81
There was also evidence that the networks were
using their substantial power with advertisers to unfairly favor
their own content.
82
After praising the DOJ Antitrust Division’s
‘‘alertness to vindicate the competitive dictates of the antitrust
laws,’’ the Subcommittee urged the Division to press its investiga-
tion into this conduct with ‘‘vigor and dispatch.’’
83
In the case of the Committee’s inquiry into the RBOCs’ conduct
in the aftermath of the 1984 breakup of AT&T, we concluded that
federal courts and regulators were not adequately protecting com-
petition in the telecommunications marketplace and that new legis-
lation was necessary. A 1992 Committee report reviewed the long,
troubled history of attempts by DOJ and the FCC
84
to check the
monopolistic power of AT&T, culminating in the famous Modified
Final Judgment (the MFJ) that Judge Harold Greene approved in
August 1982 to break up the company.
85
But even after the MFJ,
the report found, the FCC had failed to prevent the RBOCs from
using their local monopolies to commit a number of anticompetitive
violations, ‘‘many eerily reminiscent of pre-divestiture Bell System
abuses.’’
86
We were also critical of the DOJ’s actions to water down
the MFJ’s procompetitive line-of-business restrictions on the
RBOCs. Describing the massive lobbying campaign that the RBOCs
were waging to enter the business lines the MFJ had opened up
to competitors, we observed, ‘‘The thousands upon thousands of
competitive enterprises now thriving in information service, tele-
communications equipment, and long distance markets face the
prospect of their future prosperity being decided by the self-inter-
ested designs of a monopoly with ‘bottleneck’ control over the local
telephone exchange on which they all depend.’’
87
In light of the
antitrust agencies’ demonstrated failure to protect competition, the
Committee approved legislation that would codify the MFJ’s line-
of-business restrictions into law.
88
Finally, in these prior investigations, the Committee has not
hesitated to recommend that antitrust authorities further inves-
tigate suspicious conduct. After examining the conduct of the Air
Transport Association of America, the industry group representing
the established passenger airline carriers in the 1950s, the Anti-
trust Subcommittee recommended that the Antitrust Division of
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00032 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
27
89
Airlines Industry Report at 272.
90
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 76 (statement of Tim Wu, Julius Silver Prof.
of Law, Columbia Univ. Sch. of Law).
91
Id.; Roger McNamee, Co-Founder & Managing Dir., Elevation Partners, Remarks at Ven-
ture Capital and Antitrust Workshop 34 (Feb. 12, 2020), https://www.justice.gov/atr/page/file/
1255851/download (‘‘[T]here is a case that antitrust has in fact been a major catalysis of growth
in every wave of technology.’’).
92
Antitrust Agencies Hearing at 37 (statement of Makan Delrahim, Assistant Att’y Gen., U.S.
Dep’t of Justice, Antitrust Div.) (‘‘Competition also promotes improvements and upgrades to the
quality and functionality of existing offerings.’’); Jeffrey A. Rosen, Deputy Att’y Gen., U.S. Dep’t
of Justice, Speech at the Free State Foundation’s 12th Annual Telecom Policy Conference (Mar.
10, 2020), https://www.justice.gov/opa/speech/deputy-attorney-general-jeffrey-rosen-speaks-free-
state-foundations-12th-annual-telecom; Giulio Federico, Fiona Scott Morton & Carl Shapiro,
Antitrust and Innovation: Welcoming and Protecting Disruption 1 (Nat’l Bur. of Econ. Rsch.,
Working Paper No. 26005, June 2019), https://www.nber.org/papers/w26005.pdf.
93
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 209 (statement of Maureen K. Ohlhausen,
Partner, Baker Botts L.L.P.) (‘‘Antitrust law’s focus on protecting the competitive process does
not mean that it cannot reach many of the competitive concerns . . . [that] may include price
effects, reductions in quality, and impacts on innovation, as well as the ability of a dominant
player to acquire and neutralize a nascent competitor.’’); id. at 84 (statement of Fiona Scott Mor-
ton, Theodore Nierenberg Prof. of Econ., Yale Sch. of Mgmt.) (‘‘The harms from insufficient com-
petition appear in prices that are higher than competitive prices, quality that is lower than com-
petitive quality, and less innovation than consumers would benefit from in competitive mar-
kets.’’).
94
Id. at 84.
95
See generally Jeffrey A. Rosen, Deputy Att’y Gen., U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Speech at the Free
State Foundation’s 12th Annual Telecom Policy Conference (Mar. 10, 2020), https://
www.justice.gov/opa/speech/deputy-attorney-general-jeffrey-rosen-speaks-free-state-foundations-
12th-annual-telecom (referencing research by economist Kenneth Arrow).
96
Data and Privacy Hearing at 60 (statement of Jason Furman, Prof. of the Prac. of Econ.
Pol’y, Harvard Kennedy Sch.).
97
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 79 (statement of Tim Wu, Julius Silver Prof.
of Law, Columbia Univ. Sch. of Law).
98
Id. at 84. See also Sai Krishna Kamepalli, Raghuram Rajan & Luigi Zingales, Kill Zone
(Univ. of Chi., Becker Friedman Inst. for Econ., Working Paper No. 2020–19, Apr. 2020),
https://ssrn.com/abstract=3555915.
the DOJ further investigate the ‘‘serious antitrust problems’’ it had
identified.
89
III. BACKGROUND
A. Overview of Competition in Digital Markets
1. The Role of Competition Online
At a fundamental level, competition has been a key engine of eco-
nomic activity in the United States,
90
resulting in the ‘‘pioneering
of entire industries that, in time, come to employ millions and gen-
erate trillions.’’
91
This is especially true in the digital economy. As
in other industries, competition in digital markets incentivizes in-
cumbent firms and new entrants to build new technologies and im-
prove business processes.
92
It spurs capital investment and
incentivizes firms to improve the quality of their offerings.
93
In its
absence, incumbent firms lack the incentive to invest in research
and development.
94
This in turn slows the rate of innovation across
the industry.
95
Disruptive new products or services are replaced
with slow, incremental alterations
96
‘‘designed to protect [incum-
bent firms’] existing revenue streams.’’
97
Slowly but surely, ven-
ture capitalists lose the incentive to invest in new entrants willing
to challenge the dominance of incumbent firms through direct com-
petition.
98
What we are left with are so-called ‘‘kill zones’’—the
near-complete absence of competition.
The benefits of robust competition in the digital economy go be-
yond innovation and productivity. It can also spur firms to compete
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00033 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
28
99
Data and Privacy Hearing at 54 (statement of Tommaso Valletti, Prof. of Econ., Imperial
Coll. Bus. Sch.) (‘‘Quality, choice, and innovation are also important aspects for competition and
for consumer welfare.’’); Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 207–09 (statement of
Maureen K. Ohlhausen, Partner, Baker Botts L.L.P.).
100
Data and Privacy Hearing at 42 (statement of Rohit Chopra, Comm’r, Fed. Trade Comm’n)
(‘‘These services do have a price, and you are paying for them with your data.’’); id. at 60 (state-
ment of Jason Furman, Prof. of the Prac. of Econ. Pol’y, Harvard Kennedy Sch.) (‘‘Consumers
may think they are receiving ‘free’ products but they are paying a price for these products in
a number of ways.’’).
101
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 209 (statement of Maureen K. Ohlhausen,
Partner, Baker Botts L.L.P.); Data and Privacy Hearing at 60–61 (statement of Jason Furman,
Prof. of the Prac. of Econ. Pol’y, Harvard Kennedy Sch.); id. at 138 (George Slover, Senior Pol’y
Couns., Consumer Reps., Justin Brookman, Dir., Privacy & Tech. Pol’y, Consumer Reps. & Jona-
than Schwantes, Senior Pol’y Couns., Consumer Reps.) (‘‘[A] dominant platform can disregard
the interests of consumers in protecting their privacy, and design their platform to maximize
its ability to monitor, monetize, and manipulate our personal interactions as consumers and as
citizens.’’).
102
Data and Privacy Hearing at 55 (statement of Tommaso Valletti, Prof. of Econ., Imperial
Coll. Bus. Sch.).
103
Id. at 59 (statement of Jason Furman, Prof. of the Prac. of Econ. Pol’y, Harvard Kennedy
Sch.). Other anticompetitive practices in digital markets—such as product design, self-
preferencing, and anticompetitive contracting, among others—may also contribute to barriers
that impede entry by rivals or new firms. While these issues are also present in other markets,
they are much more pronounced in digital markets.
104
Id.
105
Stigler Report at 29, 35.
106
Data and Privacy Hearing at 59–60 (statement of Jason Furman, Prof. of the Prac. of
Econ. Pol’y, Harvard Kennedy Sch.).
107
U.K. C
OMPETITION &
M
KTS
. A
UTH
., O
NLINE
P
LATFORMS AND
D
IGITAL
A
DVERTISING
, M
AR
-
KET
S
TUDY
F
INAL
R
EPORT
10–11 (2020) [hereinafter Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report].
108
Data and Privacy Hearing at 58 (statement of Jason Furman, Prof. of the Prac. of Econ.
Pol’y, Harvard Kennedy Sch.).
along other dimensions such as privacy and data protection. As a
general matter, inadequate competition not only leads to higher
prices and less innovation in many cases, but it can also reduce the
quality of goods and services.
99
Given that many digital products
do not charge consumers directly for services, these firms often
compete on quality.
100
Along these lines, lack of competition can re-
sult in eroded privacy and data protection.
101
Growing evidence in-
dicates that a lack of competition goes hand in hand with just such
quality degradation.
102
2. Market Structure
(a) Winner-Take-All Markets. Certain features of digital markets-
such as network effects, switching costs, the self-reinforcing advan-
tages of data, and increasing returns to scale-make them prone to
winner-take-all economics.
103
As a result, many technology mar-
kets ‘‘tip’’ in favor of one or two large companies,
104
shifting the
‘‘the competitive process from competition in the market to com-
petition for the market.’’
105
In turn, high barriers to entry may di-
minish the ability of new firms to challenge incumbent firms, fur-
ther undermining the competitive process and protecting the domi-
nance of existing firms.
106
As the United Kingdom’s Competition
and Markets Authority explains:
[I]f potential competitors face substantial barriers to entry and expansion, such
that the market is no longer properly contestable, then a high market share can
translate into market power, giving the platform the opportunity to increase
prices, reduce quality or leverage market power to undermine competition in po-
tentially competitive markets and deny innovative rivals the chance to bring new
services to market.
107
(b) Market Concentration. Consistent with winner-take-all dy-
namics, the digital economy is highly concentrated.
108
A number of
key markets online—such as social media, general online search,
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00034 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
29
109
Id. at 59; Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 78 (statement of Tim Wu, Julius
Silver Prof. of Law, Columbia Univ. Sch. of Law).
110
Tim Wu & Stuart A. Thompson, The Roots of Big Tech Run Disturbingly Deep, N.Y. T
IMES
(June 7, 2019), https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2019/06/07/opinion/google-facebook-
mergers-acquisitions-antitrust.html; see Visualizing Tech Giants’ Billion-Dollar Acquisitions, CB
I
NSIGHTS
(May 5, 2020), https://perma.cc/KJD9-HT3Z.
111
Although several transactions, including Google’s acquisition of ITA in 2010, were subject
to settlements, U.S. antitrust enforcers did not attempt to prevent the consummation of these
transactions.
112
Tim Wu & Stuart A. Thompson, The Roots of Big Tech Run Disturbingly Deep, N.Y. T
IMES
(June 7, 2019), https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2019/06/07/opinion/google-facebook-
mergers-acquisitions-antitrust.html; Carl Shapiro, Antitrust in a Time of Populism, 61 I
NT
L
. J.
I
NDUS
. O
RG
. 714, 739–40 (2018), https://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/shapiro/antitrustpopulism
.pdf.
113
Colleen Cunningham, Florian Ederer & Song Ma, Killer Acquisitions 1 (Yale Sch. of
Mgmt., Working Paper, 2020), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3241707 (describing the practice
whereby ‘‘an incumbent firm may acquire an innovative target and terminate the development
of the target’s innovations to preempt future competition’’). See also C. Scott Hemphill & Tim
Wu, Nascent Competitors, 168 U. P
A
. L. R
EV
. 1879, 1880 (2020), https://perma.cc/62HH-34ZL
(‘‘A nascent competitor is a firm whose prospective innovation represents a serious future threat
to an incumbent.’’).
114
Mark Lemley & Andrew McCreary, Exit Strategy 24–45 (Stanford Law Sch., John M. Olin
Program in Law & Econ., Working Paper No. 542, 2020), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3506919.
115
Id.
116
See infra Section V.
and online advertising—are dominated by just one or two
firms.
109
In some instances, this concentration is the result of a
high volume of acquisitions by the dominant digital platforms. To-
gether, the largest technology firms have acquired hundreds of
companies in the last ten years.
110
Antitrust enforcers in the
United States did not block any of these transactions,
111
many of
which eliminated actual or potential competitors.
112
In some in-
stances these acquisitions enabled the dominant firm to neutralize
a competitive threat; in other instances, the dominant firm shut
down or discontinued the underlying product entirely—transactions
aptly described as ‘‘killer acquisitions.’’
113
Evidence also suggests that the venture capital industry, which
plays a critical role in funding innovative startups, contributes to
market consolidation by encouraging startups to exit via a sale to
an incumbent firm.
114
As initial public offerings (IPOs) have be-
come more expensive and time-consuming in recent decades, ven-
ture capitalists have shown a preference for realizing their invest-
ments through acquisitions rather than through public markets.
115
(c) The Role of Online Platforms as Gatekeepers. As Amazon,
Apple, Facebook, and Google have captured control over key chan-
nels of distribution, they have come to function as gatekeepers. A
large swath of businesses across the U.S. economy now depend on
these gatekeepers to access users and markets. In interviews with
the Subcommittee, numerous businesses described how dominant
platforms exploit this gatekeeper power to dictate terms and ex-
tract concessions that third parties would not consent to in a com-
petitive market.
116
According to these companies, these types of
concessions and demands carry significant economic harm but are
‘‘the cost of doing business’’ given the lack of options.
Their role as gatekeepers also gives the dominant platforms out-
sized power to control the fates of other businesses. Reflecting this
fact, several major publicly owned firms that rely on the dominant
platforms have noted in investor statements that this dependent
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00035 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
30
117
Gerrit De Vynck, The Power of Google and Amazon Looms Over Tech IPOs, B
LOOMBERG
(July 1, 2019), https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2019-07-01/google-s-and-amazon-s-
power-looms-over-procession-of-tech-ipos (noting that 17 of 22 initial public offerings by tech-
nology companies cited online platforms as competitors or risks to their businesses).
118
Id.
119
Id.
120
Id.
121
See infra Section V.
122
See Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Opens Investigation into Possible
Anti-competitive Conduct of Amazon (July 17, 2019), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/
presscorner/detail/en/IPl19l4291 (‘‘Based on the Commission’s preliminary fact-finding,
Amazon appears to use competitively sensitive information—about marketplace sellers, their
products and transactions on the marketplace.’’).
123
Tripp Mickle, Apple Dominates App Store Search Results, Thwarting Competitors, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (July 23, 2019), https://www.wsj.com/articles/apple-dominates-app-store-search-results-
thwarting-competitors-11563897221.
124
Jack Nicas & Daisuke Wakabayashi, Sonos, Squeezed by the Tech Giants, Sues Google,
N.Y. T
IMES
(Jan. 7, 2020), https://www.nytimes.com/2020/01/07/technology/sonos-sues-
google.html.
125
Reed Albergotti, Apple Says Recent Changes to Operating System Improve User Privacy,
but Some Lawmakers See Them as an Effort to Edge out Its Rivals, W
ASH
. P
OST
(Nov. 26, 2019),
https://www.washingtonpost.com/technology/2019/11/26/apple-emphasizes-user-privacy-law-
makers-see-it-an-effort-edge-out-its-rivals/; Jason Del Rey, An Amazon Revolt Could Be Brewing
as the Tech Giant Exerts More Control over Brands, V
OX
: R
ECODE
(Nov. 29, 2018), https://
www.vox.com/2018/11/29/18023132/amazon-brand-policy-changes-marketplace-control-one-
vendor.
relationship creates an inherent risk to their businesses.
117
For ex-
ample, Lyft, a ride-sharing company, has cited its use of Amazon’s
cloud services and Google Maps as a potential risk to its business
model.
118
As Lyft stated in a filing, ‘‘Some of our competitors or
technology partners may take actions which disrupt the interoper-
ability of our platform with their own products or services.’’
119
Pinterest, a photo-sharing service, likewise noted in a financial fil-
ing that changes to Google’s search algorithm may harm Pinterest.
As it noted, Pinterest’s ‘‘ability to maintain and increase the num-
ber of visitors directed to our service from search engines is not
within our control. Search engines, such as Google, may modify
their search algorithms and policies or enforce those policies in
ways that are detrimental to us.’’
120
In submissions and inter-
views with the Subcommittee, many companies reiterated the gen-
eral concern that a single act or decision by one of the dominant
platforms could wreck their businesses.
Since the dominant platforms in many cases have also integrated
into adjacent lines of business, these firms operate both as key
intermediaries for third-party companies as well as direct competi-
tors to them. Numerous entrepreneurs, small businesses, and
major companies told the Subcommittee that the dominant plat-
forms’ dual role raises significant competition concerns.
121
In re-
cent years, significant reporting has documented how the dominant
platforms can exploit this dual role, through data exploitation,
122
self-preferencing,
123
appropriation of key technologies,
124
and ab-
rupt changes to a platform’s policies.
125
The Subcommittee’s inves-
tigation uncovered numerous examples of this exploitative conduct,
suggesting that these are increasingly systemic, rather than iso-
lated, business practices.
3. Barriers to Entry
(a) Network Effects. Digital markets tend to be characterized by
strong network effects, making them prone to concentration and
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00036 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
31
126
J
AY
S
HAMBAUGH
, R
YAN
N
UNN
, A
UDREY
B
REITWISER &
P
ATRICK
L
IU
, B
ROOKINGS
I
NST
., T
HE
S
TATE OF
C
OMPETITION AND
D
YNAMISM
: F
ACTS
A
BOUT
C
ONCENTRATION
, S
TART
-U
PS
,
AND
R
E
-
LATED
P
OLICIES
10 (2018), https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2018/06/ESl
THPl20180611lCompetitionFactsl20180611.pdf.
127
See Luigi Zingales & Guy Rolnik, A Way To Own Your Social-Media Data, N.Y. T
IMES
(June 30, 2017), https://www.nytimes.com/2017/06/30/opinion/social-data-google-facebook-
europe.html.
128
M
AURICE
E. S
TUCKE &
A
LLEN
P. G
RUNES
, B
IG
D
ATA AND
C
OMPETITION
P
OLICY
163 (2016).
129
Id.
130
Id.
131
Stigler Report at 38.
132
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00063222 (Feb.
27, 2012), https://judiciary.house.gov/uploadedfiles/0006322000063223.pdf.
133
See Stigler Report at 40.
134
See Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 35.
monopolization.
126
There are two types of network effects: direct
and indirect. In markets with direct network effects, the more peo-
ple who use a product or service, the more valuable that product
or service becomes to other users.
127
By contrast, indirect network
effects arise when greater use of a product or service forms a new
type of standard and increases the incentive for third parties to in-
vest in developing compatible technologies, which in turn reinforces
the popularity of the original product or service with users.
128
Online platforms display strong network effects because they
connect disparate market segments. For example, online commerce
platforms like Amazon connect buyers and sellers. Just as with so-
cial networks, the value of Amazon Marketplace increases as more
users—both sellers and buyers—engage with the plat-
form.
129
Similarly, the value of online platforms that facilitate ad-
vertising, such as Google, increases with the number of users, as
advertisers gain access to a larger consumer base and therefore to
a larger trove of consumer data.
130
Similarly, social networks like Facebook exhibit powerful direct
network effects because they become more valuable as more users
engage with the network—no person wants to be on a social net-
work without other users.
131
Meanwhile, once a firm captures a
network it can become extremely difficult to dislodge or replace. As
Mark Zuckerberg explained to then-CFO David Ebersman the ben-
efits that would accrue to Facebook from acquiring Instagram:
[T]here are network effects around social products and a finite number of dif-
ferent social mechanics to invent. Once someone wins at a specific mechanic, it’s
difficult for others to supplant them without doing something different. It’s pos-
sible someone beats Instagram by building something that is better to the point
that they get network migration, but this is harder as long as Instagram keeps
running as a product.
132
Strong network effects serve as a powerful barrier to entry for
new firms to enter a market and displace the incumbent.
133
When
combined with other entry barriers such as restrictions on con-
sumers or businesses easily switching services, network effects all
but ensure not just market concentration but durable market
power.
134
(b) Switching Costs. Switching costs present another barrier for
potential market entrants. In many cases, large technology firms
can maintain market power in part because it is not easy for users
to switch away from the incumbent’s technology. A market exhibits
‘‘lock-in’’ when switching costs are sufficiently high that users stay
with an incumbent firm rather than switch to a firm whose product
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00037 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
32
135
M
AURICE
E. S
TUCKE &
A
LLEN
P. G
RUNES
, B
IG
D
ATA AND
C
OMPETITION
P
OLICY
159 (2016).
136
Id.
137
Data and Privacy Hearing at 134 (statement of Dina Srinivasan, Fellow, Yale Thurman
Arnold Project).
138
Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 36. Unlike the European Union, which provides
internet users with a right to data portability, the U.S. does not have any law requiring online
platforms to make data portable. Platforms like Google and Facebook are therefore largely unin-
hibited in imposing switching costs for users, hurting competition in the process. Allen St. John,
Europe’s GDPR Brings Data Portability to U.S. Consumers, C
ONSUMER
R
EPS
. (May 25, 2018),
https://www.consumerreports.org/privacy/gdpr-brings-data-portability-to-us-consumers; see also
Chris Dixon, The Interoperability of Social Networks, B
US
. I
NSIDER
(Nov. 10, 2010), https://
www.businessinsider.com/the-interoperability-of-social-networks-2011-2; Josh Constine, Friend
Portability Is the Must-Have Facebook Regulation, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(May 12, 2019), https://
technologycrunch.com/2019/05/12/friends-wherever.
139
Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 23.
140
Maurice E. Stucke, Should We Be Concerned About Data-opolies?, 2 G
EO
. L. T
ECH
. R
EV
.
275, 323 (2018) (discussing the dynamics of data-driven network effects).
141
M
AURICE
E. S
TUCKE &
A
LLEN
P. G
RUNES
, B
IG
D
ATA AND
C
OMPETITION
P
OLICY
36–50
(2016); Patrick Barwise & Leo Watkins, The Evolution of Digital Dominance: How and Why We
Got to GAFA, in D
IGITAL
D
OMINANT
: T
HE
P
OWER OF
G
OOGLE
, A
MAZON
, F
ACEBOOK
,
AND
A
PPLE
21, 28–29 (2018), http://www.lse.ac.uk/law/Assets/Documents/orla-lynskey/orla-3.pdf.
142
M
AURICE
E. S
TUCKE &
A
LLEN
P. G
RUNES
, B
IG
D
ATA AND
C
OMPETITION
P
OLICY
23–34
(2016).
143
Id. at 34.
or service they would prefer.
135
Over time, lock-in tends to reduce
competition, deter market entry, and may even worsen data pri-
vacy.
136
High switching costs are a central feature of digital search and
social media platforms, such as Google and Facebook, where users
contribute data to the platform but may not be able to migrate that
data to a competing platform. For example, a user may upload a
variety of data to Facebook, including photos and personal informa-
tion, but may not be able to easily download that data and move
it to another social media site; instead, the user would have to
start from scratch, re-uploading her photos and re-entering her per-
sonal information to the new platform.
137
An online seller who has
generated hundreds of product reviews and ratings on Amazon may
face a similar challenge when considering migrating to a different
platform. Other significant factors that contribute to switching
costs in digital markets include anticompetitive contracting terms,
default settings, and product design that favor dominant plat-
forms.
138
(c) Data. The accumulation of data can serve as another powerful
barrier to entry for firms in the digital economy. Data allows com-
panies to target advertising with scalpel-like precision, improve
services and products through a better understanding of user en-
gagement and preferences, and more quickly identify and exploit
new business opportunities.
139
Much like a network effect, data-rich accumulation is self-rein-
forcing. Companies with superior access to data can use that data
to better target users or improve product quality, drawing more
users and, in turn, generating more data—an advantageous feed-
back loop.
140
In short, new users and greater engagement bring in
more data, which enables firms to improve user experiences and
develop new products—in turn capturing more data.
141
While data
is non-rivalrous—meaning that one party’s use does not prevent or
diminish use by another—firms may nonetheless exclude rivals
from using their data through technical restrictions and legal con-
tracts.
142
These exclusionary tactics can close off markets and
shield incumbents from competition.
143
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00038 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
33
144
J
ACQUES
C
RE
´
MER
, Y
VES
-A
LEXANDRE DE
M
ONJOYE &
H
EIKE
S
CWHEITZER
, E
UR
. C
OMM
N
,
C
OMPETITION
P
OLICY FOR THE
D
IGITAL
E
RA
66–67 (2019) [hereinafter Eur. Comm’n Competition
Report].
145
Id. at 66.
146
See Dina Srinivasan, The Antitrust Case Against Facebook: A Monopolist’s Journey To-
wards Pervasive Surveillance in Spite of Consumers’ Preference for Privacy, 16 B
ERKELEY
B
US
.
L.J. 39, 70 (2019); Data and Privacy Hearing at 132 (statement of Dina Srinivasan, Fellow, Yale
Thurman Arnold Project).
147
Interview with Source 247 (June 4, 2020).
148
Roger McNamee, Co-Founder & Managing Dir., Elevation Partners, Remarks at Venture
Capital and Antitrust Workshop 30 (Feb. 12, 2020), https://www.justice.gov/atr/page/file/
1255851/download.
149
See, e.g., Stigler Report at 74, 87.
150
See Maurice E. Stucke, Should We Be Concerned About Data-opolies?, 2 G
EO
. L. T
ECH
.
R
EV
. 275, 309 (2018) (discussing the growing concern with ‘‘kill zone’’ tactics and the chilling
effect on ‘‘entrepreneurism and autonomy’’).
In addition to serving as a barrier to entry, superior access to
data can enable and exacerbate anticompetitive conduct in digital
markets. This is particularly true when a dominant platform oper-
ates as both a marketplace for third-party goods as well as a seller
of its own products on that same marketplace.
144
Through this dual
role, a dominant platform can mine commercially valuable informa-
tion from third-party businesses to benefit its own competing prod-
ucts.
145
Additionally, a dominant platform can use its market
power to extract more data from users, undermining their pri-
vacy.
146
Persistent data collection can also create information asym-
metries and grant firms access to non-public information that gives
them a significant competitive edge. These insights include infor-
mation on user behavior as well as on broader usage trends that
enable the dominant platforms to track nascent competitive
threats. In an interview with the Subcommittee, a senior executive
at a social media company referred to this ability as akin to having
‘‘a spy camera on the production floor’’ of a competitive threat.
147
Roger McNamee, the Co-Founder of Elevation Partners, has noted
that the dominant platforms’ role as digital infrastructure gives
them both leverage and insights that other competitors lack:
Essentially, the interplay of Google’s dominant position in . . . infrastructure ele-
ments [such as] ad tech infrastructure, Chrome browser, [and Nest] . . . collec-
tively provide leverage over other market participants, which include not just
startups, but also advertisers, and other would-be competitors. And the key thing
is, it’s not just about Google’s infrastructure. When you add in Gmail, Search,
Maps, apps, and all the other things that Google does so well . . . [t]hey provide
further levels of user lock-in-further protective modes that really limit the oppor-
tunity of competitors and even, frankly, suppliers and advertisers, to do the
things that they should be able to do in a freely competitive economy.
148
This significant data advantage also enables dominant platforms
to identify and acquire rivals early in their lifecycle. Leading econo-
mists and antitrust experts have expressed concern that serial ac-
quisitions of nascent competitors by large technology firms have
stifled competition and innovation.
149
This acquisition strategy ex-
ploits dominant firms’ information advantages in order to acquire
rapidly growing companies just before those companies become true
threats.
150
Lacking access to this same information or failing to ap-
preciate its significance, enforcers may fail to identify these acqui-
sitions as anticompetitive. This is more likely when the dominant
platform buys a nascent threat before it has fully developed into a
rival.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00039 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
34
151
Briefing by Jonathan Sallet, Deputy Assistant Att’y Gen., U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Antitrust
Div. (July 11, 2020).
152
Colleen Cunningham, Florian Ederer & Song Ma, Killer Acquisitions 53 (Yale Sch. of
Mgmt., Working Paper, Apr. 2020), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3241707 (finding that killer ac-
quisitions ‘‘routinely avoid regulatory scrutiny’’ because they ‘‘disproportionately occur just below
[HSR] thresholds for antitrust scrutiny’’).
153
Jonathan Sallet, Competitive Edge: Five Building Blocks For Antitrust Success: The Forth-
coming FTC Competition Report, W
ASH
. C
TR
.
FOR
E
QUITABLE
G
ROWTH
(Oct. 1, 2019), https://
equitablegrowth.org/competitive-edge-five-building-blocks-for-antitrust-success-the-forthcoming-
ftc-competition-report/.
154
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 81 (statement of Fiona Scott Morton, Theo-
dore Nierenberg Prof. of Econ., Yale Sch. of Mgmt.); Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at
32; Stigler Report at 13; see also J
AY
S
HAMBAUGH
, R
YAN
N
UNN
, A
UDREY
B
REITWIESER &
P
ATRICK
L
IU
, T
HE
B
ROOKINGS
I
NST
., T
HE
S
TATE OF
C
OMPETITION AND
D
YNAMISM
: F
ACTS
A
BOUT
C
ON
-
CENTRATION
, S
TART
-U
PS
,
AND
R
ELATED
P
OLICIES
10 (2018), https://www.brookings.edu/wp-
content/uploads/2018/06/ESlTHPl20180611lCompetitionFactsl20180611.pdf.
155
Stigler Report at 36.
156
Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 32.
157
Id.
158
Stigler Report at 37.
159
Id.
In a briefing before Members of the Subcommittee, Jonathan
Sallet, former Deputy Assistant Attorney General at the Antitrust
Division, explained that data-driven acquisitions of nascent or po-
tential rivals can significantly undermine competition while sys-
tematically evading antitrust scrutiny.
151
One reason is that up-
start competitors are often data-rich but cash-poor, a combination
that is unlikely under a price-centric framework to trigger antitrust
scrutiny if the acquisition is priced below the relevant threshold for
merger review.
152
For example, had Microsoft sought to exploit its
monopoly power in the market for personal computer operating sys-
tems by acquiring Netscape—rather than by foreclosing it—it is
unlikely that antitrust enforcers would have taken action. He noted
that this type of acquisition can tip the market in favor of a domi-
nant firm, having the same ultimate effect as monopolistic conduct
but escaping the antitrust enforcement that monopolistic conduct
has triggered in the past.
153
(d) Economies of Scale and Scope. Increasing returns to scale are
another feature of technology markets that make them prone to tip
towards concentration and monopolization.
154
In markets with in-
creasing returns to scale, as sales increase, average unit cost de-
creases.
155
Because entry into these markets requires significant
up-front costs, the market favors firms that are already large, mak-
ing it difficult for new firms to enter the market and challenge
large incumbents.
156
Likewise, a dominant firm that enjoys economies of scope can ex-
tend its reach across adjacent markets through an expansive eco-
system of its own products while incurring relatively low cost.
157
For example, if a firm has sufficient technical expertise or access
to consumer data, the cost of applying this resource into a new
market is relatively low.
Businesses that specialize in providing information, such as
Google, frequently benefit from increasing returns to scale.
158
These businesses require high upfront fixed costs, but then may
scale with relatively low increases in cost. For example, ‘‘Google
can update Google Calendar for 100 million users with similar
fixed expenses as would be needed for only a fraction of such
users.’’
159
Facebook is another company that benefits from increas-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00040 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
35
160
Id.
161
Id. at 36–37.
162
See generally Dirk Bergemann, Alessandro Bonatti & Tan Gan, The Economics of Social
Data (Cowles Found., Discussion Paper No. 2203R, Sept. 2019), https://ssrn.com/abstract
=3459796.
163
Id. at 4.
164
See, e.g., Erik Brynjolfsson & Avinash Collis, How Should We Measure the Digital Econ-
omy?, H
ARV
. B
US
. R
EV
. (Nov.–Dec. 2019), https://hbr.org/2019/11/how-should-we-measure-the-
digital-economy.
165
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 76 (statement of Tim Wu, Julius Silver Prof.
of Law, Columbia Univ. Sch. of Law).
166
Id.
167
Stigler Report at 74.
168
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 76 (statement of Tim Wu, Julius Silver Prof.
of Law, Columbia Univ. Sch. of Law).
169
This trend is also present in the broader U.S. economy as well. See, e.g., Ufuk Akcigit &
Sina T. Ates, Knowledge in the Hands of the Best, Not the Rest: The Decline of U.S. Business
Dynamism, V
OX
EU (July 4, 2019), https://voxeu.org/article/decline-us-business-dynamism.
ing returns to scale.
160
Although building the Facebook platform
required a large upfront investment, the platform was able to grow
exponentially with relatively little increase in costs. With the ben-
efit of increasing returns to scale, Facebook was able to grow from
one million users in 2004, the year of its founding, to more than
350 million users in only five years.
161
Recent economic evidence indicates that economies of scale
achieved through data collection allow platforms to get more out of
consumers than consumers get out of platforms.
162
In exchange for
‘‘free’’ services, users provide valuable social data—information
that may also shed light on other people’s behavior—in addition to
their own personal information. For instance, a person’s location
history using Google Maps reveals valuable and sensitive informa-
tion about others as well—such as traffic patterns and other data.
According to Professors Dirk Bergemann, Alessandro Bonatti, and
Tan Gan, the creation of this ‘‘data externality’’ means that, for
firms like Google, Amazon, and Facebook, ‘‘the cost of acquiring . . .
individual data can be substantially below the value of the infor-
mation to the platform.’’
163
In other words, notwithstanding claims
that services such as Google’s Search or Maps products or Facebook
are ‘‘free’’ or have immeasurable economic value to consumers,
164
the social data gathered through these services may exceed their
economic value to consumers.
B. Effects of Platform Market Power
1. Innovation and Entrepreneurship
Competition is a critical source of innovation, business dyna-
mism, entrepreneurship, and the ‘‘launching of new industries.’’
165
Vigorously contested markets have been a critical competitive asset
for the United States over the past century.
166
While large firms
with significant resources may invest in research and development
for new products and services, competition forces companies to ‘‘run
faster’’ in order to offer improved products and services.
167
Without
competitive pressure, some level of innovation may still occur, but
at a slower, iterative pace than would be present under competitive
market conditions.
168
In recent decades, however, there has been a sharp decline in
new business formation as well as early-stage startup funding.
169
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00041 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
36
170
I
AN
H
ATHWAY
, E
WING
M
ARION
K
AUFFMAN
F
OUND
., T
ECH
S
TARTS
: H
IGH
-T
ECHNOLOGY
B
USINESS
F
ORMATION AND
J
OB
C
REATION IN THE
U
NITED
S
TATES
5 (2013), https://www
.kauffman.org/-/media/kauffmanlorg/research-reports-and-covers/2013/08/bdstechnology
startsreport.pdf.
171
Id.
172
The number of technology startup financings fell from above 10,000 startup financings in
2015 to just above 6,000 in 2018. In 2014, startups closed 4,255 deals in which they raised seed
money from investors. By 2018, however, that figure had dropped by nearly a half, to 2,206.
Gene
´
Teare, Decade in Review: Trends in Seed- and Early-Stage Funding, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Mar.
13, 2019), https://technologycrunch.com/2019/03/16/decade-in-review-trends-in-seed-and-early-
stage-funding. See also American Technology Giants Are Making Life Tough for Startups, E
CON
-
OMIST
(June 2, 2018), https://www.economist.com/business/2018/06/02/american-technology-
giants-are-making-life-tough-for-startups.
173
J
OHN
H
ALTIWANGER ET AL
., E
WING
M
ARION
K
AUFFMAN
F
OUND
., D
ECLINING
B
USINESS
D
Y
-
NAMISM IN THE
U.S. H
IGH
-T
ECHNOLOGY
S
ECTOR
8 (2014).
174
Id.
175
Id.
176
Id. at 4.
177
Id. at 5.
178
Id. at 4.
179
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 76 (statement of Tim Wu, Julius Silver Prof.
of Law, Columbia Univ. Sch. of Law); Data and Privacy Hearing at 58–60 (statement of Jason
Furman, Prof. of the Prac. of Econ. Pol’y, Harvard Kennedy Sch.).
180
See generally Venture Capital and Antitrust Workshop; Stigler Report at 9.
181
Raghuram Rajan, Sai Krishna Kamepalli & Luigi Zingales, Kill Zone (Univ. of Chi., Beck-
er Friedman Inst. for Econ., Working Paper No. 2020–19, Apr. 2020).
182
Asher Schechter, Google and Facebook’s ‘‘Kill Zone’’: ‘‘We’ve Taken the Focus Off of Reward-
ing Genius and Innovation to Rewarding Capital and Scale,’’ P
RO
M
ARKET
(May 25, 2018),
Continued
The number of new technology firms in the digital economy has de-
clined,
170
while the entrepreneurship rate—the share of startups
and young firms in the industry as a whole—has also fallen signifi-
cantly in this market.
171
Unsurprisingly, there has also been a
sharp reduction in early-stage funding for technology startups.
172
The rates of entrepreneurship and job creation have also declined
over this period. The entrepreneurship rate—defined as the ‘‘share
of startups and young firms’’ in the industry as a whole—fell from
60 percent in 1982 to a low of 38 percent as of 2011.
173
As entry
slows, the average age of technology firms has skewed older.
174
Job
creation in the high-technology sector has likewise slowed consider-
ably.
175
In 2000, the job creation rate in the high-technology sector
was approaching 20 percent year-over-year. Within a decade, the
rate had halved to about 10 percent.
176
Although the job creation
rate in the high-technology sector has fallen substantially since the
early 2000s, the job destruction rate in 2011 was roughly un-
changed from 2000.
177
As a result, in 2011 the rate of job destruc-
tion in the high-technology sector was higher than the rate of job
creation, a reversal from the year 2000, when the job-creation rate
far outpaced the job-destruction rate.
178
In line with this trend, there is mounting evidence that the domi-
nance of online platforms has materially weakened innovation and
entrepreneurship in the U.S. economy.
179
Some venture capitalists,
for example, report that they avoid funding entrepreneurs and
other companies that compete directly with dominant firms in the
digital economy.
180
Often referred to as an innovation ‘‘kill zone,’’ this trend may in-
sulate powerful incumbent firms from competitive pressure simply
because venture capitalists do not view new entrants as good in-
vestments.
181
Albert Wenger, the managing partner of Union
Square Ventures, commented that the ‘‘scale of these companies
and their impact on what can be funded, and what can succeed, is
massive.’’
182
Paul Arnold, an early-stage investor and founder of
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00042 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
37
https://promarket.org/2018/05/25/google-facebooks-kill-zone-weve-taken-focus-off-rewarding-
genius-innovation-rewarding-capital-scale/.
183
Venture Capital and Antitrust Workshop at 24 (statement of Paul Arnold, Founder &
Partner, Switch Partners).
184
Id.
185
Submission from Paul Arnold, General Partner, Switch Ventures, to H. Comm. on the Ju-
diciary, 2 (Sept. 3, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
186
Venture Capital and Antitrust Workshop at 24 (Paul Arnold, Founder & Partner, Switch
Partners).
187
Id.
188
Id. at 29 (statement of Roger McNamee, Cofounder & Managing Dir., Elevation Partners).
189
Raghuram Rajan, Sai Krishna Kamepalli & Luigi Zingales, Kill Zone (Univ. of Chi., Beck-
er Friedman Inst. for Econ., Working Paper No. 2020–19, Apr. 2020).
190
Id.
Switch Ventures, commented at the Justice Department’s recent
workshop on the intersection between venture capital and antitrust
law that he considers markets dominated by large platforms to be
kill zones.
183
He explained:
[T]here’s an incredibly, concentrated market share because of the economies of
scale or because of network effects, it’s a really hard barrier to overcome. And
sometimes there’s an answer and often, that will kill things. And I think that
that’s my view, that’s my, sort of, lived experience as a venture investor, but I
think it’s a common view of a lot of venture investors.
184
In the same vein, Mr. Arnold said in a submission to the Sub-
committee that:
Venture capitalists are less likely to fund startups that compete against monopo-
lies’ core products .... As a startup investor, I see this often. For example, I will
meet yet another founder who wants to disrupt Microsoft’s LinkedIn. They will
have a clever plan to build a better professional social network. I always pass
on the investment. It is nearly impossible to overcome the monopoly LinkedIn
enjoys. It is but one example of an innovation kill zone.
185
For example, the entrenched power of firms with weak privacy
protections has created a kill zone around the market for products
that enhance privacy online.
186
To the extent that a firm success-
fully offers a service to give people tools to control their privacy,
‘‘Google or Facebook are going to want to pull that back as fast as
they possibly can. They don’t want you aggressively limiting their
extremely valuable information collection.’’
187
Other prominent venture capitalists, such as Roger McNamee,
the Co-Founder of Elevation Partners, have commented that these
trends harm more than just startups. The advantages of dominant
firms online—access to competitively significant sources of data,
network effects, intellectual property, and excess capital—are ‘‘a
barrier to a wide range of activities, not just startups, but actually
a lot of other market participants.’’
188
Merger activity may be another contributor to reduced venture
capital investment of startups. In a recent study, several leading
economists and researchers at the University of Chicago—
Raghuram G. Rajan, Luigi Zingales, and Sai Krishna Kamepalli—
found that major acquisitions by larger firms in sectors of the dig-
ital economy led to significantly less investment in startups in this
same sector.
189
As they note, in the wake of an acquisition by
Facebook or Google, investments in startups in the same space
‘‘drop by over 40% and the number of deals falls by over 20% in
the three years following an acquisition.’’
190
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00043 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
38
191
See Wen Wen & Feng Zhu, Threat of Platform-Owner Entry and Complementor Responses:
Evidence from the Mobile App Market, 40 S
TRATEGIC
M
GMT
. J. 1336 (2019); Feng Zhu & Qihong
Liu, Competing with Complementors: An Empirical Look at Amazon.com, 39 S
TRATEGIC
M
GMT
.
J. 2618 (2018).
192
Id.
193
Interview with Source 146 (May 28, 2020).
194
Raghuram Rajan, Sai Krishna Kamepalli & Luigi Zingales, Kill Zone (Univ. of Chi., Beck-
er Friedman Inst. for Econ., Working Paper No. 2020–19, Apr. 2020).
195
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 81 (statement of Fiona Scott Morton, Theo-
dore Nierenberg Prof. of Econ., Yale Sch. of Mgmt.).
196
Id. at 74 (statement of Tim Wu, Julius Silver Prof. of Law, Columbia Univ. Sch. of Law).
197
Id. at 81 (statement of Fiona Scott Morton, Theodore Nierenberg Prof. of Econ., Yale Sch.
of Mgmt.); Data and Privacy Hearing at 60 (statement of Jason Furman, Prof. of the Prac. of
Econ. Pol’y, Harvard Kennedy Sch.) (‘‘[M]ajor platforms have reduced incentives to innovate and
incumbents have distorted incentives to make more incremental improvements that can be in-
corporated into the dominant platforms rather than more paradigmatic changes that could chal-
lenge these platforms.’’).
The threat of entry from a large platform has had significant ef-
fects on other firms’ incentives to innovate,
191
while the actual
entry of the larger online platform can result in less innovation and
an additional increase in prices.
192
During the investigation, a
prominent venture capital investor in the cloud marketplace ex-
plained that this power imbalance creates a strong economic incen-
tive for other firms to avoid head-on competition. As he noted:
I think of Amazon as the sun. It is useful but also dangerous. If you’re far
enough away you can bask. If you get too close you’ll get incinerated. So, you
have to be far enough from Amazon and be doing something that they wouldn’t
do. If you’re a net consumer of Amazon’s infrastructure, like Uber, then you’re
okay. As long as Amazon doesn’t want to get into ridesharing. But it’s hard to
predict what Amazon wants to get into. If they were going to stop at retail and
computing, you’re safe. But you can’t know.
193
As discussed in this Report, other behavior by dominant firms—
such as cloning the products of new entrants—may also undermine
the likelihood that new entrants will be able to compete directly or
that early adopters will switch to a new entrant’s product, lowering
the valuation of these companies as well as their profitability.
194
In July 2019, the Subcommittee held a hearing to examine the
effects of market power on innovation and entrepreneurship. There,
a panel of experts noted that the lack of competitive pressure in
the U.S. economy has reduced innovation and business formation,
while also allowing dominant firms to control innovation.
195
Pro-
fessor Tim Wu of Columbia Law School, a pioneer in internet pol-
icy, said that there is:
[N]o question as to whether there were barriers to entry and whether the tech
economies have, in fact, become a very difficult place for people to get started
. . . the decline in the number of startups, almost unthinkable in the United
States, which has always had a comparative advantage in being the place where
startups will get their start.
196
Professor Fiona Scott Morton of the Yale University School of Man-
agement reinforced this concept in her testimony, noting that insuf-
ficient competition has given dominant firms the ability to channel
innovation in the direction they prefer ‘‘rather than being cre-
atively spread across directions chosen by entrants.’’
197
In addition to innovation harms in the digital marketplace, Stacy
Mitchell, the Co-Director of the Institute for Local Self Reliance,
explained that entrepreneurism among locally owned businesses
has also suffered as a result of this power. As she noted, ‘‘Local
businesses are disappearing and, with them, a pathway to the mid-
dle class. Producers are struggling to invest in new products and
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00044 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
39
198
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 187 (statement of Stacy F. Mitchell, Co-Dir.,
Inst. for Local Self-Reliance).
199
Competitors Hearing at 7 (statement of Patrick Spence, CEO, Sonos, Inc.).
200
Id. at 8.
201
Id. at 20 (statement of David Barnett, Founder & CEO, PopSockets LLC).
202
Id. at 57.
203
Howard A. Shelanski, Information, Innovation, and Competition Policy for the Internet, 161
U. P
A
. L. R
EV
. 1663, 1689 (2013) (‘‘One measure of a platform’s market power is the extent to
which it can engage in [privacy exploitation] without some benefit to consumers that offsets
their reduced privacy and still retain users.’’).
204
W. K
IP
V
ISCUSI ET AL
., E
CONOMICS OF
R
EGULATION AND
A
NTITRUST
164 (3d ed. 2000).
205
Data and Privacy Hearing at 60 (statement of Jason Furman, Prof. of the Prac. of Econ.
Pol’y, Harvard Kennedy Sch.); id. at 55 (statement of Tommaso Valletti, Prof. of Econ., Imperial
Coll. Bus. Sch.).
206
Howard A. Shelanski, Information, Innovation, and Competition Policy for the Internet, 161
U. P
A
. L. R
EV
. 1663, 1687 (2013) (‘‘While increased competition, at least on its own, will not
always cause firms to better use or protect customer information, any competitive effects anal-
ysis that misses these two nonprice dimensions of platform market performance will be incom-
plete and could be biased toward underenforcement.’’).
grow their companies. New business formation is down to historic
lows.’’
198
At the Subcommittee’s field hearing, senior executives rep-
resenting different businesses across the economic spectrum offered
similar testimony about the effects of market power on innovation
and entrepreneurship. Patrick Spence, the CEO of Sonos, testified
that the lack of fair competition diminishes innovation, particularly
for firms that cannot afford to sell products at a loss.
199
He ex-
plained:
These companies have gone so far as demanding that we suppress our inventions
in order to work with them. The most recent example of this is Google’s refusal
to allow us to use multiple voice assistants on our product simultaneously ....
I think the whole spirit of trying to encourage small companies, encourage new
innovations and new startups is at risk, given how dominant these companies
are.
200
Furthermore, the ability of a dominant firm to extract economic
concessions from smaller companies that rely on it to reach the
market can also depress innovation. David Barnett, the CEO and
Founder of PopSockets, testified at the field hearing that Amazon
required his company ‘‘to pay almost two million in marketing dol-
lars in order to remove illegal product from the Amazon market-
place.’’
201
In response to questions from Representative Ken Buck
(R–CO) on the effect of this policy on innovation, Mr. Barnett testi-
fied that this money could have been used to double the number
of employees dedicated to developing innovative products at the
company.
202
2. Privacy and Data Protection
The persistent collection and misuse of consumer data is an indi-
cator of market power in the digital economy.
203
Traditionally,
market power has been defined as the ability to raise prices with-
out a loss to demand, such as fewer sales or customers.
204
Scholars
and market participants have noted that even as online platforms
rarely charge consumers a monetary price—products appear to be
‘‘free’’ but are monetized through people’s attention or with their
data
205
—traditional assessments of market power are more dif-
ficult to apply to digital markets.
206
The best evidence of platform market power therefore is not
prices charged but rather the degree to which platforms have erod-
ed consumer privacy without prompting a response from the mar-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00045 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
40
207
See, e.g., Makan Delrahim, Assistant Att’y Gen., U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Antitrust Div., Re-
marks for the Antitrust New Frontiers Conference (June 11, 2019), https://www.justice.gov/
opa/speech/assistant-attorney-general-makan-delrahim-delivers-remarks-antitrust-new-frontiers
(‘‘It is well-settled, however, that competition has price and non-price dimensions.’’); Maurice E.
Stucke & Ariel Ezrachi, When Competition Fails to Optimize Quality: A Look at Search Engines,
18 Y
ALE
J.L.
&
T
ECH
. 70, 103 (2016); E
LEONORA
O
CELLO &
C
RISTINA
S
JOODIN
, E
UR
. C
OMM
N
,
C
OMPETITION
M
ERGER
B
RIEF
: M
ICROSOFT
/L
INKED
I
N
: B
IG
D
ATA AND
C
ONGLOMERATE
E
FFECTS IN
T
ECH
M
ARKETS
5 (2017), http://ec.europa.eu/competition/publications/cmb/2017/kdal17001
enn.pdf.
208
Dina Srinivasan, The Antitrust Case Against Facebook: A Monopolist’s Journey Towards
Pervasive Surveillance in Spite of Consumers’ Preference for Privacy, 16 B
ERKELEY
B
US
. L.J. 39,
44 (2019) (‘‘Facebook is a monopolist, and what Facebook extracts overtly from consumers today,
from a quality perspective, is a direct function of Facebook’s monopoly power.’’); see also Kath-
arine Kemp, Concealed Data Practices and Competition Law: Why Privacy Matters (Univ. of
N.S.W., Fac. of Law, Research Paper No. 19–53, 2019), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers
.cfm?abstractlid=3432769; OECD, B
IG
D
ATA
: B
RINGING
C
OMPETITION
P
OLICY TO THE
D
IGITAL
E
RA
(2016), https://one.oecd.org/document/DAF/COMP(2016)14/en/pdf.
209
Data and Privacy Hearing at 55 (statement of Tommaso Valletti, Prof. of Econ., Imperial
Coll. Bus. Sch.); Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 42–45.
210
David N. Cicilline & Terrell McSweeny, Competition Is at the Heart of Facebook’s Privacy
Problem, W
IRED
(Apr. 24, 2018), https://www.wired.com/story/competition-is-at-the-heart-of-
facebooks-privacy-problem.
211
Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 43 (‘‘[T]he misuse of consumer data and harm
to privacy is arguably an indicator of low quality caused by a lack of competition.’’); Dina
Srinivasan, The Antitrust Case Against Facebook: A Monopolist’s Journey Towards Pervasive
Surveillance in Spite of Consumers’ Preference for Privacy, 16 B
ERKELEY
B
US
. L.J. 39, 40 (2019)
(‘‘Consumers effectively face a singular choice-use Facebook and submit to the quality and stipu-
lations of Facebook’s product or forgo all use of the only social network.’’).
212
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 318.
213
Giuseppe Colangelo & Mariateresa Maggiolino, Data Protection in Attention Markets: Pro-
tecting Privacy through Competition?, 8 J.
OF
E
UR
. C
OMPETITION
L.
&
P
RAC
. 363, 365 (2017).
214
Data and Privacy Hearing at 135 (statement of Dina Srinivasan, Fellow, Yale Thurman
Arnold Project); Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 82 (statement of Fiona Scott Mor-
ton, Theodore Nierenberg Prof. of Econ., Yale Sch. of Mgmt.).
215
Data and Privacy Hearing at 59 (statement of Jason Furman, Prof. of the Prac. of Econ.
Pol’y, Harvard Kennedy Sch.); id. at 55 (statement of Tommaso Valletti, Prof. of Econ., Imperial
Coll. Bus. Sch.); Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 4 (‘‘It can be harder for new companies
to enter or scale up.’’); Giuseppe Colangelo & Mariateresa Maggiolino, Data Protection in Atten-
tion Markets: Protecting Privacy Through Competition?, 8 J.
OF
E
UR
. C
OMPETITION
L.
&
P
RAC
.
363, 365 (2017) (‘‘Similarly, in such a market, a dominant firm could abuse its power to exclude
a rival producing privacy-friendly goods that consumer would otherwise prefer.’’); Stigler Report
at 67 (‘‘When facing a zero-money price, and when quality is difficult to observe, consumers
Continued
ket.
207
As scholars have noted, a platform’s ability to maintain
strong networks while degrading user privacy can reasonably be
considered equivalent to a monopolist’s decision to increase prices
or reduce product quality.
208
A firm’s dominance can enable it to
abuse consumers’ privacy without losing customers.
209
In the ab-
sence of genuine competitive threats, a firm offers fewer privacy
protections than it otherwise would. In the process, it extracts more
data, further entrenching its dominance.
210
When paired with the
tendency toward winner-take-all outcomes, consumers are forced to
either use a service with poor privacy safeguards or forgo the serv-
ice altogether.
211
As the United Kingdom’s Competition and Mar-
kets Authority observes, ‘‘The collection and use of personal data
by Google and Facebook for personalised advertising, in many cases
with no or limited controls available to consumers, is another indi-
cation that these platforms do not face a strong enough competitive
constraint.’’
212
Given the increasingly critical role platforms play in mediating
access to everyday goods and services, users are also far more like-
ly to surrender more information than to cease using the service
entirely.
213
Without adequate competition, firms are able to collect
more data than a competitive market would allow,
214
further en-
trenching their market power while diminishing privacy in the
process.
215
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00046 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
41
are not receiving salient signals about the social value of their consumption because the price
they believe they face does not reflect the economics of the transaction, and they are ignorant
of those numbers.’’).
216
Data and Privacy Hearing at 54–55 (statement of Tommaso Valletti, Prof. of Econ., Impe-
rial Coll. Bus. Sch.).
217
Maurice E. Stucke, Should We Be Concerned About Data-opolies?, 2 G
EO
. L. T
ECH
. R
EV
.
275, 311 (2018).
218
See, e.g., Paul Hitlin & Lee Rainie, Facebook Algorithms and Personal Data, P
EW
R
SCH
.
C
TR
. (Jan. 16. 2019), https://www.pewinternet.org/2019/01/16/facebook-algorithms-and-
personal-data/. See A
USTL
. C
OMPETITION &
C
ONSUMER
C
OMM
N
, D
IGITAL
P
LATFORMS
I
NQUIRY
F
INAL
R
EPORT
11 (2019) [hereinafter Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n Report]; Ryan
Calo & Alex Rosenblat, The Taking Economy: Uber, Information, and Power, 117 C
OLUM
. L.
R
EV
. 1623 (2017); Dina Srinivasan, The Antitrust Case Against Facebook: A Monopolist’s Journey
Towards Pervasive Surveillance in Spite of Consumers’ Preference for Privacy, 16 B
ERKELEY
B
US
.
L.J. 39, 41 (2019) (‘‘[A]ccepting Facebook’s policies in order to use its service means accepting
broad-scale commercial surveillance.’’).
219
Arvind Narayanan, Arunesh Mathur, Marshini Chetty & Mihir Kshirsagar, Dark Patterns:
Past, Present, and Future, 18(2) ACM Q
UEUE
67, 77 (2020), https://queue.acm.org/detail.cfm
?id=3400901.
220
Id.; N
ORWEGIAN
C
ONSUMER
C
OUNCIL
, D
ECEIVED BY
D
ESIGN
(2018), https://fil
.forbrukerradet.no/wp-content/uploads/2018/06/2018-06-27-deceived-by-design-final.pdf (de-
scribing the use of ‘‘dark patterns’’).
221
Jamie Luguri & Lior Strahilevitz, Shining a Light on Dark Patterns 29 (Univ. of Chi. Law
Sch. Pub. Law Working Paper, Paper No. 719, 2019), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm
?abstractlid=3431205.
222
Mark Bergen, Google Really Wants You to Try Its New Video Tool, B
LOOMBERG
(May 19,
2020), https://www.bloomberg.com/news/newsletters/2020-05-19/google-really-wants-you-to-try-
its-new-video-tool.
223
Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 45; David N. Cicilline & Terrell McSweeny, Com-
petition Is at the Heart of Facebook’s Privacy Problem, W
IRED
(Apr. 24, 2018), https://
www.wired.com/story/competition-is-at-the-heart-of-facebooks-privacy-problem.
Because persistent data collection online is often concealed,
216
it
is more difficult to compare privacy costs across different products
and services.
217
Consumers are largely unaware of firms’ data col-
lection practices, which are presented in dense and lengthy disclo-
sures.
218
The use of manipulative design interfaces has also become
a pervasive tool ‘‘to increase the likelihood of users consenting to
tracking.’’
219
These behavioral nudges—referred to as dark pat-
terns—are commonly used in online tracking and advertising mar-
kets to enhance a firm’s market power and ‘‘maximize a company’s
ability to extract revenue from its users.’’
220
And in e-commerce,
Jamie Luguri and Lior Strahilevitz observe that dark patterns ‘‘are
harming consumers by convincing them to surrender cash or per-
sonal data in deals that do not reflect consumers’ actual pref-
erences and may not serve their interests. There appears to be a
substantial market failure where dark patterns are concerned—
what is good for ecommerce profits is bad for consumers.’’
221
More recently, as remote work became commonplace during the
COVID–19 pandemic, Google attempted to manipulate users into
using its Google Meet videoconferencing tool instead of upstart
competitor Zoom. As Zoom emerged as the market leader during
the early stages of the pandemic, Google introduced a new widget
for Meet inside Gmail. A similar message could be found inside
Google Calendar, which prompted users to ‘‘Add Google Meet video
conferencing’’ to their appointments. ‘‘For people with the Zoom
Video Communications Inc. extension on their Chrome browsers,
the prompt sits directly above the option to: ‘Make it a Zoom Meet-
ing.’ ’’
222
To the extent that consumers are aware of data collection prac-
tices, it is often in the wake of scandals involving large-scale data
breaches or privacy incidents such as Cambridge Analytica.
223
As
Dina Srinivasan notes, ‘‘Today, nuances in privacy terms are rel-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00047 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
42
224
Data and Privacy Hearing at 135 (statement of Dina Srinivasan, Fellow, Yale Thurman
Arnold Project).
225
Brooke Auxier et al., Americans and Privacy: Concerned, Confused and Feeling Lack of
Control Over Their Personal Information, P
EW
R
SCH
. C
TR
. (Nov. 15 2019), https://www
.pewresearch.org/internet/2019/11/15/americans-and-privacy-concerned-confused-and-feeling-
lack-of-control-over-their-personal-information/; Daniel J. Solove, The Myth of the Privacy Par-
adox, 89 G
EO
. W
ASH
. L. R
EV
. 1 (2021).
226
Data and Privacy Hearing at 54 (statement of Tommaso Valletti, Prof. of Econ., Imperial
Coll. Bus. Sch.).
227
Id.
228
Competitors Hearing at 36 (statement of David Heinemeier Hansson, Cofounder & Chief
Tech. Officer, Basecamp); Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 6 (‘‘[W]ell-functioning com-
petitive digital markets have the potential to develop new solutions and increased choice for con-
sumers, where privacy and quality of service can be differentiating factors.’’); Howard A.
Shelanski, Information, Innovation, and Competition Policy for the Internet, 161 U. P
A
. L. R
EV
.
1663, 1691 (2013) (‘‘Competition, however, may drive platforms to adopt and adhere to stronger
privacy policies, making it worthwhile for a platform to advertise such policies to consumers in
order to differentiate itself from its competitors.’’).
229
Basecamp is an internet software firm based in Chicago, Illinois, that sells project-manage-
ment and team-collaboration tools. Competitors Hearing at 27 (statement of David Heinemeier
Hansson, Cofounder & Chief Tech. Officer, Basecamp).
230
Id. at 36.
231
Data and Privacy Hearing at 134–35 (statement of Dina Srinivasan, Fellow, Yale Thurman
Arnold Project); Venture Capital and Antitrust Workshop at 24 (Paul Arnold, Founder & Part-
ner, Switch Partners).
egated to investigative journalists to discover and explain. When
the media does report on them—as they did around Google’s prac-
tice of letting employees and contractors read Gmail users’
emails—consumers often switch to a competitor that offers a better
product or service.’’
224
The opacity of data collection and use con-
tributes to consumer confusion and the misperception that con-
sumers do not care about their privacy—the so-called privacy par-
adox—simply because they use services that have become essen-
tial.
225
While insufficient competition can lead to reduced quality in
many markets, the loss of quality due to monopolization—and in
turn, privacy and data protection—is even more pronounced in dig-
ital markets because product quality is often the ‘‘relevant locus of
competition.’’
226
Without transparency or effective choice, domi-
nant firms may impose terms of service with weak privacy protec-
tions that are designed to restrict consumer choice,
227
creating a
race to the bottom.
228
As David Heinemeier Hansson, the Co-
Founder and Chief Technology Officer of Basecamp,
229
explained in
his testimony before the Subcommittee:
When businesses do not have to account for the negative externalities they
cause, it’s a race to the bottom. The industrial-scale exploitation of privacy online
is much the same. Facebook and Google have built comprehensive dossiers on
almost everyone, and they can sell incredibly targeted advertisement on that
basis. When Facebook knows you’re pregnant, or worse, thinks it knows when
you’re pregnant, they can target ads for baby clothes or strollers with striking
efficiency. But doing so represents an inherent violation of the receiver’s privacy.
Every ad targeted using personal information gathered without explicit, in-
formed consent is at some level a violation of privacy. And Facebook and Google
are profiting immensely by selling these violations to advertisers. Advertisers
who may well feel that purchasing these violations go against their ethics, but
see no choice to compete without participating.
230
In addition to creating a race to the bottom, this same dynamic
can also prevent new firms from offering products with strong pri-
vacy protections or reduce the incentive of new entrants or rivals
to compete directly.
231
Roger McNamee, the Co-Founder and Man-
aging Director of Elevation Partners, has also explained that to the
extent there is direct competition between a firm with a privacy-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00048 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
43
232
Venture Capital and Antitrust Workshop at 30 (statement of Roger McNamee, Co-Founder
& Managing Dir., Elevation Partners).
233
Competitors Hearing at 85 (response to Questions for the Record of Kirsten Daru, Chief
Priv. Officer & Gen. Couns., Tile, Inc.).
234
Id. at 43 (statement of Kirsten Daru, Chief Priv. Officer & Gen. Couns., Tile, Inc.).
235
Venture Capital and Antitrust Workshop at 36 (Ram Shriram, Managing Partner,
Sherpalo Ventures LLC).
236
Data and Privacy Hearing at 42 (statement of Rohit Chopra, Comm’r, Fed. Trade
Comm’n).
237
Id.
238
Id.
239
Id. at 52 (statement of Tommaso Valletti, Prof. of Econ., Imperial Coll. Bus. Sch.).
centric business model, such as DuckDuckGo’s search engine, they
can ‘‘still have trouble applying different business models once
they’re not compatible with the business models that have made
the Internet platforms so successful.’’
232
Conversely, without adequate safeguards in place, measures that
appear to improve privacy for consumers may also have anti-
competitive effects. Kirsten Daru, Chief Privacy Officer and Gen-
eral Counsel of Tile, told the Subcommittee: ‘‘Apple has used the
concept of privacy as a shield by making changes in the name of
privacy that at the same time give it a competitive advan-
tage.’’
233
In particular, she testified at the Subcommittee’s field
hearing:
Apple has attempted to justify its own collection of sensitive information and dis-
parate treatment of competitors because FindMy is ‘‘part of the OS,’’ as well as
due to a need for enhanced consumer privacy. But the changes don’t meaning-
fully improve or enhance privacy of third-party app developers.
234
Ram Shriram, a prominent investor who is a founding board
member of Google, noted that ‘‘[p]rivacy does impact how you think
about dominance, for example, in a market because Google and
Apple both eliminated third-party cookies, which then makes your
data a little more private. But it ironically will hurt the young com-
panies that are trying to build digital advertising businesses while
improving user privacy.’’
235
The Subcommittee held several hearings during the investigation
that examined the role of competition and privacy online.
In September 2016, the Subcommittee held a hearing on the role
of data and privacy in competition. There, FTC Commissioner
Rohit Chopra testified that dominant firms have the ability to im-
pose ‘‘complex and draconian’’ terms of service that can change sud-
denly ‘‘to collect and use data more expansively and more in-
tensely.’’
236
As he noted, this behavior is the equivalent of a price
hike that would be difficult to impose unilaterally in a competitive
marketplace.
237
Without sufficient competition, however, ‘‘compa-
nies can focus on blocking new entrants and limiting choice to pro-
tect their dominance and pricing power.’’
238
Tommaso Valletti, the
former Chief Competition Economist for the European Commission,
noted that it is ‘‘self-evident that data is key to digital platforms,
and that some applications imply real-time knowledge of consumer
behaviour as well as cross linkages across apps that only very few
digital players have access to.’’
239
And finally, Jason Furman, the
former Chair of the Council of Economic Advisers and an author
of the ‘‘Unlocking Digital Competition’’ report, said that ‘‘the mis-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00049 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
44
240
Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 43.
241
Antitrust Agencies Hearing at 44 (statement of Makan Delrahim, Assistant Att’y Gen.,
U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Antitrust Div.).
242
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 209 n.14 (statement of Maureen K.
Ohlhausen, Partner, Baker Botts, L.L.P.).
243
Data and Privacy Hearing at 171 (statement of Margrethe Vestager, Eur. Comm’r for Com-
petition).
244
Id. at 129 (statement of Rod Sims, Chair, Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n).
245
Noah Smith, Opinion, Goodbye, Newspapers. Hello, Bad Government, B
LOOMBERG
(June
1, 2018), https://www.bloomberg.com/opinion/articles/2018-06-01/goodbye-newspapers-hello-
bad-government.
246
Free and Diverse Press Hearing at 19 (statement of David Chavern, President & CEO,
News Media All.).
247
Douglas McLennan & Jack Miles, Opinion, A Once Unimaginable Scenario: No More News-
papers, W
ASH
. P
OST
: T
HE
W
ORLDPOST
(Mar. 21, 2018), https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/
theworldpost/wp/2018/03/21/newspapers/?utmlterm=.c1b57c9efcd7.
248
Free and Diverse Press Hearing at 72–73 (statement of David Pitofsky, Gen. Couns., News
Corp).
use of consumer data and harm to privacy is arguably an indicator
of low quality caused by a lack of competition.’’
240
At the Subcommittee’s oversight hearing in November 2019,
Makan Delrahim, the Assistant Attorney General of the Justice
Department’s Antitrust Division, testified that because privacy is a
dimension of quality, protecting competition ‘‘can have an impact
on privacy and data protection.’’
241
And finally, Maureen
Ohlhausen, the former Acting Chair of the FTC, echoed this point
at the Subcommittee’s hearing on innovation and entrepreneurship,
noting that quality reductions online could ‘‘include factors such as
reduced features, restricted consumer choice, or lessened control
over privacy.’’
242
Leading international antitrust enforcers offered similar testi-
mony before the Subcommittee. Margrethe Vestager, the European
Union’s Competition Commissioner, testified that due to the Com-
mission’s finding that data protection is an important dimension of
competition that could be undermined by certain merger activity,
the Commission ‘‘has . . . integrated, where appropriate, data pro-
tection as a quality parameter for the assessment of merger
cases.’’
243
Similarly, Rod Sims, the Chair of the Australian Com-
petition and Consumer Commission, told the Subcommittee that
the ACCC’s ‘‘Digital Platforms Inquiry’’ report recommends
‘‘[u]pdating Australia’s merger law to incorporate . . . the nature
and significance of assets, including data and technology, acquired
through a merger.’’
244
3. The Free and Diverse Press
A free and diverse press is essential to a vibrant democracy.
Whether exposing corruption in government, informing citizens, or
holding power to account, independent journalism sustains our de-
mocracy by facilitating public discourse.
Since 2006, newspaper advertising revenue, which is critical for
funding high-quality journalism, fell by over 50 percent.
245
Despite
significant growth in online traffic among the nation’s leading
newspapers,
246
print and digital newsrooms across the country are
laying off reporters or folding altogether.
247
As a result, commu-
nities throughout the United States are increasingly going without
sources for local news. The emergence of platform gatekeepers—
and the market power wielded by these firms—has contributed to
the decline of trustworthy sources of news.
248
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00050 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
45
249
eMarketer estimates that Google’s and Facebook’s U.S. ad revenues will be $39.58 billion
and $31.43 billion, respectively, in 2020.
E
M
ARKETER
, G
OOGLE
A
D
R
EVENUES TO
D
ROP FOR THE
F
IRST
T
IME
(June 23, 2020), https://www.emarketer.com/content/google-ad-revenues-drop-first-
time. According to BIA, local TV and radio station ad revenues (counting both their OTA and
much more limited digital revenues) will total $31.3 billion this year. See BIA Revises Local
Radio Advertising Estimates Down to $12.8B in 2020 Due to Pandemic, BIA A
DVISORY
S
ERVS
.
(June 25, 2020), http://www.biakelsey.com/bia-revises-local-radio-advertising-estimates-12-8-b-
2020-due-pandemic-transition-digital-accelerating/; BIA Lowers 2020 Local Television Station
Advertising Revenue Forecast to $18.5B, BIA A
DVISORY
S
ERVS
. (May 21, 2020), http://
www.biakelsey.com/bia-lowers-2020-local-television-station-advertising-revenue-forecast-18-5b/.
250
Michael Barthel, Despite Subscription Surges for Largest U.S. Newspapers, Circulation and
Revenue Fall for Industry Overall, P
EW
R
SCH
. C
TR
.: F
ACT
T
ANK
(June 1, 2017), https://www
.pewresearch.org/fact-tank/2017/06/01/circulation-and-revenue-fall-for-newspaper-industry;
Newspapers Fact Sheet, P
EW
R
SCH
. C
TR
. (June 13, 2018), https://www.journalism.org/fact-
sheet/newspapers.
251
Submission from Source 220, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 7 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
252
See P
ENELOPE
M
USE
A
BERNATHY
, U
NIV
. N.C. S
CH
.
OF
M
EDIA &
J
OURNALISM
, N
EWS
D
ESERTS AND
G
HOST
N
EWSPAPERS
: W
ILL
L
OCAL
N
EWS
S
URVIVE
45 (2020), https://www.usnews
deserts.com/wp-content/uploads/2020/06/2020lNewslDesertslandlGhostlNewspapers
.pdf.
253
Submission from Nat’l Ass’n of Broads., to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Oct. 14, 2019),
http://www.nab.org/documents/newsRoom/pdfs/09220lHJClLocallJournalismlAtlRisk
lSubmission.pdf.
254
Oliver Darcy & Tom Kludt, Media Industry Loses About 1,000 Jobs as Layoffs Hit News
Organizations, CNN (Jan. 24, 2019), https://edition.cnn.com/2019/01/24/media/media-layoffs-
buzzfeed-huffpost-gannett/index.html; Edmund Lee, Founder’s Big Idea to Revive BuzzFeed’s
Fortunes? A Merger with Rivals, N.Y. T
IMES
(Nov. 19, 2018), https://www.nytimes.com/2018/
11/19/business/media/buzzfeed-jonah-peretti-mergers.html.
255
Edmund Lee, Founder’s Big Idea to Revive BuzzFeed’s Fortunes? A Merger with Rivals,
N.Y. T
IMES
(Nov. 19, 2018), https://www.nytimes.com/2018/11/19/business/media/buzzfeed-
jonah-peretti-mergers.html.
(a) Journalism in Decline. Since 2006, the news industry has
been in economic freefall, primarily due to a massive decrease in
advertising revenue. Both print and broadcast news organizations
rely heavily on advertising revenue to support their operations, and
as the market has shifted to digital platforms, news organizations
have seen the value of their advertising space plummet steeply.
249
For newspapers, advertising has declined from $49 billion in 2006
to $16.5 billion in 2017.
250
This decrease has been felt by national
and local news sources alike. As total annual advertising revenues
have fallen over 62 percent across the industry since 2008, one
major national newspaper told the Subcommittee that its annual
advertising revenue has fallen 48 percent over that period.
251
Addi-
tionally, ethnic news outlets have suffered from the shift from
broadcast and print ads to digital ads.
252
Regarding television and
radio broadcast news, the National Association of Broadcasters told
the Subcommittee, ‘‘[T]his year, the U.S. advertising revenue of a
single company—Google—are projected to exceed the combined ad
revenue of all TV and radio stations in the country by over $8 bil-
lion.’’
253
While the decline of advertising revenue has most severely af-
fected local news publishers, prominent digital publishers have also
been affected. In January 2019, Buzzfeed announced layoffs of 220
employees, about 15 percent of its workforce, due to advertising
losses.
254
Jonah Peretti, the Chief Executive Officer of BuzzFeed,
commented prior to the layoffs that consolidation of digital pub-
lishers into a single large digital media company may be the only
path forward for profitability, suggesting that publishers’ lack of
bargaining power in negotiations with online platforms is the cen-
tral obstacle to long-term survival.
255
Despite a recent boost in the number of digital subscriptions and
the level of online traffic for the top newspapers in the United
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00051 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
46
256
Michael Barthel, Despite Subscription Surges for Largest U.S. Newspapers, Circulation and
Revenue Fall for Industry Overall, P
EW
R
SCH
. C
TR
.: F
ACT
T
ANK
(June 1, 2017), https://
www.pewresearch.org/fact-tank/2017/06/01/circulation-and-revenue-fall-for-newspaper-indus-
try/; Newspapers Fact Sheet, P
EW
R
SCH
. C
TR
. (July 9, 2019), https://www.journalism.org/fact-
sheet/newspapers; David Chavern, Opinion, Protect the News From Google and Facebook, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (Feb. 25, 2018), https://www.wsj.com/articles/protect-the-news-from-google-and-facebook-
1519594942.
257
Submission from Source 220, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 7 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
258
P
ENELOPE
M
USE
A
BERNATHY
, U
NIV
. N.C. S
CH
.
OF
M
EDIA &
J
OURNALISM
, T
HE
E
XPANDING
N
EWS
D
ESERT
33 (2018), https://www.cislm.org/wp-content/uploads/2018/10/The-Expanding-
News-Desert-10l14-Web.pdf.
259
Alex Shephard, Finance Is Killing the News, N
EW
R
EPUBLIC
(Apr. 18, 2018), https://
newrepublic.com/article/148022/finance-killing-news.
260
Lesley Chiou & Catherine Tucker, Content Aggregation by Platforms: The Case of the News
Media (Nat’l Bureau of Econ. Rsch., Working Paper No. 21404, 2015), https://www.nber.org/
papers/w21404.pdf.
261
N
EWS
M
EDIA
A
LL
., H
OW
G
OOGLE
A
BUSES
I
TS
P
OSITION AS A
M
ARKET
D
OMINANT
P
LATFORM
TO
S
TRONG
-A
RM
N
EWS
P
UBLISHERS AND
H
URT
J
OURNALISM
2 (2020), http://www
.newsmediaalliance.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/06/Final-Alliance-White-Paper-June-18-
2020.pdf.
262
Id. at 12.
263
Id. at 12–14.
264
Submission from the Nat’l Ass’n of Broads., to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 9 (Sept. 2,
2020), http://www.nab.org/documents/newsRoom/pdfs/09220lHJClLocallJournalismlAt
lRisklSubmission.pdf.
States, these increases did not offset losses in online advertising or
circulation in the industry overall.
256
As one news publisher told
the Subcommittee, ‘‘For the vast majority of news publishers, dig-
ital subscription revenues remain a minor revenue stream and do
not appear to be on a path to replace the decline in print subscrip-
tions.’’
257
Over the past two decades, hundreds of local news pub-
lishers have been acquired or gone bankrupt.
258
In some cases, pri-
vate equity firms and hedge funds have purchased major regional
chains and newspapers, resulting in mass layoffs of journalists and
increased debt burdens for publishers.
259
In recent years, news consumption has largely shifted to a model
of content aggregation, through which platforms consolidate con-
tent from multiple news sources.
260
In submissions to the Sub-
committee and public statements, publishers across the spectrum
say they have little choice but to participate in content aggregation,
particularly those run by dominant platforms because the
aggregators’ ‘‘use of news publishers’ content does send substantial
traffic to news publishers.’’
261
But this can also prevent traffic
from flowing to newspapers. As some publishers have noted, news
aggregators package and present content to users using attention-
grabbing quotes from high points of stories, which can make it un-
necessary for the user to click through to the publisher’s
website.
262
As these publishers noted, this dynamic forces news or-
ganizations to effectively compete with their own content, lowering
the potential revenue from user traffic to news organizations’
websites.
263
As a result of falling revenues, newspapers and broadcast sta-
tions are steadily losing the ability to financially support their
newsrooms, which are costly to maintain but provide immense
value to their communities.
264
A robust local newsroom requires
the financial freedom to support in-depth, sometimes years-long re-
porting, as well as the ability to hire and retain journalists with
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00052 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
47
265
Free and Diverse Press Hearing at 83–84 (statement of Kevin Riley, Ed., The Atlanta
Journal-Constitution).
266
Submission from the Nat’l Ass’n of Broads., to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 1 (Sept. 2,
2020), http://www.nab.org/documents/newsRoom/pdfs/09220lHJClLocallJournalismlAt
lRisklSubmission.pdf.
267
Free and Diverse Press Hearing at 82 (statement of Kevin Riley, Ed., The Atlanta Journal-
Constitution).
268
Sara Fischer & Margaret Harding McGill, Coronavirus Sends Local News into Crisis,
A
XIOS
(Mar. 21, 2020), https://www.axios.com/coronavirus-local-news-853e96fa-51aa-43cc-a990-
eb48cc896b17.html.
269
Mark Glaser, 6 Ways Local News Makes a Crucial Impact Covering COVID–19, K
NIGHT
F
OUND
. (Apr. 20, 2020), https://knightfoundation.org/articles/6-ways-local-news-makes-a-
crucial-impact-covering-covid-19/.
270
COVID–19 Response from Native Tribes, NMPBS (Mar. 30, 2020), https://www
.newmexicopbs.org/productions/newmexicoinfocus/covid-19-response-from-native-tribes/.
271
See, e.g., Bill Chappell, Coronavirus Cases Spike in Navajo Nation, Where Water Service
Is Often Scarce, NPR (Mar. 26, 2020), https://www.npr.org/sections/coronavirus-live-updates/
2020/03/26/822037719/coronavirus-cases-spike-in-navajo-nation-where-water-service-is-often-
scarce.
272
Submission from the Nat’l Ass’n of Broads., to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Sept. 2,
2020), http://www.nab.org/documents/newsRoom/pdfs/09220lHJClLocallJournalismlAt
lRisklSubmission.pdf.
273
Id. at 4, 7 n.16.
274
Id. at 7.
expertise in fundamentally local issues, such as coverage of state
government.
265
The societal value of local news is significant. As noted by the
National Association of Broadcasters, local broadcast stations pro-
vide on-the-air programming which is ‘‘rooted in localism and the
public interest,’’ offering content which ‘‘[is] still free to the public
and accessible to all Americans.’’
266
Kevin Riley, the editor of The
Atlanta Journal-Constitution, similarly testified before the Sub-
committee that ‘‘it would be impossible to even put a cost estimate
on the work’’ of local journalists.
267
The COVID–19 pandemic has particularly highlighted the impor-
tance of local news sources. Despite taking major revenue losses,
268
local journalists have provided valuable reporting on the trans-
mission of the novel coronavirus, particularly for underserved and
vulnerable communities.
269
For example, PBS New Mexico pro-
vided an in-depth focus on the effects of the coronavirus on Native
Americans ‘‘dealing with scarce resources as they respond to novel
coronavirus outbreaks on tribal lands.’’
270
Apart from serving their
communities, local news stories bring national attention to these
critical issues.
271
In addition to news coverage, the National Asso-
ciation of Broadcasters aired public-service announcements in re-
sponse to the pandemic ‘‘more than 765,000 times for an estimated
ad value of more than $156,500,000,’’ a number which ‘‘do[es] not
include the likely much greater number of other coronavirus-re-
lated PSAs’’ aired by local television and radio stations across the
United States.
272
To run a new operation, broadcast stations must be able to sus-
tain ‘‘the basic costs of running a station, including engineering,
sales, [and] programming’’ costs, and must make significant capital
expenditures in equipment, such as satellite trucks.
273
These ex-
penses must be satisfied before broadcast stations can invest in im-
provements to keep pace with changing technologies, ‘‘including
ultra-high definition programming, better emergency alerting, mo-
bile services, interactivity, hyper-local content and more.’’
274
The costs of news production add up. From 2003 to 2013, these
costs ‘‘accounted for nearly 24 percent of TV stations’ total ex-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00053 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
48
275
Id. at 4 (citing NAB Television Financial Reports 2004–2019).
276
Elizabeth Grieco, U.S. Newspapers Have Shed Half of Their Newsroom Employees Since
2008, P
EW
R
SCH
. C
TR
.: F
ACT
T
ANK
(Apr. 20, 2020), https://www.pewresearch.org/fact-tank/
2020/04/20/u-s-newsroom-employment-has-dropped-by-a-quarter-since-2008/.
277
Benjamin Goggin, 7,800 People Lost Their Media Jobs in a 2019 Landslide, B
US
. I
NSIDER
(Dec. 10, 2019), https://www.businessinsider.com/2019-media-layoffs-job-cuts-at-buzzfeed-huff
post-vice-details-2019-2#spin-media-group-29-jobs-september-and-january-18.
278
Occupational Outlook Handbook: Reporters, Correspondents, and Broadcast News Ana-
lysts, U.S. D
EP
TOF
L
ABOR
: B
UREAU OF
L
ABOR
S
TATS
., https://www.bls.gov/ooh/media-and-
communication/reporters-correspondents-and-broadcast-news-analysts.htm (last modified Apr.
12, 2019).
279
P
ENELOPE
M
USE
A
BERNATHY
, U
NIV
. N.C. S
CH
.
OF
M
EDIA &
J
OURNALISM
, T
HE
E
XPANDING
N
EWS
D
ESERT
10–11 (2018), https://www.cislm.org/wp-content/uploads/2018/10/The-Expand-
ing-News-Desert-10l14-Web.pdf.
280
Id. at 8, 10.
281
Free and Diverse Press Hearing at 83 (statement of Kevin Riley, Ed., The Atlanta Journal-
Constitution).
282
Matthew Gentzkow et al., The Effects of Newspaper Entry and Exit on Electoral Politics,
101 A
M
. E
CON
. R
EV
. 2980, 2980 (2011) (‘‘We find that newspapers have a robust positive effect
on political participation, with one additional newspaper increasing both presidential and con-
gressional turnout by approximately 0.3 percentage points.’’ (italics removed)).
283
Mary Ellen Klas, Less Local News Means Less Democracy, N
IEMAN
R
EPS
. (Sept. 20, 2019),
https://niemanreports.org/articles/less-local-news-means-less-democracy/.
penses (and nearly 26 percent of the total expenses of ABC/CBS/
Fox/NBC stations).’’
275
In light of the expenses associated with
producing high-quality journalism, declining revenue has major im-
plications for the maintenance—let alone enrichment—of quality
news production.
Budget cuts have also led to a dramatic number of newsroom job
losses. This decline has been primarily driven by a reduction in
newspaper employees, who have seen employment fall by half over
a recent eight-year period, from 71,000 in 2008 to 35,000 in
2019.
276
In 2019 alone, 7,800 media industry employees were laid
off.
277
The Bureau of Labor Statistics estimates that the total em-
ployment of reporters, correspondents, and broadcast news analysts
will continue to decline by about 11 percent between 2019 and
2029.
278
Researchers at the University of North Carolina School of Media
and Journalism found that the United States has lost nearly 1,800
newspapers since 2004 either to closure or merger, 70 percent of
which were in metropolitan areas.
279
As a result, the majority of
counties in America no longer have more than one publisher of
local news, and 200 are without any paper.
280
At the Subcommit-
tee’s hearing on online platforms’ effects on a free and diverse
press, Mr. Riley described this new media landscape as character-
ized by digital platform dominance and disappearing local news-
papers:
We produce journalism that is distinguished by its depth, accuracy and origi-
nality. That costs money and is expensive, but if the system works correctly, it
also makes money that the paper uses to investigate and develop the next story
or cover the next local event. If others repackage our journalism and make
money off it, yet none of that money makes its way back to the local paper, then
it makes breaking that next story or exposing the next scandal more challenging.
If that cycle continues indefinitely, quality local journalism will slowly wither
and eventually cease to exist.
281
This cycle has a profoundly negative effect on American democ-
racy and civic life. Communities without quality local news cov-
erage have lower rates of voter turnout.
282
Government corruption
may go unchecked, leaving communities vulnerable to serious mis-
management.
283
Relatedly, these communities see local government
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00054 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
49
284
Noah Smith, Opinion, Goodbye Newspapers. Hello, Bad Government, B
LOOMBERG
(June 1,
2018), https://www.bloomberg.com/opinion/articles/2018-06-01/goodbye-newspapers-hello-bad-
government (‘‘[T]he authors show that without local newspapers, local governments tend to en-
gage in more inefficient or dubious financing arrangements.’’).
285
Amy Mitchell et al., Civic Engagement Strongly Tied to Local News Habits, P
EW
R
SCH
.
C
TR
. (Nov. 3, 2016), https://www.journalism.org/2016/11/03/civic-engagement-strongly-tied-to-
local-news-habits.
286
Danny Hayes & Jennifer L. Lawless, As Local News Goes, So Goes Citizen Engagement:
Media, Knowledge, and Participation in U.S. House Elections, 77 J. P
OL
. 447, 447 (2014).
287
Submission from Source 220, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 7 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.). Although Apple News and Apple News Plus are increasingly popular news aggregators,
most market participants interviewed by the Subcommittee do not view Apple as a critical inter-
mediary for online news at this time, although some publishers raised concerns about the tying
of payments inside Apple’s news product.
288
Submission from Source 955, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 12 (Oct. 30, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
289
Free and Diverse Press Hearing at 20 (statement of David Chavern, President & CEO,
News Media All.) (‘‘In effect, a couple of dominant tech platforms are acting as regulators of
the digital news industry.’’).
290
See, e.g., Submission from Source 140, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Oct. 15, 2019)
(on file with Comm.) (‘‘Facebook’s decision, announced in June 2016, to make significant changes
to its algorithm to [favor] content from friends and family, which was made without notice, con-
sultation or warning to the market, and which led to significant disruption for a range of busi-
nesses.’’).
291
Submission from Source 114, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 12 (Oct. 2, 2019) (on file with
Comm.); Data and Privacy Hearing at 127 (statement of Rod Sims, Chair, Austl. Competition
& Consumer Comm’n).
spending increase.
284
Towns without robust local news coverage
also exhibit lower levels of social cohesion, undermining a sense of
belonging in a community.
285
As fewer publishers operate in local
markets, local news is supplanted by aggregation of national cov-
erage, reducing residents’ knowledge of local happenings and
events, and generally leaving them less connected to their commu-
nities.
286
Compounding this problem, the gap created by the loss of trust-
worthy and credible news sources has been increasingly filled by
false and misleading information. Once communities lack a local
newspaper source, people tend to get their local news from social
media. As local news dies, it is filled by unchecked information,
some of which can spread quickly and can have severe con-
sequences.
(b) The Effect of Market Power on Journalism. During the Sub-
committee’s investigation, news publishers raised concerns about
the ‘‘significant and growing asymmetry of power’’ between domi-
nant online platforms and news publishers, as well as the effect of
this dominance on the production and availability of trustworthy
sources of news. In interviews, submissions, and testimony before
the Subcommittee, publishers with distinct business models and
distribution strategies said they are ‘‘increasingly beholden’’ to
these firms, and in particular, Google and Facebook.
287
As a result,
several dominant firms have an outsized influence over the dis-
tribution and monetization of trustworthy sources of news on-
line,
288
undermining the availability of high-quality sources of jour-
nalism.
289
(i) Distribution of News Online. Several dominant platforms func-
tion as intermediaries to news online. Due to their outsized role as
digital gateways to news, a change to one of these firms’ algorithms
can significantly affect the online referrals to news publishers,
290
directly affecting their advertising revenue.
291
One news publisher
stated in its submission to the Subcommittee that it and other
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00055 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
50
292
Submission from Source 220, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Mar. 10, 2020) (on file with
Comm.).
293
Submission from Source 955, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 12 (Oct. 15, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
294
Id. at 17.
295
Id.
296
Adam Mosseri, Bringing People Closer Together, F
ACEBOOK
: N
EWSROOM
(Jan. 11, 2018),
https://newsroom.fb.com/news/2018/01/news-feed-fyi-bringing-people-closer-together.
297
How Much Have Facebook Algorithm Changes Impacted Publishers?, M
ARKETING
C
HARTS
(Apr. 4, 2019), https://www.marketingcharts.com/digital/social-media-107974.
298
Submission from Source 140, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
299
Nicholas Thompson & Fred Vogelstein, Inside the Two Years That Shook Facebook—and
the World, W
IRED
(Feb. 12, 2018), https://www.wired.com/story/inside-facebook-mark-
zuckerberg-2-years-of-hell/ (emphasis added).
300
See, e.g., Submission from Source 140, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Oct. 15, 2019)
(on file with Comm.) (describing ‘‘Apple’s decision to tie all payments made through iOS apps
to its own payment system, which takes a 30 percent share of any contributions and subscrip-
tions made to news [publishers] through news apps downloaded from the Apple store’’).
news organizations ‘‘depend on a few big tech platforms to help
them distribute their journalism to consumers.’’
292
In submissions to the Subcommittee, several news publishers
noted that the dominance of Google and Facebook allows them to
‘‘pick winners’’ online by adjusting visibility and traffic.
293
For ex-
ample, an update to Google’s search algorithm in June 2019 de-
creased a major news publisher’s online traffic ‘‘by close to 50%’’
even as their referrals from other sources—such as their home
page and apps—grew during the same period.
294
As they noted, a
‘‘smaller business would have been crushed’’ by this decline.
295
Similarly, news organizations were negatively affected when, in
January 2018, Facebook adjusted its News Feed algorithm to
prioritize content based on audience engagement.
296
According to
an internet analytics firm, these changes significantly affected the
visibility of news content on Facebook, resulting in a 33 percent de-
crease in referral traffic from Facebook to news publishers’ sites.
297
As one publisher noted in its submission to the Subcommittee, this
change ‘‘was made without notice, consultation or warning to the
market, [leading] to significant disruption for a range of busi-
nesses.’’
298
Nicholas Thompson, the Editor-in-Chief of Wired maga-
zine, and Wired contributing editor Fred Vogelstein described the
relationship between publishers and Facebook as being ‘‘share-
croppers on Facebook’s massive industrial farm,’’ writing that:
Even at the best of times, meetings between Facebook and media executives can
feel like unhappy family gatherings. The two sides are inextricably bound to-
gether, but they don’t like each other all that much .... And then there’s the
simple, deep fear and mistrust that Facebook inspires. Every publisher knows
that, at best, they are sharecroppers on Facebook’s massive industrial farm. The
social network is roughly 200 times more valuable than the Times. And journal-
ists know that the man who owns the farm has the leverage. If Facebook wanted
to, it could quietly turn any number of dials that would harm a publisher—by
manipulating its traffic, its ad network, or its readers.
299
The Subcommittee has also received evidence that the dominance
of several online platforms has created a significant imbalance of
bargaining power. In several submissions, news publishers note
that dominant firms can impose unilateral terms on publishers,
such as take-it-or-leave-it revenue sharing agreements.
300
A promi-
nent publisher described this relationship as platforms having a
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00056 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
51
301
Submission from Source 114, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 12 (Oct. 2, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
302
Free and Diverse Press Hearing.
303
Data and Privacy Hearing at 125 (statement of Rod Sims, Chair, Austl. Competition &
Consumer Comm’n) (testifying that the power of dominant platforms ‘‘creates an imbalance of
bargaining power between digital platforms and news media businesses, meaning that agree-
ments they reach are likely much different to those that would be reached in a competitive mar-
ket’’).
304
Free and Diverse Press Hearing at 45 (statement of Sally Hubbard, Dir. of Enf’t Strategy,
Open Mkts. Inst.).
305
Id. at 22 (statement of David Chavern, President, News Media All.).
306
N
EWS
M
EDIA
A
LL
., H
OW
G
OOGLE
A
BUSES
I
TS
P
OSITION AS A
M
ARKET
D
OMINANT
P
LATFORM
TO
S
TRONG
-A
RM
N
EWS
P
UBLISHERS AND
H
URT
J
OURNALISM
(2020), http://www
.newsmediaalliance.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/06/Final-Alliance-White-Paper-June-18-2020
.pdf.
307
Id. at 1.
308
Id. at 5.
309
Id. at 7.
310
Id. at 6.
‘‘finger on the scales’’ with the ability to suppress publishers that
do not ‘‘appease platforms’ business terms.’’
301
During the Subcommittee’s hearing on the effects of market
power on journalism,
302
several witnesses also testified about the
lack of equal bargaining power between news publishers and domi-
nant platforms.
303
At the Subcommittee’s hearing on market power
and the free and diverse press, Sally Hubbard, Director of Enforce-
ment Strategy at the Open Markets Institute, testified that the
lack of competition online has led to diminished bargaining power
among news publishers. Consequently, in response to changing
terms and algorithmic treatment by platforms, ‘‘publishers have lit-
tle choice but to adapt and accommodate regardless of how the
changes may negatively affect their own profitability.’’
304
David
Chavern, President of the News Media Alliance, similarly testified
that publishers have a ‘‘collective action problem,’’ stating that ‘‘no
news organization on its own can stand up to the platforms. The
risk of demotion or exclusion from the platforms is simply too
great.’’
305
In June 2020, the News Media Alliance published a white paper
examining the relationship between news publishers and Google
based on interviews with its members over the course of more than
a year.
306
As it notes, ‘‘Google has exercised control over news pub-
lishers to force them into several relationships that benefit Google
at the publishers’ expense.’’
307
In the context of Google’s place-
ment of news on accelerated mobile pages (AMP)—a format for dis-
playing web pages on mobile devices—publishers raised concerns
that ‘‘Google effectively gave news publishers little choice but to
adopt it,’’ requiring the creation of parallel websites ‘‘that are
hosted, stored and served from Google’s servers rather than their
own.’’
308
While this format has benefits in terms of loading information
quickly on mobile devices, publishers argue that these benefits
‘‘could have been achieved through means that did not so signifi-
cantly increase Google’s power over publishers or so favor its abil-
ity to collect data to foster its market domination.’’
309
And when
a publisher attempts to avoid this cost by moving its content be-
hind a paywall, its rise in subscriptions was offset by declines in
traffic from Google and other platforms.
310
Referring to this trade-
off as a ‘‘Hobson’s choice,’’ the News Media Alliance explained:
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00057 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
52
311
Id. at 8 n.14 (‘‘These include the following: (1) Google gets the subscriber data; (2) the
user must use Google Wallet or Google Pay, instead of providing its credit card to the news pub-
lisher and establishing a direct relationship with the publisher; and (3) Google takes a 5–15%
cut. See Nushin Rashidian, George Civeris & Pete Brown, Platforms and Publishers: The End
of an Era, C
OLUM
. J
OURNALISM
R
EV
. (Nov. 22, 2019), https://www.cjr.org/towlcenterlreports/
platforms-and-publishers-end-of-an-era.php.’’).
312
Id. at 8.
313
Submission from Google Austl. Pty. Ltd., to Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n, 45–
46 (Feb. 18, 2019), https://www.accc.gov.au/system/files/Google%20%28February%202019
%29.PDF. But see Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n Report at 240 (‘‘[T]here is a broader
issue about the extent to which Google, by way of AMP, retains users within its ecosystem and
reduces monetisation opportunities for media businesses outside of AMP. That is, rather than
directing users to the websites of media businesses, AMP’s design encourages users to stay with-
in the Google ecosystem. As a result, media businesses are less likely to monetise content on
their own properties, either through advertising or subscription revenue.’’).
314
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 422 (response to Questions for the Record
of Adam Cohen, Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC).
315
Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n at 297 (describing atomization as ‘‘the process
by which news is ‘decoupled from its source’ and consumed on a ‘story-by-story basis’ ’’); Free
and Diverse Press Hearing at 20 (statement of David Chavern, President, News Media All.)
(‘‘These tech giants use secret, unpredictable algorithms to determine how and even whether
content is delivered to readers. They scrape news organizations’ content and use it to their own
ends, without permission or remuneration for the companies that generated the content in the
first place. They also suppress news organizations’ brands, control their data, and refuse to rec-
ognize and support quality journalism.’’).
316
Submission from Source 114, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 12 (Oct. 2, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
317
Interview with Source 114 (Oct. 2, 2019).
Newspapers such as The Wall Street Journal employ a highly customized
paywall on their websites, significantly varying the number of free articles that
a user is permitted to read before being asked to subscribe to the newspaper.
This flexibility is highly beneficial, allowing them to maximize engagement and
increase subscriptions. For AMP articles, however, Google restricts the paywall
options. Unless publishers rebuild their paywall options and their meters for
AMP, they can only provide all of their content for free or none of their content
for free. The only other option is to use Subscribe with Google, which has many
benefits for Google and downsides for news publishers.
311
Accordingly, unless
they invest in building another and separate paywall, news publishers who do
not want to use Subscribe with Google have a de facto all-or-nothing choice re-
garding the imposition of a paywall, which lowers subscriber conversion rates.
312
Google has responded to this concern by noting that AMP does not
prevent publishers from placing ads on AMP pages, but restricting
the number of ads ‘‘leads to improved page load times, increased
site traffic, superior ad engagement, and thus typically increases
advertising revenue overall.’’
313
Google also said in its responses to
Subcommittee Chair David N. Cicilline’s questions for the record
that it ‘‘does not privilege publishers who use AMP over publishers
that adopt non-Google technical solutions that would also guar-
antee fast-loading pages.’’
314
Finally, because news is often accessed online through channels
other than the original publication—including search results, voice
assistants, social platforms, or news aggregators—journalism has
increasingly become ‘‘atomized’’ or removed from its source and
placed alongside other content.
315
In the context of audio news,
one market participant noted that aggregating different news
sources can create a bad experience for users.
316
The aggregation
of different news sources without editorial oversight can also cause
reputational harm to news publishers, such as when highly cred-
ible reporting appears alongside an opinion-based news source.
317
Indirectly, the atomization of news may increase the likelihood
that people are exposed to disinformation or untrustworthy sources
of news online. When online news is disintermediated from its
source, people generally have more difficulty discerning the credi-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00058 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
53
318
Submission from Source 140, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
319
CEO Hearing at 143 (statement of Rep. David N. Cicilline (D–RI), Chair, Subcomm. on
Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
320
Id.
321
Id. (statement of Mark Zuckerberg, CEO, Facebook, Inc.).
322
Id. at 143–44 (statement of Rep. David N. Cicilline (D–RI), Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust,
Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
323
Id. at 144 (statement of Mark Zuckerberg, CEO, Facebook, Inc.).
324
Free and Diverse Press Hearing at 45 (statement of Sally Hubbard, Dir. of Enf’t Strategy,
Open Mkts. Inst.); Charlie Warzel, Opinion, Facebook Can’t Be Reformed, N.Y. T
IMES
(July 1,
2020), https://www.nytimes.com/2020/07/01/opinion/facebook-zuckerberg.html.
325
Conversely, the decline of trustworthy sources of news due to rising market power and
declining ad revenue has also contributed to this harm. Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at
9 (‘‘[C]oncerns relating to online platforms funded by digital advertising can lead to wider social,
political and cultural harm through the decline of authoritative and reliable news media, the
resultant spread of ‘fake news’ and the decline of the local press which is often a significant
force in sustaining communities.’’).
326
Submission from Source 140, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
bility of reporting online. This process may also ‘‘foster ambivalence
about the quality and nature of content that garners users’ atten-
tion,’’ particularly among young people.
318
For example, during the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Sub-
committee Chair Cicilline presented Facebook CEO Mark
Zuckerberg with evidence of a Breitbart video that claimed that
‘‘you don’t need a mask and hydroxychloroquine is a cure for
COVID.’’
319
As he noted, within the first five hours of this video
being posted, it had nearly ‘‘20 million views and over 100,000 com-
ments before Facebook acted to remove it.’’
320
Mr. Zuckerberg re-
sponded that ‘‘a lot of people shared that, and we did take it down
because it violate[d] our policies.’’
321
In response, Chair Cicilline
asked if ‘‘20 million people saw it over the period of five hours . . .
doesn’t that suggest, Mr. Zuckerberg, that your platform is so big
that, even with the right policies in place, you can’t contain deadly
content?’’
322
Mr. Zuckerberg responded by claiming that Facebook
has a ‘‘relatively good track record of finding and taking down lots
of false content.’’
323
Moreover, because there is not meaningful competition, dominant
firms face little financial consequence when misinformation and
propaganda are promoted online.
324
Platforms that are dependent
on online advertising have an incentive to prioritize content that is
addictive or exploitative to increase engagement on the platform.
325
And the reliance on platforms by advertisers has generally dimin-
ished their ability to push for improvements in content standards.
As a news publisher explained in a submission to the Sub-
committee:
As advertisers have become more reliant on dominant search and social plat-
forms to reach potential consumers, they have lost any leverage to demand
change in the policies or practices of the platforms. In the era of newspapers,
television, radio, or indeed direct sales of digital advertising online, there was
a connection between advertising and the content it funds, creating a high de-
gree of accountability for both parties in that transaction. This maintained high
content standards, and enabled advertisers to demand or pursue change from
publishers whose content standards fell. While many high-quality publishers
continue to operate stringent policies in relation to the digital advertising that
they permit to appear within their services, in a world of programmatic audience
trading that self-regulated compact between advertisers and platform does not
exist.
326
During the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Representative Jamie
Raskin (D–MD) raised this concern. As he noted, in July 2020,
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00059 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
54
327
CEO Hearing at 57 (statement of Rep. Jamie Raskin (D–MD), Member, Subcomm. on
Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
328
Id. Stop Hate for Profit was established by the Anti-Defamation League, the NAACP,
Color of Change, and other civil rights groups in the wake of the May 2020 police killing of
George Floyd, an unarmed Black man, in Minneapolis and the ensuing national protests. Shirin
Ghaffary & Rebecca Heilweil, Why Facebook Is ‘‘The Front Line in Fighting Hate Today,’’ V
OX
:
R
ECODE
(July 15, 2020), https://www.vox.com/recode/2020/7/15/21325728/facebook-stop-hate-
for-profit-campaign-jonathan-greenblatt-anti-defamation-league.
329
Steven Levy, Facebook Has More to Learn from the Ad Boycott, W
IRED
(Aug. 6, 2020),
https://www.wired.com/story/rashad-robinson-facebook-ad-boycott/.
330
CEO Hearing at 57 (statement of Rep. Jamie Raskin (D–MD), Member, Subcomm. on
Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
331
Id. (statement of Mark Zuckerberg, CEO, Facebook, Inc.).
332
Id.
333
Id. at 216 (question of Rep. Pramila Jayapal (D–WA), Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial
and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
334
Id. (statement of Mark Zuckerberg, CEO, Facebook, Inc.).
335
Statement from Stop Hate for Profit on July 2020 Ad Pause Success and #StopHateFor
Profit Campaign, S
TOP
H
ATE FOR
P
ROFIT
(July 30, 2020), https://www.stophateforprofit.org/.
336
Donie O’Sullivan, Group That Led Facebook Boycott Is Back With New Action, CNN B
US
.
(Sept. 14, 2020), https://www.cnn.com/2020/09/14/tech/facebook-boycott-return/index.html.
Facebook faced an advertiser boycott by hundreds of companies.
327
This effort was spearheaded by the Stop Hate for Profit campaign,
a coalition of civil rights groups organizing in protest of ‘‘the rapid
spread of hate messages online, the presence of boogaloo and other
right-wing extremist groups trying to infiltrate and disrupt Black
Lives Matter protests and the fact that alt-right racists and anti-
Semitic content flourishes on Facebook.’’
328
As a result of this campaign, more than a thousand major com-
panies—including Disney, Coca-Cola, and General Motors—an-
nounced that they would pull $7 billion in advertisements on
Facebook as part of the Stop Hate for Profit boycott.
329
But, as
Representative Raskin pointed out during the hearing, Facebook
does not ‘‘seem to be that moved by their campaign.’’
330
Representative Pramila Jayapal (D–WA) also noted during the
hearing that Mr. Zuckerberg reportedly told Facebook’s employees
at an internal meeting that the company is ‘‘not gonna change our
policies or approach on anything because of a threat to a small per-
cent of our revenue, or to any percent of our revenue.’’
331
During
that meeting, Mr. Zuckerberg reportedly acknowledged that the
boycott ‘‘hurts us reputationally,’’ but said that the company was
insulated from threats by large advertisers due to advertising rev-
enue from small businesses.
332
In response to this report, Ms.
Jayapal asked Mr. Zuckerberg whether Facebook is ‘‘so big that
you don’t care how you’re impacted by a major boycott of 1,100 ad-
vertisers?’’
333
Mr. Zuckerberg responded that ‘‘[o]f course we care.
But we’re also not going to set our content policies because of ad-
vertisers. I think that that would be the wrong thing for us to
do.’’
334
Since then, the civil rights groups have said that, although
Facebook made some changes in response to the boycott—such as
the creation of a position within the company dedicated to over-
seeing civil rights and algorithmic bias—it ultimately has not made
meaningful changes at scale, and it ‘‘lags competitors in working
systematically to address hate and bigotry on their platform.’’
335
The group organized further action in September 2020, when it
called for companies and public figures to stop posting on
Instagram beginning September 16th.
336
This protest, aimed again
at Facebook’s treatment of hate groups, was spurred by the police
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00060 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
55
337
Id.
338
Brian Fung, Facebook CEO Admits ‘‘Operational Mistake’’ in Failure to Remove Kenosha
Militia Page, CNN B
US
. (Sept. 4, 2020), https://www.cnn.com/2020/08/28/tech/zuckerberg-
kenosha-page/index.html.
339
Id.
340
See, e.g., Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n Report at 7; David Chavern, Opinion,
Protect the News from Google and Facebook, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (Feb. 25, 2018), https://www.wsj.com/
articles/protect-the-news-from-google-and-facebook-1519594942; supra Section III.C.3(b)(i).
341
See, e.g., Hamza Shaban, Digital Advertising to Surpass Print and TV for the First Time,
Report Says, W
ASH
. P
OST
: T
ECH
. (Feb. 20, 2019), https://www.washingtonpost.com/technology/
2019/02/20/digital-advertising-surpass-print-tv-first-time-report-says/.
342
Sarah Sluis, Digital Ad Market Soars to $88 Billion, Facebook and Google Contribute 90%
of Growth, A
D
E
XCHANGER
(May 10, 2018), https://adexchanger.com/online-advertising/
digital-ad-market-soars-to-88-billion-facebook-and-google-contribute-90-of-growth.
343
Jean Baptiste Su, Amazon Is Now the #3 Digital Ad Platform in the U.S. Behind Google
and Facebook, Says eMarketer, F
ORBES
(Sept. 20, 2018), https://www.forbes.com/sites/
jeanbaptiste/2018/09/20/amazon-is-now-the-3-digital-ad-platform-in-the-u-s-behind-google-and-
facebook-says-emarketer/#333342de3926.
344
Id.
345
See, e.g., Shannon Bond, Google and Facebook Build Digital Ad Duopoly, F
IN
. T
IMES
(Mar.
14, 2017), https://www.ft.com/content/30c81d12-08c8-11e7-97d1-5e720a26771b; John Diaz,
Opinion, How Google and Facebook Suppress the News, S.F. C
HRON
. (Apr. 5, 2019), https://
www.sfchronicle.com/opinion/diaz/article/How-Google-and-Facebook-suppress-the-news-
13745431.php.
346
Data and Privacy Hearing at 126 (statement of Rod Sims, Chair, Austl. Competition &
Consumer Comm’n); Free and Diverse Press Hearing at 73 (statement of David Pitofsky, Gen.
Couns., News Corp).
347
Free and Diverse Press Hearing at 20 (statement of David Chavern, President, News
Media All.).
348
Daniel Funke, What’s Behind the Recent Media Bloodbath? The Dominance of Google and
Facebook, P
OYNTER
(June 14, 2017), https://www.poynter.org/business-work/2017/whats-
behind-the-recent-media-bloodbath-the-dominance-of-google-and-facebook.
shooting of Jacob Blake in Kenosha, Wisconsin.
337
In the after-
math, Facebook failed to remove a group promoting the coalescence
of an armed militia in the streets of Kenosha, despite numerous
users reporting the page.
338
Mr. Zuckerberg called this failure an
‘‘operational mistake.’’
339
(ii) Monetization. The rise of market power online has severely
affected the monetization of news, diminishing the ability of pub-
lishers to deliver valuable reporting.
340
The digital advertising market is highly concentrated, with
Google and Facebook controlling the majority of the online adver-
tising market in the United States,
341
capturing nearly all of its
growth in recent years.
342
Although Amazon has grown its digital
advertising business to become the third largest competitor in the
market,
343
it still accounts for a relatively small percentage.
344
News publishers have raised concerns that this significant level
of concentration in the online advertising market—commonly re-
ferred to as the digital ad duopoly—has harmed the quality and
availability of journalism.
345
They note that, as a result of this
dominance, there has been a significant decline in advertising rev-
enue to news publishers,
346
undermining publishers’ ability to de-
liver valuable reporting, and ‘‘siphon[ing] revenue away from news
organizations.’’
347
Jason Kint, the CEO of Digital Content Next, a trade association
that represents both digital and traditional news publishers, notes
that there is ‘‘a clear correlation between layoffs and buyouts with
the growth in market share for the duopoly—Google and
Facebook.’’
348
David Chavern, the President and CEO of the News
Media Alliance, has likewise said that ‘‘[t]he problem is that today’s
internet distribution systems distort the flow of economic value de-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00061 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
56
349
David Chavern, Opinion, How Antitrust Undermines Press Freedom, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (July 9,
2017), https://www.wsj.com/articles/how-antitrust-undermines-press-freedom-1499638532.
350
P
ENELOPE
M
USE
A
BERNATHY
, U
NIV
. N.C. S
CH
.
OF
M
EDIA &
J
OURNALISM
, T
HE
E
XPANDING
N
EWS
D
ESERT
33 (2018), https://www.cislm.org/wp-content/uploads/2018/10/The-Expanding-
News-Desert-10l14-Web.pdf.
351
Submission from Source 140, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 11 (Oct. 15, 2019) (on file
with Comm.); Submission from Source 114, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 13 (Oct. 2, 2019) (on
file with Comm.).
352
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 319.
353
Free and Diverse Press Hearing at 72 (statement of David Pitofsky, Gen. Couns., News
Corp).
354
Press Release, Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n, Holistic, Dynamic Reforms Need-
ed to Address Dominance of Digital Platforms (July 26, 2019), https://www.accc.gov.au/media-
release/holistic-dynamic-reforms-needed-to-address-dominance-of-digital-platforms.
355
Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n Report at 226.
356
Id. at 296.
357
Id. at 206, 247 (concluding that AMP is a ‘‘must have’’ product for publishers).
rived from good reporting.’’
349
The effects of this revenue decline
are most severe at the local level, where the decimation of local
news sources is giving rise to local news deserts.
350
Other news publishers have expressed concerns about the dual
role of platforms as both intermediaries and platforms for people’s
attention.
351
By keeping people inside a ‘‘walled garden,’’ platforms
can monetize their attention through ads, creating a strong eco-
nomic incentive to minimize outbound referrals that lead to a de-
cline in users’ attention and engagement. In turn, this diminishes
the incentives of publishers to invest in high-quality journalism.
352
David Pitofsky, the General Counsel of News Corp, described this
as a free-riding problem in his testimony before the Subcommittee,
explaining that platforms:
[D]eploy our highly engaging news content to target our audiences, then turn
around and sell that audience engagement to the same advertisers news pub-
lishers are trying to serve. Dominant platforms take the overwhelming majority
of advertising revenue without making any investment in the production of the
news, all while foreswearing any responsibility for its quality and accuracy. As
a result, one of the pillars of the news industry’s business model, advertising rev-
enue, is crumbling.
353
(c) International Scrutiny. Several of the concerns regarding the
distribution and monetization of news through platform inter-
mediaries were raised as part of a comprehensive inquiry by the
Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC). Over
the span of several years, the Commission collected evidence from
more than a hundred market participants and organizations as
part of its review. Following its publication of a Preliminary Report
in December 2018 and an Issues Paper in February 2018, the
ACCC issued an extensive Final Report spanning more than 600
pages and including submissions from more than 100 market par-
ticipants.
354
Among its findings, the ACCC concluded that Facebook and
Google have significant and durable market power over the dis-
tribution of news online.
355
As the ACCC noted, ‘‘Google and
Facebook are the gateways to online news media for many con-
sumers,’’ accounting for a significant amount of referral traffic to
news publishers’ websites.
356
As a result, news publishers are reli-
ant on these platforms for reaching people online, which affects
publishers’ ability to monetize journalism, particularly on formats
such as Google’s Accelerated Mobile Pages (AMP).
357
The ACCC made 23 recommendations to address concerns across
a broad range of issues, including antitrust, privacy, and consumer
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00062 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
57
358
Press Release, Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n, ACCC Commences Inquiry into
Digital Platforms (Dec. 4, 2017), https://www.accc.gov.au/media-release/accc-commences-
inquiry-into-digital-platforms.
359
Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n Report at 245.
360
Draft News Media Bargaining Code, A
USTL
. C
OMPETITION &
C
ONSUMER
C
OMM
N
, https://
www.accc.gov.au/focus-areas/digital-platforms/draft-news-media-bargaining-code (last visited
Sept. 27, 2020).
361
A
USTL
. C
OMPETITION &
C
ONSUMER
C
OMM
N
, Q
&
A
S
: D
RAFT
N
EWS
M
EDIA AND
D
IGITAL
P
LATFORMS
M
ANDATORY
B
ARGAINING
C
ODE
7 (July 2020), https://www.accc.gov.au/system/
files/DPB%20-%20Draft%20news%20media%20and%20digital%20platforms%20mandatory%20
bargaining%20code%20Q%26As.pdf.
362
Id. at 6.
363
Id. at 9.
364
Id.
365
Amanda Meade, News Corp to Suspend Print Editions of 60 Local Newspapers as Adver-
tising Revenue Slumps, G
UARDIAN
(Mar. 31, 2020), https://www.theguardian.com/media/2020/
apr/01/news-corp-to-suspend-print-editions-of-60-local-newspapers-as-advertising-revenue-
slumps.
366
Update to Our Open Letter to Australians, G
OOGLE
, https://about.google/google-in-
australia/an-open-letter/ (last visited Oct. 5, 2020).
protection.
358
Within the context of addressing the effects of mar-
ket power on the news industry—particularly as it relates to the
imbalance of bargaining power between platforms and publishers—
the Commission recommended developing ‘‘a code of conduct to gov-
ern the relationship between media businesses and digital plat-
forms [which] seeks, among other things, to address this imbal-
ance.’’
359
On July 31, 2020, the Commission released a draft code to ad-
dress a ‘‘fundamental bargaining power imbalance’’ between news
publishers and dominant platforms that has led to ‘‘news media
businesses accepting less favourable terms for the inclusion of news
on digital platform services than they would otherwise agree to in
response to a request by the Australian government.’’
360
Under this code, Facebook, Google, and other platforms with sig-
nificant bargaining power designated by Australia’s Treasurer
must negotiate with covered news publishers ‘‘in good faith over all
issues relevant to news on digital platform services.’’
361
News pub-
lishers may negotiate either individually or collectively over a
three-month period, allowing local and rural publishers ‘‘to nego-
tiate from a stronger position than negotiating individually.’’
362
If publishers are unable to reach an agreement during the medi-
ated negotiation period, they may bring the dispute to compulsory
arbitration. As part of this process, the arbitrator must consider
the parties’ final offers covering: (1) the benefits of news content to
the platform; (2) the costs of producing news by the publisher; and
(3) whether a payment model would unduly burden the commercial
interests of the platform.
363
The arbitrator must choose one of the
parties’ proposals, encouraging both parties to make reasonable of-
fers.
364
Facebook and Google have responded to the draft code by warn-
ing that they may no longer display news on their respective plat-
forms in Australia. Despite an ‘‘unprecedented surge in audiences
for news websites and TV news,’’
365
Google claims that the draft
code does not reflect the ‘‘more than $200 million in value that
Google provides to publishers each year by sending people to their
websites.’’
366
Facebook described the draft code as ‘‘unprecedented
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00063 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
58
367
Natasha Lomas, France’s Competition Watchdog Orders Google to Pay for News Reuse,
T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Apr. 9, 2020), https://techcrunch.com/2020/04/09/frances-competition-watch-
dog-orders-google-to-pay-for-news-reuse/.
368
Ashley Cullins, National Association of Broadcasters Warns Congress Tech Giants Could
Kill Local Journalism, H
OLLYWOOD
R
EP
. (Sept. 3, 2020), https://www.hollywoodreporter
.com/thr-esq/national-association-of-broadcasters-warns-congress-tech-giants-could-kill-local-
journalism.
369
Naaman Zhou, Google’s Open Letter to Australians About News Code Contains ‘‘Misin-
formation,’’ ACCC Says, G
UARDIAN
(Aug. 17, 2020), https://www.theguardian.com/technology/
2020/aug/17/google-open-letter-australia-news-media-bargaining-code-free-services-risk-contains
-misinformation-accc-says.
370
Jamie Smyth & Alex Barker, Battle Lines Drawn as Australia Takes on Big Tech Over
Paying for News, F
IN
. T
IMES
(Sept. 2, 2020), https://www.ft.com/content/0834d986-eece-4e66-
ac55-f62e1331f7f7.
371
21 C
ONG
. R
EC
. 3146 (1890) (statement of Sen. George F. Hoar).
372
Id. at 2459 (statement of Sen. John Sherman); see also 95 C
ONG
. R
EC
. 11,486 (1949)
(statement of Rep. Emanuel Celler) (‘‘[B]usiness concentration is politically dangerous, leading
inevitably to increasing Government control.’’); 96 C
ONG
. R
EC
. 16,452 (1950) (statement of Sen.
Estes Kefauver) (‘‘[T]he history of what has taken place in other nations where mergers and
concentrations have placed economic control in the hands of a very few people is too clear to
pass over easily. A point is eventually reached, and we are rapidly reaching that point in this
country, where the public steps in to take over when concentration and monopoly gain too much
power. The taking over by the public through its government always follows one or two methods
and has one or two political results. It either results in a Fascist state or the nationalization
of industries and thereafter a Socialist or Communist state.’’).
in its reach,’’ notwithstanding similar proposals in other countries,
including France,
367
as well as the United States.
368
In response to Google’s threat to boycott journalism in Australia,
ACCC Chair Rod Sims said that Google’s statement contained
‘‘misinformation’’ about the draft code, asserting that the draft code
responds to ‘‘a significant bargaining power imbalance between
Australian news media businesses and Google and Facebook.’’
369
Australia’s Treasurer, Josh Frydenberg, similarly said that the
country would not ‘‘respond to coercion or heavy-handed threats
wherever they come from.’’
370
4. Political and Economic Liberty
During the investigation, the Subcommittee examined the effects
of market power on political and economic liberty. Concerns about
the democratic effects of private monopolies trace back to the
foundational antitrust statutes, where lawmakers worried that mo-
nopolies were ‘‘a menace to republican institutions themselves.’’
371
The Subcommittee’s examination of these matters follows a long
tradition of congressional attention to this issue.
372
Based on interviews and submissions from market participants,
along with other evidence examined by the Subcommittee, there
are several ways in which the market power of the dominant plat-
forms affects political and economic power.
First, the Subcommittee encountered a prevalence of fear among
market participants who depend on the dominant platforms. Re-
peatedly, market participants expressed deep concern that speak-
ing about the dominant platforms’ business practices—even con-
fidentially without attribution—would lead a platform to retaliate
against them, with severe financial repercussions. The source of
this fear was twofold. Some firms were so dependent on the plat-
form that even potentially risking retaliation caused alarm. Others
had previously seen a platform retaliate against someone for rais-
ing public concerns about their business practices and wanted to
avoid the same fate.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00064 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
59
373
Interview with Source 636 (Mar. 11, 2020).
374
Submission from Source 147, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (on file with Comm.).
375
Submission from Source 88, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (on file with Comm.).
376
21 C
ONG
. R
EC
. 2457 (1890) (statement of Sen. John Sherman).
377
Press Release, Federal Trade Comm’n, Facebook Settles FTC Charges that It Deceived
Consumers by Failing to Keep Privacy Promises (Nov. 29, 2011), https://www.ftc.gov/news-
events/press-releases/2011/11/facebook-settles-ftc-charges-it-deceived-consumers-failing-keep
(proposed settlement).
378
Id.
379
United States v. Facebook, Inc., 456 F. Supp. 3d 115, 119 (D.D.C. 2020) (‘‘The United
States now alleges that Facebook violated the 2012 Order by ‘subvert[ing] users privacy choices
to serve its own business interests’ in several ways, starting almost immediately after agreeing
to comply with the 2012 Order.’’).
380
Id. at 117.
381
Press Release, Federal Trade Comm’n, Google and YouTube Will Pay Record $170 Million
for Alleged Violations of Children’s Privacy Law (Sept. 4, 2019), https://www.ftc.gov/news-
events/press-releases/2019/09/google-youtube-will-pay-record-170-million-alleged-violations.
382
Press Release, Dep’t of Justice, Justice Department Requires Six High Tech Companies
to Stop Entering into Anticompetitive Employee Solicitation Agreements (Sept. 24, 2010),
Continued
Several market participants told the Subcommittee that they
‘‘live in fear’’ of the platforms. One said, ‘‘It would be commercial
suicide to be in Amazon’s crosshairs .... If Amazon saw us criti-
cizing, I have no doubt they would remove our access and destroy
our business.’’
373
Another told the Subcommittee, ‘‘Given how pow-
erful Google is and their past actions, we are also quite frankly
worried about retaliation.’’
374
An attorney representing app devel-
opers said they ‘‘fear retaliation by Apple’’ and are ‘‘worried that
their private communications are being monitored, so they won’t
speak out against abusive and discriminatory behavior.’’
375
Market participants also expressed unease about the success of
their business and their economic livelihood depending on the deci-
sion-making of the platforms. A single tweak of an algorithm, in-
tentional or not, could cause significant costs if not financial dis-
aster—with little recourse. Market participants routinely charac-
terized the platforms as having arbitrary and unaccountable
power—the same forms of undue power that antitrust laws were
designed to prevent. As Senator John Sherman (R–OH) explained,
antitrust was essential to preserve liberty ‘‘at the foundation of the
equality of all rights and privileges’’ because concentrations of
power outside of democratic institutions were a ‘‘kingly prerogative,
inconsistent with our form of government.’’
376
Additionally, courts and regulators have found that several of the
dominant platforms have engaged in recidivism. For example,
Facebook settled charges brought in 2012 by the Federal Trade
Commission (FTC) that it had ‘‘deceived consumers by telling them
they could keep their information on Facebook private, and then
repeatedly allowing it to be shared and made public.’’
377
As part
of this settlement, Facebook agreed to abide by an administrative
order requiring that Facebook not misrepresent its privacy protec-
tions.
378
Seven years later, the FTC concluded that Facebook had
almost immediately begun violating that order following its adop-
tion.
379
Ruling on the FTC’s subsequent settlement with Facebook,
District Court Judge Timothy Kelley wrote that ‘‘the unscrupulous
way in which the United States alleges Facebook violated both the
law and the administrative order is stunning.’’
380
The FTC has
similarly sanctioned Google on several occasions for privacy viola-
tions.
381
In 2010, Apple settled charges it had entered into no-
poach agreements with six other technology companies.
382
Two
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00065 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
60
https://www.justice.gov/opa/pr/justice-department-requires-six-high-tech-companies-stop-
entering-anticompetitive-employee.
383
United States v. Apple, Inc., 952 F. Supp. 2d 638, 644 (S.D.N.Y. 2013), aff’d, 791 F.3d 290
(2d Cir. 2015).
384
Aug. 27, 2013 Hr’g Tr. at 17:1–6, United States v. Apple, Inc., 952 F. Supp. 2d 638
(S.D.N.Y. 2013) (No. 12–cv–2826). During the investigation, the Subcommittee also encountered
instances in which the platforms did not appear fully committed to telling lawmakers the truth,
including one incident in which members of the Subcommittee were forced to question whether
Amazon had committed perjury. Letter from Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judi-
ciary, et al., to Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc. (May 1, 2020), https://judiciary.house.gov/
uploadedfiles/2020-05-01lletterltolamazonlceolbezos.pdf.
385
See, e.g., Spencer Soper et al., Amazon’s Jeff Bezos Can’t Beat Washington, so He’s Joining
It: The Influence Game, B
LOOMBERG
(Feb. 14, 2018), https://www.bloomberg.com/graphics/
2018-amazon-lobbying/. This is a trend for the industry. The total reported lobbying expendi-
tures by digital platforms increased from $1,190,000 a year in 1998, to $74,285,000 in 2019 as
the industry consolidated and gained market power. Lobbying Spending Database, C
TR
.
FOR
R
E
-
SPONSIVE
P
OL
., https://www.opensecrets.org/lobby/top.php?indexType=i&showYear=2019 (last
visited Sept. 27, 2020).
386
See J.H. Kim, Corporate Lobbying Revisited, 10 B
US
.
&
P
OL
. 1 (2008) (analyzing lobbying’s
effect on equity returns); Brian Shaffer et al., Firm Level Performance Implications of Non-
market Actions, 39 B
US
.
&
S
OC
. 126 (2000) (analyzing lobbying’s effect on market share).
387
Andrew Perez & Tim Zelina, Facebook, Google, Amazon Are Ramping up Their Secretive
Influence Campaigns in D.C., F
AST
C
O
. (Oct. 31, 2019), https://www.fastcompany.com/9042
4503/facebook-google-amazon-are-ramping-up-their-secretive-influence-campaigns-in-dc.
388
Daisuke Wakabayashi, Big Tech Funds a Think Tank Pushing for Fewer Rules. For Big
Tech., N.Y. T
IMES
(July 24, 2020), https://www.nytimes.com/2020/07/24/technology/global-
antitrust-institute-google-amazon-qualcomm.html.
389
Competitors Hearing at 57 (question of Rep. Ken Buck (R–CO), Member, Subcomm. on
Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm on the Judiciary).
years later, Apple was found liable for orchestrating a price-fixing
conspiracy.
383
In that case, the presiding judge stated that the
record ‘‘demonstrated a blatant and aggressive disregard’’ by Apple
‘‘for the requirements of the law,’’ noting that the conduct ‘‘included
Apple lawyers and its highest level executives.’’
384
Lastly, the growth in the platforms’ market power has coincided
with an increase in their influence over the policymaking process.
Over the past decade, the dominant online platforms have signifi-
cantly increased their lobbying activity,
385
which tends to create a
feedback loop for large companies. More money spent on lobbying
may deliver higher equity returns and market share,
386
which, in
turn, may spur more lobbying.
Outside of traditionally reported and regulated lobbying, firms
with market power and dispensable income fund think tanks and
nonprofit advocacy groups to steer policy discussion. For example,
Facebook, Google, and Amazon reportedly donated significant
amounts to the American Enterprise Institute (AEI), which, in
turn, has argued that antitrust critiques of the big platforms are
‘‘astonishingly weak.’’
387
More recently, Google and Amazon have
contributed significant funding to the Global Antitrust Institute at
the George Mason University’s Antonin Scalia Law School, which
advocates against antitrust scrutiny of the dominant platforms.
388
By funding academics and advocacy groups, the dominant plat-
forms can expand their sphere of influence, further shaping how
they are governed and regulated.
At several hearings, Members of the Subcommittee noted that
the outsized political influence of dominant firms has adverse ef-
fects on the democratic process. At the Subcommittee’s field hear-
ing in Colorado, Representative Ken Buck (R–CO) asked each of
the witnesses about this issue.
389
As Representative Buck noted,
the dominant platforms are generally well represented in the pol-
icymaking process:
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00066 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
61
390
Id.
391
CEO Hearing at 7 (statement of Rep. David N. Cicilline (D–RI), Chair, Subcomm. on Anti-
trust, Commercial and Admin Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
392
Search Engine Market Share United States of America: Sept. 2019–Sept. 2020, S
TAT
C
OUNTER
, http://gs.statcounter.com/search-engine-market-share/all/united-states-of-america
(last visited Oct. 3, 2020).
Part of what we are dealing with here is the reality that [dominant firms] walk
into our offices and they tell us their side of the story and we very rarely hear
the other side of the story, and somehow part of this solution has to be that pub-
lic policymakers elected, appointed, have to have access to that kind of informa-
tion. So I thank you for being here and I also would encourage you to make sure
that, you know, we are accessible. We are trying our best to make sure that we
continue to create the environment for your kinds of companies.
390
During the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Subcommittee Chair
David N. Cicilline (D–RI) noted the democratic stakes of the Sub-
committee’s work. He said, ‘‘Because concentrated economic power
also leads to concentrated political power, this investigation also
goes to the heart of whether we, as a people, govern ourselves, or
whether we let ourselves be governed by private monopolies.’’
391
IV. MARKETS INVESTIGATED
A. Online Search
Online search engines enable users to retrieve webpages and in-
formation stored on the internet. After a user enters a query into
the search engine, the search provider returns a list of webpages
and information that are relevant to the search term entered.
There are two types of search engines: horizontal and vertical.
Horizontal search engines are designed to retrieve a comprehensive
list of general search results. Vertical search engines are designed
to retrieve a narrower category of content, such as photo images
(e.g., Dreamstime) or travel (e.g., Expedia). The majority of general
search engines monetize the service through selling ad placements
rather than charging search users a monetary price. The over-
whelmingly dominant provider of general online search is Google,
which captures around 81 percent of all general search queries in
the U.S. on desktop and 94 percent on mobile. Other search pro-
viders include Bing, which captures six percent of the market,
Yahoo (three percent), and DuckDuckGo (one percent).
392
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00067 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
62
393
Prepared by the Subcommittee based on Desktop & Mobile Search Engine Market Share
United States of America, January 2009–September 2020, S
TAT
C
OUNTER
, https://gs.statcounter
.com/search-engine-market-share/desktop-mobile/united-states-of-america/#monthly-200901-
202009 (last visited Oct. 3, 2020). The ‘‘Other’’ category includes AOL, Ask Jeeves, DuckDuckGo,
MSN, Webcrawler, Windows Live, AVG Search, Baidu, Comcast, Babylon, Dogpile, Earthlink,
Norton Safe Search, and YANDEX RU. Id.
394
Submission from Source 531, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 531–000017 (Nov. 21,
2011) (on file with Comm.). According to one market participant, ‘‘[t]he greatest challenges in
building a search index are finding the URLs for documents stored on the Web and then being
able to parse the best URLs and documents to include in the index. Overcoming these chal-
lenges requires massive amounts of data on user interactions with websites to discover new
URLs and then filter down to the 5% of known URLs [the search engine] uses to determine
which documents to index, and how frequently these documents should be refreshed.’’ Id.
395
Id. at Source 531–000016 to –000019.
396
Submission from Source 209, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 209–000537 to
–000538 (Aug. 24, 2009) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Comprehensiveness, freshness, and responsive-
ness are all directly related to the amount of computing power and storage capacity brought
to bear on the problem of crawling and indexing the web. It would therefore be implausible to
attribute Google’s massive search advantage to superior technology. Rather, the main driver of
search performance is scale. Scale is driven primarily by the level of financial investment in
search infrastructure.’’).
Desktop and Mobile Search Market Share
393
Online search comprises three distinct activities. First, an engine
must ‘‘crawl’’ the Internet by using an automated bot to collect cop-
ies of all of the webpages it can find. Once a crawler has recorded
all of this material, it must be collated and organized into an
‘‘index,’’ or a map of the Internet that can be searched in real-time.
Indexing organizes the information into the formats and databases
required for the querying function. When a user enters a query into
the search engine, the engine draws from the index to pull a list
of responsive websites, ordered in terms of relevance. The rel-
evance, in turn, is determined by the search algorithm applied by
the search engine. A search engine can function only if it has ac-
cess to an index, and an index can exist only once web pages have
been crawled and collated into a repository.
394
Indexing has high
fixed costs and requires significant server storage and compute
power.
395
The ability to invest heavily in computing power and
storage yields a significant advantage.
396
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00068 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 1 here 11701.001
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
63
397
See, e.g., Submission from Source 534, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 1 (Oct. 14, 2019)
(on file with Comm.) (‘‘[The Company] does not own its own search index and is not planning
to invest into building an own index because of the high investment costs.’’); Case AT.39740,
Google Search (Shopping), Eur. Comm’n Decision C(2017) 4444, ¶ 304 (June 27, 2017), https://
ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/decldocs/39740/39740l14996l3.pdf (‘‘Bing and
Google each spend hundreds of millions of dollars a year crawling and indexing the deep Web.
It costs so much that even big companies like Yahoo and Ask are giving up general crawling
and indexing. Therefore, it seems silly to compete on crawling and, besides, we do not have the
money to do so.’’).
398
Submission from Zack Maril, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Sept. 30, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
399
Total Number of Websites, I
NTERNET
L
IVE
S
TATS
, https://www.internetlivestats.com/total-
number-of-websites (last visited Oct. 3, 2020) (showing that, in 2000, the internet had around
17,000,000 websites; today, it has more than 1.8 billion).
400
Submission from Zack Maril, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Sept. 30, 2019) (on file with
Comm.); see also Submission from Source 481, to H. Comm on the Judiciary (Feb. 20, 2020) (on
file with Comm.); Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 340 (statement of Megan Gray,
Gen. Couns. & Pol’y Advoc., DuckDuckGo).
401
Submission from Zack Maril, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Sept. 30, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
402
Game over, F
INDX
(Sept. 21, 2019), https://web.archive.org/web/20190921180535/
https://privacore.github.io (‘‘Many large websites like LinkedIn, Yelp, Quora, Github, Facebook
and others only allow certain specific crawlers like Google and Bing to include their webpages
in a search engine index .... That meant that the Findx search index was incomplete and was
not able to return results that were likely both relevant and good quality. When you compare
any independent search engine’s results to Google for example, they have no chance to be as
relevant or complete because many large websites refuse to allow any other search engine to
include their pages.’’); Submission from Source 407, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 407–
000024 (Nov. 21, 2011) (on file with Comm.); Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 91.
Several online search features tilt the market towards the domi-
nant incumbent and make entry by new market participants dif-
ficult. First, web crawling is costly and strongly favors first-mov-
ers.
397
In a submission to the Subcommittee, one expert described
how Google’s early efforts have locked in its dominance.
398
In par-
ticular, Google was the first company to crawl the entirety of the
Internet, a feat motivated in part due to its PageRank algorithm,
which used links between pages to identify the most relevant
webpages for specific topics and queries. Unlike most search engine
algorithms at the time, the quality of PageRank results improved
with more webpages, incentivizing Google to crawl a greater por-
tion of the web.
The web has grown exponentially over the last two decades,
399
which means the cost of crawling the entire Internet has increased
too, despite advances in crawling technology. Today several major
webpage owners block all but a select few crawlers, in part because
being constantly crawled by a large number of bots can hike costs
for owners and lead their webpages to crash. The one crawler that
nearly all webpages will allow is Google’s ‘‘Googlebot,’’ as dis-
appearing from Google’s index would lead most webpages to suffer
dramatic drops in traffic and revenue.
400
Any new search engine
crawler, by contrast, would likely be blocked by major webpage
owners unless that search engine was driving significant traffic to
webpages—which a search engine cannot do until it has crawled
enough webpages.
401
The high cost of maintaining a fresh index and the decision by
many large webpages to block most crawlers significantly limits
new search engine entrants. In 2018, Findx—a privacy-oriented
search engine that had attempted to build its own index—shut
down its crawler, citing the impossibility of building a comprehen-
sive search index when many large websites only permit crawlers
from Google and Bing.
402
Today the only English-language search
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00069 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
64
403
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 89.
404
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 341 (statement of Megan Gray, Gen. Couns.
& Pol’y Advoc., DuckDuckGo) (noting that alternatives to serving ads through Google or Micro-
soft, such as only showing product ads from Amazon or travel ads from Booking.com, are ‘‘not
sufficiently lucrative to cover the costs of purchasing organic links,’’ which means ‘‘an aspiring
search engine start-up today (and in the foreseeable future) cannot avoid the need to sign a
search syndication contract’’).
405
Submission from Source 209, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 209–0000346 (Aug.
24, 2009) (on file with Comm.).
406
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 11–12.
407
Submission from Source 26, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 26–000016 (Nov. 21,
2011) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Queries are a critical component of the user data necessary to iden-
tify and rank URLs and documents for inclusion in a search index. Fewer queries mean fewer
opportunities to identify relevant URLs and documents, which ultimately means a smaller usa-
ble search index.’’); id. at Source 26–000026 (Nov. 21, 2011) (‘‘Index freshness also is an impor-
tant factor in the quality of a search engine’s result .... A [] survey found that a lack of
freshness was a significant driver of dissatisfaction among users searching in the Entertainment
and News categories.’’).
408
Submission from Source 531, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 531–000015 (‘‘The
more user queries the search engine handles, the more data it obtains to improve the relevance
of the search results it serves.’’); id. at Source 531–000060 (‘‘The secret to successful algorithmic
search matching algorithms is user feedback .... Ultimately this feedback helps the engine im-
prove core relevance and other experience factors—driving higher engagement.’’); Innovation and
Entrepreneurship Hearing at 341 (statement of Megan Gray, Gen. Couns. & Pol’y Advoc.,
DuckDuckGo) (‘‘Another barrier facing a start-up search engine is that it needs data, such as
the most commonly clicked links for a particular query, in order to produce a useful ranking
of organic links, i.e., what organic link is first, second, etc.’’); Submission from Source 209, to
H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 209–0000346 to –0000352 (Aug. 24, 2009) (on file with
Comm.) (‘‘Increased search traffic brings more indications of user intent, facilitating more ex-
perimentation and allowing a search platform to generate more relevant natural and paid
search results.’’); see also Di He et al., Scale Effects in Web Search, in W
EB AND
I
NTERNET
E
CO
-
NOMICS
294, 294–310 (Nikhil R. Devanur & Pinyan Lu eds., 2017).
409
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–03815864 (Apr. 23,
2010) (‘‘Google leads competitors .... Our long-tail precision is why users continue to come to
Google. Users may try the bells and whistles of Bing and other competitors, but Google still
produces the results. As soon as this ceases to be the case, our business is in jeopardy.’’); Com-
petition & Mkts. Auth. Report app. I, at 15 (‘‘[A]round 1% of Google ‘tail’ search events are for
queries which are seen by Bing,’’ whereas ‘‘31% of Bing ‘tail’ search events are for queries which
are seen by Google.’’ Furthermore, ‘‘0.8% of Google’s ‘tail’ distinct queries are seen by Bing,
whereas 30% of Bing’s ‘tail’ distinct queries are seen by Google.’’); see also Submission from
Source 209, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 209–0000532 (Feb. 17, 2011) (on file with
Continued
engines that maintain their own comprehensive webpage index are
Google and Bing.
403
Other search engines—including Yahoo and
DuckDuckGo—must purchase access to the index from Google and/
or Bing through syndication agreements that provide syndicated
search engines with access to search results and search adver-
tising.
404
While Yahoo previously maintained an independent
index, it entered a deal with Microsoft in 2009 to integrate search
technologies—a move driven by the two firms’ belief that combining
was necessary to provide a real alternative to Google.
405
A second major competitive advantage enjoyed by search engine
incumbents is their access to voluminous click-and-query data. This
data, which tracks what users searched for and how they
interacted with the search results, benefits search engines in sev-
eral key ways.
406
First, search engines rely on click-and-query data
to guide their search index’s upkeep, as this data helps identify
which webpages are most relevant and should be most regularly
updated in the index.
407
Second, click-and-query data is used to re-
fine the search algorithm and the relevance of search results, as
past user interactions improve the algorithm’s ability to predict fu-
ture interactions.
408
In particular, data on ‘‘tail’’ (or rare) queries
enable a search engine to offer relevant results across a higher set
of potential queries—improving the overall quality of the search en-
gine—and Google’s internal documents show that the company rec-
ognizes its long-tail advantage.
409
And third, increased query scale
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00070 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
65
Comm.) (‘‘[W]ithout strong tail performance, a horizontal search engine cannot compete against
Google.’’); id. at Source 209–0000535 to –0000536 (‘‘[P]oor search engine performance in the tail
means overall weak search engine performance.’’).
410
See, e.g., Submission from Source 531, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 531–000056
(July 11, 2011) (on file with Comm.) (stating that query scale increases advertiser engagement,
since at scale the platform ‘‘makes better matches, has higher value generation’’).
411
See Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report app. I, at 18.
412
Submission from Source 531, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 531–000874 (May 5,
2011) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘As a platform gains more and more scale, the associated benefits
begin to taper off such that eventually additional scale provides only modest returns.’’); id. at
Source 531–000025 (Nov. 21, 2011) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Above 30 billion documents, user sat-
isfaction improves rapidly with increased index size; above 90 billion documents, it still con-
tinues to improve albeit at a slower rate.’’).
413
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 342 (statement of Megan Gray, Gen. Couns.
& Pol’y Advoc., DuckDuckGo).
414
Id.
415
Mobile Operating System Market Share in United States of America—September 2020,
S
TAT
C
OUNTER
, https://gs.statcounter.com/os-market-share/mobile/united-states-of-america (last
visited Oct. 3, 2020).
416
Submission from Source 534, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 1 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
increases advertiser engagement rates, given that more user que-
ries generally translate to more advertisement clicks, generating
greater revenue for advertisers.
410
Overall there are significant advantages to scale in click-and-
query data, though the marginal benefit of additional data on tail
queries is higher than the marginal benefit of additional data on
‘‘head’’ (or relatively common) queries.
411
Some market partici-
pants also stated that the benefits of scale diminish once a search
engine reaches a certain size.
412
The benefits of scale create a feed-
back loop, where access to greater click-and-query data improves
search quality, which drives more usage and generates additional
click-and-query data.
A third barrier to competition in general online search is that
Google has established extensive default positions across both
browsers and mobile devices. Among desktop browsers, Google en-
joys default placement in Chrome (which captures 51 percent of the
U.S. market), Safari (31 percent), and Firefox (5 percent)—or 87
percent of the browser market.
413
Meanwhile, Microsoft’s Edge,
which captures four percent of the desktop browser market, sets
Bing as its search default, leaving little opening for independent
search engines.
414
In mobile, Google Search is primarily the de-
fault on Android and on Apple’s iOS mobile operating system—to-
gether, Android and iOS account for over 99 percent of
smartphones in the United States.
415
This default position provides
Google with a significant advantage over other search engines,
given users’ tendency to stick with the default choice presented.
Moreover, market participants identified several ways Google dis-
suades even those users who do attempt to switch default search
engines on Chrome.
416
Google won itself default placement across the mobile and desk-
top ecosystem through both integration and contractual arrange-
ments. By owning Android, the world’s most popular mobile oper-
ating system, Google ensured that Google Search remained domi-
nant even as mobile replaced desktop as the critical entry point to
the Internet. Documents submitted to the Subcommittee show that,
at certain key moments, Google conditioned access to the Google
Play Store on making Google Search the default search engine, a
requirement that gave Google a significant advantage over com-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00071 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
66
417
See infra Section V.
418
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 595 (response to Questions for the Record
of Kyle Andeer, Vice President, Corp. Law, Apple, Inc.).
419
See, e.g., Adam Kovacevich, Google’s Approach to Competition, G
OOGLE
P
UB
. P
OL
Y
B
LOG
(May 8, 2009), https://publicpolicy.googleblog.com/2009/05/googles-approach-to-competition
.html.
420
See, e.g., Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–01196214
(May 31, 2005) (on file with Comm.).
421
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–01680749 (Feb. 16,
2006) (on file with Comm.) (identifying several recommendations, including, ‘‘[f]ewest clicks re-
quired to change default, which promotes search innovation by facilitating the user’s ability to
switch’’).
422
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 343 (statement of Megan Gray, Gen. Couns.
& Pol’y Advoc., DuckDuckGo).
423
Id. at 343–44.
424
Id. at 339.
peting search engines.
417
Through revenue-sharing agreements
amounting to billions of dollars in annual payments, Google also
established default positions on Apple’s Safari browser (on both
desktop and mobile) and Mozilla’s Firefox.
418
In public statements, Google has downplayed the significance of
default placement, claiming that ‘‘competition is just a click
away.’’
419
However, Google’s internal documents show that when
Google was still jostling for search market share, Google executives
closely tracked search defaults on Microsoft’s Internet Explorer and
expressed concern that non-Google defaults could impede Google
Search.
420
In an internal presentation about Internet Explorer’s
default search selection, Google recommended that users be given
an initial opportunity to select a search engine and that browsers
minimize the steps required to change the default search engine.
421
These discussions—along with the steep sums Google pays Apple
and various browsers for default search placement—further high-
light the competitive significance of default positions.
Independent search engines told the Subcommittee that because
they are not set as the default search engine on popular browsers,
they face significant business challenges. As a result, DuckDuckGo
said it was compelled to invest in browser technology, including
creating its own browser for Android and iOS and various browser
extensions.
422
It noted, however, that ‘‘the same default placement
challenges exist in the browser market, just one level up—with the
device makers requiring millions or billions of dollars to become a
default browser on a device.’’
423
A fourth challenge facing upstart search engines is the growing
number of features and services that a general search provider
must offer to be competitive with Google. Through the mid-2000s,
a general search engine could compete through providing organic
links alone. Since Google and Bing now incorporate information
boxes and various specialized services directly onto their general
search results page, a market entrant would similarly need to pro-
vide a broader set of search features and services. One market par-
ticipant told the Subcommittee that this set of ‘‘mandatory high-
quality search features’’ includes maps, local business answers,
news, images, videos, definitions, and ‘‘quick answers.’’
424
Deliv-
ering this variety of features requires access to various sources of
data, raising the overall costs of entry.
Vertical search providers differ from horizontal search engines in
several ways. By offering specialized search focused on a particular
topic or activity, they fulfill a separate role and require distinct
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00072 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
67
425
Submission from Source 564, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Nov. 12, 2019) (on file with
Comm.) (‘‘The most important source of traffic for local search services are general search
websites.’’).
426
Id.; Submission from Source 115, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 19 (Dec. 27, 2019) (on
file with Comm.); Submission from Source 887, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Oct. 28, 2019)
(on file with Comm.); Submission from Foundem, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 9 (Dec. 12,
2016) (on file with Comm.).
427
Submission from Source 564, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Nov. 12, 2019) (on file with
Comm.); Submission from Source 115, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 19 (Dec. 27, 2019) (on file
with Comm.); Submission from Source 887, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Oct. 28, 2019) (on
file with Comm.); Submission from Foundem, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 9 (Dec. 12, 2016)
(on file with Comm.).
428
Submission from Source 407, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 407–000071 (Nov. 12,
2019) (on file with Comm.).
tools and expertise. The necessary inputs vary by search vertical.
Flight search, for example, requires access to flight software and
data, whereas certain local search providers rely on user-generated
content such as reviews. Many vertical providers use structured
data feeds that pull from third-party databases, rather than from
a general index.
A significant challenge for vertical providers is reaching users.
Although they serve distinct needs, most vertical search providers
still depend on horizontal search engines—and specifically on
Google—to reach users.
425
In submissions to the Subcommittee,
even some of the largest and most well-known verticals stated that
they depend on Google for up to 80–95 percent of their traf-
fic.
426
Since Google now also provides vertical search services, it
has the incentive and ability to use its dominance in horizontal
search to disfavor vertical providers that compete with its own
vertical search services. Internal documents from Google show that
it has used its dominance in general search to closely track traffic
to competing verticals, demanding that certain verticals permit
Google to scrape their user-generated content and demote several
verticals. Several market participants told the Subcommittee that
Google’s preferential treatment of its own verticals, as well as its
direct listing of information in the ‘‘OneBox’’ that appears at the
top of Google search results, has the net effect of diverting traffic
from competing verticals and jeopardizing the health and viability
of their business.
427
Google’s internal documents and submissions from third-party
market participants suggest that verticals are both a complement
to horizontal search as well as a competitive threat to it. One mar-
ket participant explained that, while vertical search providers can
increase demand for horizontal search engines in the short-term,
they can divert traffic from horizontal search providers in the long-
term, as the growing popularity of a vertical may lead users to
navigate to it directly.
428
Diverting traffic from general search pro-
viders, in turn, would deprive them of both advertiser revenue as
well as valuable click-and-query data. Given these dynamics, a
dominant horizontal search provider that also enters vertical
search faces a significant conflict of interest that can skew search
results to the detriment of third-party businesses and users alike.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00073 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
68
429
Press Release, U.S. Dep’t of Commerce, U.S. Census Bureau, Retail E-Commerce Sales in
Fourth Quarter 2001 Were $10.0 Billion, up 13.1 Percent from Fourth Quarter 2000, Census
Bureau Reports (Feb. 20, 2002), https://www2.census.gov/retail/releases/historical/ecomm/
01q4.pdf (defining e-commerce as ‘‘sales of goods and services where an order is placed by the
buyer or price and terms of sale are negotiated over an Internet, extranet, Electronic Data Inter-
change (EDI) network, electronic mail, or other comparable online system’’ and noting that
‘‘[p]ayment may or may not be made online’’).
430
Press Release, U.S. Dep’t of Commerce, U.S. Census Bureau, Quarterly Retail E-Com-
merce Sales 4th Quarter 2019 (Feb. 19, 2020), https://www2.census.gov/retail/releases/
historical/ecomm/19q4.pdf.
431
Press Release, U.S. Dep’t of Commerce, U.S. Census Bureau, Retail E-Commerce Sales in
Fourth Quarter 2001 Were $10.0 Billion, up 13.1 Percent from Fourth Quarter 2000, Census
Bureau Reports (Feb. 20, 2002), https://www2.census.gov/retail/releases/historical/ecomm/
01q4.pdf.
432
Gayle Kesten, As Online Prices Increase, Consumers’ Purchasing Power Declines, A
DOBE
:
R
ETAIL
(July 13, 2020), https://blog.adobe.com/en/2020/07/13/as-online-prices-increase-con-
sumers-purchasing-power-declines.html (‘‘[T]otal online spending of $73 billion in June marked
a 76.2 percent increase year-over-year.’’); see also A
NDREW
L
IPSMAN
, E
MARKETER
, US
E
COMMERCE BY
C
ATEGORY
2020: H
OW THE
P
ANDEMIC IS
R
ESHAPING THE
P
RODUCT
C
ATEGORY
L
ANDSCAPE
(July 22, 2020), https://www.emarketer.com/content/us-ecommerce-by-category-2020
(‘‘US ecommerce sales will surge 18.0% to $709.78 billion, while brick-and-mortar retail sales
will experience a historically significant decline of 14.0% to $4.184 trillion.’’).
433
F
EEDVISOR
, 2020 Q4 T
RENDS AND
P
ROJECTIONS
: T
HE
D
IGITAL
R
EVOLUTION OF
R
ETAIL AND
E-M
ARKETPLACES
2–3, 5 (2020) (showing that Grocery and Gourmet sales on Amazon and
Walmart were up 91 percent and 46 percent over the months of March and April 2020, respec-
tively, compared to February); see also Giselle Abramovich, How COVID–19 Is Impacting Online
Shopping Behavior, A
DOBE
: COVID–19 (Mar. 26, 2020), https://blog.adobe.com/en/2020/03/
26/how-covid-19-is-impacting-online-shopping-behavior.html (reporting that, after the COVID–
19 outbreak, ‘‘purchases for cold, cough & flu products increased 198%, while online purchases
for pain relievers increased 152%’’).
B. Online Commerce
Online commerce, also known as e-commerce, is the activity of
buying or selling products or services using the Internet.
429
E-com-
merce transactions take place through a variety of channels, in-
cluding online marketplaces like Amazon Marketplace, where a
wide variety of brands and products from different sellers are sold
in one place, or a business’s direct-to-consumer website like
Nike.com. In 2019, the U.S. Census Bureau estimated e-commerce
retail sales to be about $600 billion,
430
compared to just under $33
billion in 2001.
431
As the COVID–19 pandemic pushes more Amer-
ican shoppers online, e-commerce growth has exploded.
432
This is
particularly true for online marketplaces, where sales for essential
items like groceries, masks, and electronics for home offices in-
creased sharply in the wake of the pandemic.
433
An online marketplace’s most basic function is to serve as a plat-
form that connects buyers and sellers. Marketplaces include prod-
uct listings from a variety of sellers. Some online marketplaces,
such as Amazon and eBay, aim to be fully integrated, multi-cat-
egory e-commerce sites. Other marketplaces, however, operate as
vertical, single-category sites, such as Newegg.com, for computer
hardware and consumer electronics. The primary customers of e-
commerce marketplaces are customers looking to buy an item or
service online, and businesses looking to sell goods or services to
customers online. Because of this, a successful marketplace must
be attractive to consumers and third-party sellers.
The consumer-facing side of the marketplace allows users to
search for and purchase products. Most online marketplaces offer
features that enable users to compare competing products based on
details like their price, popularity, and customer satisfaction re-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00074 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
69
434
See, e.g., A
NDREW
L
IPSMAN
, E
MARKETER
, T
OP
10 US E
COMMERCE
C
OMPANIES
2020 (Mar.
10, 2020), https://www.emarketer.com/content/top-10-us-ecommerce-companies-2020 (fore-
casting Amazon’s e-commerce market share for 2020 at 38.7 percent, compared to second-place
Walmart at 5.3 percent and third-place eBay at 4.7 percent); see also Submission from Amazon,
to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZONlHJCl00061156 (Oct. 30, 2019) (on file with Comm.)
(showing that Amazon.com was about five times larger than eBay in 2018, its next closest mar-
ketplace competitor at the time).
435
A
NDREW
L
IPSMAN
, E
MARKETER
, T
OP
10 US E
COMMERCE
C
OMPANIES
2020 (Mar. 10, 2020),
https://www.emarketer.com/content/top-10-us-ecommerce-companies-2020.
436
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 1 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.) (‘‘AmazonBasics is an Amazon private brand that launched in 2009. The brand offers
a number of products, including electronics accessories, luggage, and office products.’’).
437
See, e.g., Amazon.com, Inc., Quarterly Report (Form 10–Q) 18 (July 31, 2020), http://
d18rn0p25nwr6d.cloudfront.net/CIK-0001018724/a77b5839-99b8-4851-8f37-0b012f9292b9.pdf
(showing net sales for third-party seller services increased from $23 billion in the first six
months of 2019 to $32 billion in the first six months of 2020).
438
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 1–2 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
439
See, e.g., Amazon.com, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 23, 47 (Jan. 31, 2017), https://
www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1018724/000101872417000011/amzn-20161231x10k.htm.
views. Amazon is by far the largest marketplace.
434
Other market-
places that are popular with consumers include eBay, Walmart,
and Wayfair.
435
Online marketplaces also serve third-party sellers. Third-party
sellers have needs that are distinct from consumers visiting the
marketplace to make a purchase. The seller-facing side of the busi-
ness consists of providing third-party sellers with a platform to list
their products for consumers to purchase. Often, the marketplace
will supply vendors with services such as inventory tracking and
pricing recommendations. Online marketplaces usually offer addi-
tional paid services to third-party sellers such as advertising and
fulfillment services, consisting of warehousing, packing, and ship-
ping.
The businesses that own and operate e-commerce marketplaces
may host only independent, third-party seller listings, or list their
own items for sale alongside third-party sellers. Amazon Market-
place is an example of the latter, in that customers view Amazon
Retail offers for its own private-label brands, such as
AmazonBasics,
436
alongside independent, third-party seller offers.
Amazon Retail also acts as a reseller of brand-name items, pur-
chasing items like Levi’s jeans from a wholesaler, and then resell-
ing them on the marketplace. In these circumstances, third-party
sellers are both customers and competitors of online marketplaces.
Marketplace operators benefit financially from the sale of serv-
ices to third-party sellers and consumers.
437
On the seller-facing
side of their business, marketplaces usually take a cut of third-
party sales and charge fees for sales-related services like fulfill-
ment, payment, and advertising. If the marketplace operators also
sell products on their own platforms, they make money like a typ-
ical retailer from the difference between the wholesale and retail
price. Marketplaces may also make money from fees paid by cus-
tomers to participate in membership programs. For example, Ama-
zon offers Amazon Prime for $119 per year as a paid membership
program that provides customers with benefits such as unlimited
free shipping on eligible items and digital streaming video.
438
Other revenue sources for marketplaces may include credit card
and gift card services that are tied to the platform.
439
A few large companies dominate the e-commerce industry, and
Amazon is the clear leader among them. The market research com-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00075 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
70
440
A
NDREW
L
IPSMAN
, E
MARKETER
, T
OP
10 US E
COMMERCE
C
OMPANIES
2020 (Mar. 10, 2020),
https://www.emarketer.com/content/top-10-us-ecommerce-companies-2020.
441
Worldwide E-Commerce and Shopping Category Performance, S
IMILAR
W
EB
(July 2020),
https://pro.similarweb.com/#/industry/overview/E-commercelandlShopping/999/1m/?web
Source=Total (showing that Amazon had 2.6 billion visits compared to 940.8 million for eBay
in July 2020).
442
L
UCY
K
OCH
, E
MARKETER
, L
OOKING FOR A
N
EW
P
RODUCT?
Y
OU
P
ROBABLY
S
EARCHED
A
MA
-
ZON
(Mar. 31, 2019), https://www.emarketer.com/content/looking-for-a-new-product-you-prob-
ably-searched-amazon (citing F
EED
V
ISOR
, T
HE
2019 A
MAZON
C
ONSUMER
B
EHAVIOR
R
EPORT
14
(2019)); see also W
UNDERMAN
T
HOMPSON
C
OMMERCE
, T
HE
F
UTURE
S
HOPPER
R
EPORT
2020, at 11
(2020) (on file with Comm.).
443
Press Release, Consumer Intel. Rsch. Partners, LLC, U.S. Amazon Prime Members—Slow,
Steady Growth (Jan. 16, 2020), https://files.constantcontact.com/150f9af2201/9f9e47b4-0d66-
4366-ad76-552ae3daa4f0.pdf; see Todd Bishop, Amazon Tops 150M Paid Prime Subscribers
Globally After Record Quarter for Membership Program, G
EEK
W
IRE
(Jan. 30, 2020), https://
www.geekwire.com/2020/breaking-amazon-tops-150m-paid-prime-members-globally-record-quar-
ter/; Parkev Tatevosian, Will Amazon Prime Reach 200 Million Members by the End of 2020?,
M
OTLEY
F
OOL
(July 18, 2020), https://www.fool.com/investing/2020/07/18/will-amazon-prime-
reach-200-million-members-by-the.aspx (noting a 29 percent increase in Amazon’s revenue in the
second quarter of 2020 versus the same quarter in 2019, primarily as a result of COVID–19).
444
Number of Sellers on Amazon Marketplace, M
ARKETPLACE
P
ULSE
, https://www.market
placepulse.com/amazon/number-of-sellers (last visited Oct. 3, 2020).
445
Walmart’s Fulfillment Service for Sellers Not Seeing Adoption, M
ARKETPLACE
P
ULSE
(Sept.
1, 2020), https://www.marketplacepulse.com/articles/walmarts-fulfillment-service-for-sellers-
not-seeing-adoption.
446
Stigler Report at 38 (describing indirect, multi-sided network effects in e-commerce, noting
that ‘‘in ecommerce platforms, which intermediate trade between sellers and buyers, a buyer
does not directly benefit from the presence of other buyers but does benefit from the presence
of more sellers—who are in turn attracted by the presence of the buyers’’).
447
Submission from Source 718, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
448
A
NDREW
L
IPSMAN
, E
MARKETER
, T
OP
10 US E
COMMERCE
C
OMPANIES
2020 (Mar. 10, 2020),
https://www.emarketer.com/content/top-10-us-ecommerce-companies-2020 (illustrating that, al-
though Walmart’s increased share of the U.S. retail e-commerce market will allow it to overtake
eBay for second place, it will remain a distant second to Amazon).
pany eMarketer estimates that Amazon is about eight times larger
than eBay and Walmart in terms of market share.
440
Other metrics
further demonstrate Amazon’s role as a gatekeeper for e-commerce.
Amazon is the most-visited website globally for e-commerce and
shopping,
441
and recent analyses suggest that over 60 percent of all
online product searches in the U.S. begin on Amazon.com.
442
Amazon’s dominance in e-commerce extends to its role as a mar-
ketplace operator and its relationship with sellers. Because of its
size and scale, no other marketplace comes close to providing sell-
ers with access to such a large pool of buyers, as well as sales-re-
lated services. There are over 112 million Prime members in the
United States—about 44 percent of the adult population. The num-
ber of Prime members has doubled since reaching 50 million mem-
bers in 2015, with Amazon projecting additional growth.
443
Ama-
zon.com has 2.3 million active sellers on its marketplace world-
wide.
444
In comparison, Amazon’s closest e-commerce competitor,
Walmart, has roughly 54,000 sellers on its marketplace.
445
In gen-
eral, the more sellers a platform has, the more buyers it can attract
and vice versa.
446
According to a competing online marketplace,
sellers feel forced to be on Amazon because that is where the buy-
ers are.
447
If current trends continue, no company is likely to pose a threat
to Amazon’s dominance in the near or distant future. Although
some alternatives to Amazon have experienced growth during the
pandemic, there is still a massive gap between the market leader
and its competitors.
448
Several factors privilege Amazon as the
dominant e-commerce marketplace, and also make entry or expan-
sion by a challenger unlikely. While some of these barriers to entry
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00076 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
71
449
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZONlHJCl00068510
(Sept. 8, 2010) (on file with Comm.).
450
See Lydia Ramsey Pflanzer, Walmart’s Talks with an Insurance Giant Could Be Part of
an Assault on Amazon Prime, B
US
. I
NSIDER
(Apr. 3, 2018), https://www.businessinsider.com/
morgan-stanley-why-walmart-could-bid-on-humana-2018-4.
451
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 53.
452
Jan H. Kietzmann, Kristopher Hermkens, Ian P. McCarthy & Bruno S. Silvestre, Social
Media? Get Serious! Understanding the Functional Building Blocks of Social Media, 54 B
US
. H
O
-
RIZONS
241 (2011), http://summit.sfu.ca/system/files/iritems1/18103/2011lsociallmedia
lbh.pdf.
453
Submission from Source 247, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 247–0000000006 (Oct.
23, 2019) (on file with Comm.); Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 53.
454
Submission from Source 471, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 4 (Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with
Comm.) (‘‘[T]here are a number of other competitors who focus on different or additional aspects
of public and private communication. For example, some competitors focus on sharing and ex-
pression though images and other media (e.g., Instagram, YouTube, and Pinterest). Some com-
panies focus more on private communications (e.g., WhatsApp, Snap (for the most part),
Facebook, Signal, and Telegram). Other companies focus on communications about specific top-
ics (e.g., Discord for gaming and Slack for workplace communications).’’).
455
Submission from Source 164, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 164–000015 (Oct. 28,
2019) (on file with Comm.) (describing how online advertising requires building an ad product,
a sales team to sell that product, and the engineering and product capacity to target and meas-
ure the effectiveness of those ads).
456
F
IONA
M. S
COTT
M
ORTON &
D
AVID
C. D
INIELLI
, O
MIDYAR
N
ETWORK
, R
OADMAP FOR AN
A
NTITRUST
C
ASE
A
GAINST
F
ACEBOOK
3 (2020) [hereinafter Omidyar Network Report], https://
www.omidyar.com/wp-content/uploads/2020/06/Roadmap-for-an-Antitrust-Case-Against-
Facebook.pdf.
are inherent to e-commerce—such as economies of scale and net-
work effects—others result from Amazon’s anticompetitive conduct.
As discussed elsewhere in the Report, Amazon’s acquisition strat-
egy and many of its business practices were successfully designed
to protect and expand its market power. An Amazon executive re-
ferred to some of these tactics as the company’s ‘‘Big Moats,’’ and
suggested ‘‘doubl[ing] down’’ on them in a business strategy docu-
ment.
449
Similarly, in 2018, an investment analyst report ex-
pressed skepticism about Walmart’s ability to challenge Amazon,
commenting, ‘‘[W]e are concerned Amazon’s Prime membership pro-
gram is fortifying an impenetrable moat around its customers.’’
450
C. Social Networks and Social Media
Social media products and services include social networking,
messaging, and media platforms designed to engage people by fa-
cilitating sharing, creating, and communicating content and infor-
mation online.
451
Although the boundaries of the social media mar-
ket are imprecise,
452
social media platforms generally allow users
on their networks to interact with people or groups they know, dis-
play content through linear feeds, or otherwise add socially layered
functionality for services online, usually through a mobile app. In
response to the Committee’s requests for information, several mar-
ket participants said they view social media as driven by networks,
while many social media products and services include common
functionalities, such as public profiles, curated feeds, followers,
messaging, and other use cases.
453
Others focus on certain aspects
of public and private communications.
454
A principal feature of social media platforms is that they typi-
cally offer their services for a zero monetary price to the platform’s
users.
455
The platform develops a service it hopes will attract a
critical mass of users to then attract advertisers to the plat-
form.
456
Some social media companies offer additional services to
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00077 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
72
457
L
INKED
I
N
P
REMIUM
, https://premium.linkedin.com/ (last visited Oct. 3, 2020).
458
Production from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FBlHJClACALl00059100
(Apr. 6, 2012) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Advertising is a scale thing, it wasn’t until we reached
350 million users did we become interesting to big brands.’’).
459
Briefing with Brad Smith, President, Microsoft, in Washington, D.C. (June 23, 2020).
460
Submission from Source 164, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 164–000014 (Oct. 28,
2019) (on file with Comm.). But see B
UNDESKARTELLAMT
[Federal Cartel Office], C
ASE
S
UMMARY
:
F
ACEBOOK
, E
XPLOITATIVE
B
USINESS
T
ERMS
P
URSUANT TO
S
ECTION
19(1) GWB
FOR
I
NADEQUATE
D
ATA
P
ROCESSING
5 (Feb. 15, 2019), https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Ent
scheidung/EN/Fallberichte/Missbrauchsaufsicht/2019/B6-22-16.pdf?lblob=publicationFile
&v=4 (‘‘At least as far as the services affected in this case are concerned, it is not sufficient
to have a ‘critical mass’ of users or technical, financial and personal expertise in order to be
able to enter neighbouring markets and be as successful as on the original market. As the exam-
ple of Google+ has shown, a service cannot expect to have the same reach when providing a
different type of service, due to strong direct network effects.’’).
461
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 115.
462
Michelle Santiago Cortes, These Are the TikTok Editing Apps You’ve Been Seeing on Your
‘‘For You’’ Page, R
EFINERY
29 (Mar. 25, 2020), https://www.refinery29.com/en-us/tik-tok-editing-
apps.
463
Zac Hall, Lens Is a Modern and Feature-Packed Instagram App for Apple Watch that
Works Without the iPhone, 9
TO
5M
AC
(Apr. 24, 2019), https://9to5mac.com/2019/04/24/lens-
instagram-for-apple-watch/.
464
Omidyar Network Report at 22.
465
Id. at 22–25; Submission from Source 471, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 8 (Oct. 15, 2019)
(on file with Comm.) (‘‘In or around 2010, [Source 471] restricted the access of our API by some
Continued
users for a price or allow users to pay for additional functionality.
For example, LinkedIn Premium provides users with an option to
pay for additional features, such as their network and in-app mes-
saging insights.
457
Social media platforms with a larger network of users are more
likely to attract users and advertisers.
458
In a briefing to Sub-
committee members and staff, Brad Smith, the President of Micro-
soft, described this value:
You don’t always need to have a proven business model to attract capital. You
just need an idea that will get a lot of users. And then people assume you’ll find
a way to turn that usage into a business model that will produce revenue. That’s
been very important for the US. It distinguishes us and allows venture funding.
There’s something magical about 100 million active monthly users (MAU) in the
United States. At that level a company becomes a force unto themselves. If you
see a company acquire another company that’s in the same product market and
is on the path to reach 100 million MAU, that’s more likely to raise a competitive
concern. Historically, I think regulators were slow to notice that issue.
459
As another market participant describes it, ‘‘attracting a critical
mass of users is essential to delivering a viable social network, as
there is no reason for users to start using a social network if there
is no one there with whom they can connect.’’
460
Social media companies may also focus on attracting particular
types or groups of consumers to differentiate themselves from larg-
er companies.
461
Many of the top-ranking apps on iOS are com-
plementary to popular social media applications. For example, Dazz
Cam, a vintage-inspired photo-editing app used with TikTok, was
popular in the U.S. in 2020.
462
Similarly, Lens is a popular iOS
app that allows users to browse, like, and comment on photos and
videos on Instagram using the Apple Watch.
463
Due to network effects in the social media market, new entrants
may choose to begin as a complement by relying on the incumbent
platform’s application programming interfaces (APIs), such as
Facebook’s Open Graph or Twitter’s search API.
464
However, be-
cause incumbent platforms control access to these APIs and can
foreclose access to a complementary app that is successful or gain-
ing users,
465
some market participants view relying on these plat-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00078 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
73
third-party developers because we had significant concerns regarding some third-
partydevelopers use of [Source 471]’s private data. In order to protect private data, [Source 471]
determined such changes were necessary to ensure that these data were not used improperly.’’).
466
Submission from Source 164, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 164–00023 (Oct. 28,
2019) (on file with Comm.); Submission from Source 471, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 10 (Oct.
15, 2019) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘[Our company’s] business would be affected if other social net-
working networks were to disallow cross-posting . . . to their platforms or discontinue APIs cen-
tral to the functionality of our products or services.’’).
467
Submission from Source 471, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 10 (Oct. 15, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
468
Omidyar Network Report at 16.
469
Submission from Source 407, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 4 (Nov. 1, 2019); Competition
& Mkts. Auth. Report at 55 (‘‘Differentiation can incentivise consumers to access multiple plat-
forms, allowing for the co-existence of platforms.’’).
470
Submission from Source 164, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source–32–000014 (Oct. 28,
2019) (on file with Comm.) (discussing how they see ‘‘social media sites’’ as competitors for ads
even though they don’t think they are in that market).
471
See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 51–52 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (‘‘[T]he relevant
market must include all products ‘reasonably interchangeable by consumers for the same pur-
poses.’ ’’) (quoting United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours, 351 U.S. 377, 395 (1956)); see also
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 117–18 (‘‘[T]he closeness of competition between different
platforms depends on the degree to which consumers consider them substitutes, rather than the
extent to which they share common functionalities.’’).
472
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 54 (citing Bundeskartellamt, Feb. 6, 2019, B6–22/
16, ¶ 249, https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Entscheidung/EN/Entscheidun gen/
Missbrauchsaufsicht/2019/B6-22-16.pdf?lblob=publicationFile&v=5).
473
Id.
474
Id.
forms to reach users as a constant business risk.
466
One market
participant noted that, in addition to harming its business, these
actions also ‘‘restrict users’ ability to multi-home and increase bar-
riers to entry, including network effects and switching costs.’’
467
Given Facebook’s dominance, the primary way for new entrants
to compete is to attract a subgroup or niche.
468
One market partici-
pant explained, ‘‘competitors may be limited to niche strategies
that do not challenge the incumbent directly. For example,
Facebook (including Instagram) is by far the most popular social
networking platform. Although there are several competitors, such
as LinkedIn, and fast-growing new entrants, such as TikTok, most
or all employ niche strategies to varying degrees, and most have
far less user engagement, attention, and data and a smaller share
of advertising revenue than Facebook.’’
469
1. Social Networks Are Distinguishable from Social Media
While a broad view of the social media market is useful for con-
sidering the wider landscape for social data and online adver-
tising,
470
it is important to focus on the actual use, demand, and
substitutability of social products when examining competition
among social platforms online.
471
The critical distinction between
social networking and social media markets is how people use the
platform. As Germany’s Federal Cartel Office (Bundeskartellamt)
and the United Kingdom’s Competition and Markets Authority
(CMA) have noted, the specific demand for social networks ‘‘is fun-
damentally different from the demand for other social media.’’
472
Social network platforms facilitate their users finding, inter-
acting, and networking with other people they already know online,
and by providing a ‘‘rich social experience’’ through features on
their products.
473
People regularly use social network platforms to
exchange ‘‘experiences, opinions and contents among specific con-
tacts which the users define based on identity.’’
474
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00079 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
74
475
Omidyar Network Report at 6.
476
Letter from Michael Beckerman, Vice President, Head of U.S. Pub. Pol’y, TikTok, to Hon.
David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.
Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. F. James Sensenbrenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Anti-
trust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Jerrold Nadler,
Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. Jim Jordan, Ranking Member, H. Comm. on the Judi-
ciary 1 (July 29, 2020), https://docs.house.gov/meetings/JU/JU05/20200729/110883/HHRG-
116-JU05-20200729-SD005.pdf.
477
Omidyar Network Report at 6.
478
T
HOMAS
C
UNNINGHAM
, P
OSSIBLE
E
ND
S
TATES FOR THE
F
AMILY OF
A
PPS
(2018) (on file with
Comm.) (discussing social networking platforms with comparable and orthogonal social graphs).
479
Average Time Spent Daily on Social Media (Latest 2020 Data), B
ROADBAND
S
EARCH
,
https://www.broadbandsearch.net/blog/average-daily-time-on-social-media#post-navigation-4
(last visited Oct. 3, 2020).
480
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 115 n.140 (indicating that there are several other
smaller firms that conform to this definition of social media but lack a significant user base).
481
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–00086585 (Jan. 2020)
(on file with Comm.).
In contrast, social media platforms principally facilitate the dis-
tribution and consumption of content. Much of the content on
YouTube, for example, can be enjoyed by users with a wide range
of relationships to the person posting, including by strang-
ers.
475
Similarly, TikTok describes itself as a ‘‘global platform for
users to express their ideas by sharing videos with a broader com-
munity.’’
476
In light of this distinction, the CMA concluded that
YouTube is focused on offering content and does not compete with
Facebook, facilitating communication and sharing content among
groups of friends who choose each other and enjoy content in large
part because of those relationships.
477
In sum, social networking sites have a robust social graph,
whereas content-centric sites do not.
478
Although users can share
videos or stream events on Facebook and YouTube in similar ways,
there is a fundamental difference between sharing a video among
a person’s social network on Facebook, Instagram, or WhatsApp—
such as a child’s first steps—and broadcasting it publicly on
YouTube. While people may spend significant time on both
YouTube and Facebook,
479
these firms provide distinct services to
their users, and including both in the same market would be incon-
sistent with how users engage with each platform.
2. Market Concentration
Social platforms that are within a broad definition of social
media include YouTube, Facebook and its family of products—
Instagram, Messenger, and WhatsApp—as well as TikTok, Twitter,
LinkedIn, Pinterest, Reddit, and Tumblr.
480
According to
Facebook’s internal market data, YouTube and Facebook’s family of
products were by far the most popular social media sites by Month-
ly Active Persons (MAP) as of December 2019.
481
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00080 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
75
482
Prepared by the Subcommittee based on the Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on
the Judiciary, FB–HJC–00086585 (Jan. 2020) (on file with Comm.) (metrics collected by
Facebook, Inc.).
483
T
HOMAS
C
UNNINGHAM
, P
OSSIBLE
E
ND
S
TATES FOR THE
F
AMILY OF
A
PPS
(2018) (on file with
Comm.) (discussing social networking platforms with comparable and orthogonal social graphs).
484
See Alex Sherman, TikTok Reveals Detailed User Numbers for the First Time, CNBC (Aug.
24, 2020), https://www.cnbc.com/2020/08/24/tiktok-reveals-us-global-user-growth-numbers-for-
first-time.html.
485
See, e.g., Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJClAPPLEl000003
(Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with Comm.); Letter from Exec. at Source 736, to Members of the
Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 4 (Oct.
31, 2019) (on file with Comm.); B
RICS
C
OMPETITION
, I
NNOVATION
, L
AW &
P
OL
Y
C
TR
., D
IGITAL
E
RA
C
OMPETITION
: A B
RICS
V
IEW
347 (2019), http://bricscompetition.org/upload/iblock/6a1/
brics%20book%20full.pdf.
Social Media Companies by Monthly Active Persons (MAP)
in Millions
482
The social network marketplace is highly concentrated. Facebook
(1.8 billion users) and its family of products—WhatsApp (2.0 billion
users) and Instagram (1.4 billion users)—have significantly more
users and time spent on its platform than its closest competitors,
Snapchat (443 million users) or Twitter (582 million users).
483
TikTok is growing quickly and is often referenced as evidence that
the social media landscape is competitive.
484
Although it meets the
broad definition of social media as a social app for distributing and
consuming video content, TikTok is not a social network.
D. Mobile App Stores
Mobile application stores (app stores) are digital stores that en-
able software developers to distribute software applications (apps)
to mobile device users.
485
A mobile app is a standardized piece of
software optimized for use on a mobile device. Users can install
this software to access digital content or services, share content,
play games, or make transactions for physical goods and services.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00081 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 2 here 11701.002
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
76
486
N
ETH
. A
UTH
.
FOR
C
ONSUMERS &
M
KTS
., M
ARKET
S
TUDY INTO
M
OBILE
A
PP
S
TORES
20
(2019), https://www.acm.nl/sites/default/files/documents/market-study-into-mobile-app-stores
.pdf [hereinafter Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study].
487
Id.
488
See Apple App Store Review Guidelines, A
PPLE
, https://developer.apple.com/app-store/
review/guidelines/#legal (last visited Oct. 3, 2020); Apple Developer Program License Agreement,
A
PPLE
, https://developer.apple.com/services-account/agreement/XV2A27GUJ6/content/pdf
(last visited Oct. 3, 2020); Google Play Developer Policy Center, G
OOGLE
, https://play.google
.com/about/developer-content-policy/ (last visited Oct. 3, 2020); Google Play Developer Distribu-
tion Agreement, G
OOGLE
, https://play.google.com/intl/ALLlus/about/developer-distribution-
agreement.html (last visited Oct. 3, 2020).
489
See CEO Hearing at 397 (response to Questions for the Record of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple,
Inc.); see also J
OHN
B
ERGMAYER
, P
UB
. K
NOWLEDGE
, T
ENDING THE
G
ARDEN
: H
OW TO
E
NSURE
THAT
A
PP
S
TORES
P
UT
U
SERS
F
IRST
1, 5, 18 (2020), https://www.publicknowledge.org/wp-
content/uploads/2020/06/TendinglthelGarden.pdf.
490
Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJClAPPLEl000003 (Oct. 14,
2019) (on file with Comm.); Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 108.
491
D
ELOITTE
, T
HE
A
PP
E
CONOMY IN THE
U
NITED
S
TATES
8 (2018), https://www.ftc.gov/
system/files/documents/publiclcomments/2018/08/ftc-2018-0048-d-0121-155299.pdf.
492
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 29.
Apps are configured to run on a device’s operating system as ‘‘na-
tive apps.’’ These apps may be pre-installed on a mobile device as
a component of the operating system or by the device manufac-
turer, downloaded from an app store, or loaded directly from the
web using a browser—a process referred to as sideloading. Soft-
ware developers upload apps and updates to app stores, and mobile
device users can then install apps by downloading them from the
app store to their device.
App stores include free and paid apps that charge a fee. In addi-
tion to allowing users to install apps, app stores enable users to
search, browse, and find reviews for apps, as well as remove apps
from their devices.
486
The leading app stores also offer tools and
services to support developers building apps for the app store.
487
App stores have rules that govern the types of apps permitted in
the app store, conduct of app developers, how users pay for apps,
the distribution of revenue between the app and the app store, and
other details regarding the relationship between the app store op-
erator and the app developers that distribute apps through the
store.
488
App stores provide mobile device users with a sense of trust and
security that the apps they install from an app store have been re-
viewed, will not harm the user’s mobile device, will function as in-
tended, and will not violate user privacy.
489
App stores also reduce
customer acquisition costs for app developers by allowing devel-
opers to reach an extraordinarily large consumer base—every mo-
bile device user in the U.S. is addressable by developing for the
Apple App Store and the Google Play Store. By reducing the costs
of app developers, app stores help make software applications more
affordable for consumers.
490
Deloitte has explained that app stores provide developers with
various benefits, including providing a consistent interface and ex-
perience for users on a mobile operating system, a secure platform
for apps, storage systems for hosting apps and managing
downloads and updates, and billing and payment management sys-
tems that can reduce overhead for developers.
491
Apple and Google
also provide developers with software-development tools to create,
test, and publish apps; technical support and analytics tools; and
tutorials.
492
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00082 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
77
493
Id. at 15.
494
See Data and Privacy Hearing at 155 (statement of Maurice E. Stucke, Prof. of Law, Univ.
of Tenn., & Ariel Ezrachi, Slaughter & May Prof. of Competition Law, Univ. of Oxford, Fellow,
Pembroke Coll., Dir., Oxford Ctr. for Competition Law & Pol’y).
495
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 4, 21.
496
See Interview with Source 407 (Sept. 10, 2020); Interview with Source 143 (Aug. 27, 2020);
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 51–52, 67, 73.
497
See Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Fines Google Ö4.34 Billion for Il-
legal Practices Regarding Android Mobile Devices to Strengthen Dominance of Google’s Search
Engine (July 18, 2018), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/IPl18l4581;
Letter from Exec. at Source 181, to Members of the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and
Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 4 (Oct. 31, 2019) (on file with Comm.); Submis-
sion from Source 301, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5, 7 (Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
498
Number of Apps Available in Leading App Stores as of 1st Quarter 2020, S
TATISTA
,
https://www.statista.com/statistics/276623/number-of-apps-available-in-leading-app-stores/
(last visited Oct. 5, 2020).
499
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 50; Interview with Source 766 (July 2, 2020).
500
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 50. See also Press Release, Eur. Comm’n,
Antitrust: Commission Fines Google Ö4.34 Billion for Illegal Practices Regarding Android Mobile
Devices to Strengthen Dominance of Google’s Search Engine (July 18, 2018), https://
ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/IPl18l4581 (explaining that worldwide, ex-
cluding China, ‘‘the Play Store accounts for more than 90% apps downloaded on Android de-
vices’’).
501
Joe Hindy, 10 Best Third Party App Stores for Android and Other Options Too, A
NDROID
A
UTH
. (Aug. 28, 2020), https://www.androidauthority.com/best-app-stores-936652/.
The mobile operating system on a device determines which app
stores the user can access. The provider of the mobile operating
system determines which app stores may be pre-installed on de-
vices running the operating system, and whether and how addi-
tional app stores may be installed. As discussed elsewhere in the
Report, both Apple and Google have durable and persistent market
power in the mobile operating system market; iOS and Android run
on more than 99 percent of mobile devices in the U.S. and glob-
ally.
493
There are high switching costs in the mobile operating sys-
tem market and high barriers to entry. Due to their dominance in
the mobile operating system market, Apple and Google have the
power to dictate the terms and extent of competition for distrib-
uting software on mobile devices running their respective mobile
operating systems.
494
The Google Play Store is the primary app store installed on all
Android devices. The Apple App Store is the only app store avail-
able on iOS devices.
495
Apps are not interoperable between oper-
ating systems—native apps developed for iOS only work on iOS de-
vices, and native apps developed for Android only work on Android
devices.
496
The App Store and the Play Store do not compete
against one another. Android users cannot access the Apple App
Store, and iOS users cannot access the Google Play Store, so the
dominance of the Play Store is not constrained by the App Store
and vice versa.
497
Statista reports that in the first quarter of 2020 there were ap-
proximately 2.56 million apps available in the Google Play Store
and 1.847 million apps available in Apple’s App Store.
498
Apple’s
App Store is the only means to distribute software on iOS de-
vices.
499
The Google Play Store is the dominant app store on An-
droid devices; however, Google does permit users to sideload alter-
native app stores. Some Android device partners, such as Samsung,
pre-install their own app stores on their devices.
500
Leading alter-
native Android app stores include Amazon’s Appstore, Aptoide, F-
Droid, and the Samsung Galaxy Store.
501
App developers who want
to reach the entire addressable market of U.S. or global
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00083 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
78
502
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 15.
503
See, e.g., Interview with Source 143 (Aug. 27, 2020); Submission from Facebook, to H.
Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00045377 (Feb. 14, 2014) (on file with Comm.) (dem-
onstrating that Facebook COO Sheryl Sandberg explained to Facebook’s Board of Directors that
Apple’s and Google’s positions as dominant mobile operating system and app store operators
posed a ‘‘significant strategic threat’’ to Facebook’s business and adding another popular mobile
app to Facebook’s suite of apps ‘‘would make it more difficult for operating system providers
to exclude the Company’s mobile applications from mobile platforms’’); Letter from Exec. at
Source 181, to Members of the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.
Comm. on the Judiciary, 4 (Oct. 31, 2019) (on file with Comm.); Kara Swisher, Is It Finally
Hammer Time for Apple and Its App Store, N.Y. T
IMES
(June 19, 2020), https://
www.nytimes.com/2020/06/19/opinion/apple-app-store-hey.html?referringSource=articleShare.
504
CEO Hearing at 397 (response to Questions for the Record of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple, Inc.).
505
Data and Privacy Hearing at 145 (statement of Maurice E. Stucke, Prof. of Law, Univ.
of Tenn., & Ariel Ezrachi, Slaughter & May Prof. of Competition Law, Univ. of Oxford, Fellow,
Pembroke Coll., Dir., Oxford Ctr. for Competition Law & Pol’y).
506
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 29; see also Press Release, Japan Fair Trade
Comm’n, Report Regarding Trade Practices on Digital Platforms: Business-to-Business Trans-
actions on Online Retail Platform and App Store 24–25 (Oct. 2019), https://www.jftc.go.jp/en/
pressreleases/yearly-2019/October/191031Report.pdf (explaining that consumers rely on pre-in-
stalled app stores to install apps, so developers believe they ‘‘have no choice but to use the app
store services’’ to reach consumers).
507
See Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00068877
(Feb. 21, 2012) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Native apps will dominate over mobile-web for a long time
(maybe forever) and we cannot prop up HTML–5 / are not strong enough to lead a shift—The
mobile OS makers have a strong incentive in native apps performing better / working better than
the web? so theory / what is possible aside, native apps will work better & be better experiences
than the mobile web.’’); Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 42–51, 69.
smartphone users must have an app in both the App Store and the
Play Store.
502
Apple and Google also determine the terms and con-
ditions app developers must agree to in order to distribute software
through the App Store and Play Store, respectively. As a result,
app developers and industry observers agree that Apple and Google
control the app distribution market on mobile devices.
503
There is no method for a third-party app store to challenge the
App Store on iOS devices. Apple CEO Tim Cook told the Sub-
committee that Apple has no plans to open iOS to alternative app
stores.
504
For a third-party app store to successfully challenge the
Play Store, consumers must be able to install the app store, and
the store must have popular apps that users want. As with mobile
operating systems, network effects create momentum so that as
more consumers install software from the app store, more devel-
opers will build apps for the app store, increasing the value of the
app store for users and attracting more consumers. Once users
have migrated to a large platform—such as an operating system
and its app store, it is difficult for smaller competitors to attract
users and app developers.
505
The United Kingdom’s Competition and Markets Authority ob-
served that ‘‘almost all mobile app downloads are made through
the App Store, on iOS devices, or Google Play, on Android de-
vices.’’
506
Alternatives app distribution methods such as third-
party app stores, gaming platforms, or sideloading are often irrele-
vant to the mobile applications market, not always practical op-
tions for users, have significant disadvantages compared to the pre-
installed app stores, and offer only limited functionality.
507
Websites and web apps are not competitively significant alter-
natives to the dominant app stores on iOS and Android devices for
distributing software to mobile devices. Apps provide a deeper,
richer user experience and can provide additional functionality by
accessing features within the mobile device’s hardware and oper-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00084 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
79
508
See Letter from Exec. at Source 181, to Members of the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commer-
cial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 1 (Oct. 31, 2019) (on file with Comm.);
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 59, 81.
509
See Interview with Source 88 (May 12, 2020).
510
App Store Review Guidelines, A
PPLE
§ 4.2, https://developer.apple.com/app-store/review/
guidelines/#design (last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
511
CEO Hearing at 397 (response to Questions for the Record of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple, Inc.).
512
See Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJClAPPLEl000003 (Oct.
14, 2019) (on file with Comm.); Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 102.
513
C
OMSCORE
, 2019 R
EPORT
G
LOBAL
S
TATE OF
M
OBILE
7 (2019); see also Letter from Exec.
at Source 181, to Members of the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the
H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 1 (Oct. 31, 2019) (on file with Comm.); Submission from Source 301,
to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 7 (Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
514
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 45–46; Submission from Source 736, to H.
Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 736–00000166 (July 1, 2019).
515
Interview with Source 59 (May 13, 2020).
516
Interview with Source 83 (June 30, 2020).
ating system, such as a camera or location services.
508
Web apps
and browsers are also reliant on the device being connected to the
internet. Native apps can continue to work even when a device
loses access to the internet.
509
Apple’s App Store Review Guide-
lines differentiate apps from websites, explaining that apps sub-
mitted to the App store ‘‘should include features, content and [a
user interface] that elevate [the app] beyond a repackaged
website.’’
510
Curation and centralized review of apps is an advan-
tage touted by app store operators. Apple CEO Tim Cook explained
to the Subcommittee that on iOS devices, Apple’s control of soft-
ware installation through the App Store ensures downloaded apps
‘‘meet our high standards for privacy, performance, and security,’’
which is important for maintaining user trust.
511
Additionally, dis-
tributing software via app stores lowers customer acquisition costs
for software developers.
512
Consumers do access content on their mobile devices via the open
internet. However, mobile apps are the primary way users access
content and services on mobile devices and have become integral
in Americans’ daily lives for basic communication, business trans-
actions, entertainment, and news. In the U.S., nearly 90 percent of
the time users spend online on mobile devices occurs in
apps.
513
Software distribution via web apps or through a website
accessible on a browser is not a competitively significant alter-
native to distributing apps through the dominant app store on a
mobile device and does not discipline the market power of the dom-
inant app stores controlled by Apple and Google.
Similarly, the ability for consumers to sideload apps—installing
apps without using an app store—does not discipline the domi-
nance of Apple and Google in the mobile app store market. Apple
does not permit users to sideload apps on iOS devices, and few con-
sumers have the technical savvy to ‘‘jailbreak’’ an iOS device to
sideload apps.
514
Google does permit sideloading on Android de-
vices, but developers find that, given the option, consumers prefer
to install apps from app stores, and few opt for sideloading.
515
Google has created significant friction for sideloading apps to An-
droid devices. One developer explained to the Subcommittee that
sideloading entails a complicated twenty-step process, and users
encounter multiple security warnings designed to discourage
sideloading.
516
Additionally, software developers that have left the
Play Store to distribute software to Android users via sideloading
have experienced precipitous declines in downloads and revenue
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00085 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
80
517
See Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 48; J
OHN
B
ERGMAYER
, P
UB
. K
NOWL
-
EDGE
, T
ENDING THE
G
ARDEN
: H
OW TO
E
NSURE THAT
A
PP
S
TORES
P
UT
U
SERS
F
IRST
44 (2020),
https://www.publicknowledge.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/06/TendinglthelGarden.pdf;
Interview with Source 83 (June 30, 2020).
518
See J
OHN
B
ERGMAYER
, P
UB
. K
NOWLEDGE
, T
ENDING THE
G
ARDEN
: H
OW TO
E
NSURE THAT
A
PP
S
TORES
P
UT
U
SERS
F
IRST
19 (2020), https://www.publicknowledge.org/wp-content/
uploads/2020/06/TendinglthelGarden.pdf.
519
See id. at 7, 19.
520
See Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 3, 15.
521
See A
NALYSIS
G
RP
., A
PPLE
S
A
PP
S
TORE AND
O
THER
D
IGITAL
M
ARKETPLACES
: A C
OMPARI
-
SON OF
C
OMMISSION
R
ATES
4–6 (2020), https://www.analysisgroup.com/globalassets/insights/
publishing/appleslapplstorelandlotherldigitallmarketplaceslalcomparisonlofl
commissionlrates.pdf.
522
See id. at 4.
523
See Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 23, 29, 86, 89.
524
See, e.g., Letter from Exec. at Source 181, to Members of the Subcomm. on Antitrust,
Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3, 5–6 (Oct. 31, 2019) (on file
with Comm.); Submission from Source 736, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 736–00000009
(on file with Comm.); Submission from Source 304, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 7–8 (Sept.
3, 2020); see also Reed Albergotti & Tony Romm, Tinder and Fortnite criticize Apple for Its ‘‘App
Store Monopoly,’’ W
ASH
. P
OST
(June 16, 2020), https://www.washingtonpost.com/technology/
2020/06/16/apple-antitrust-european-commission/.
525
See Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 29.
526
Id. at 29.
and report problems updating their apps.
517
Thus, the option for
sideloading apps on mobile devices does not discipline the market
power of dominant app stores.
There are no competitive constraints on the power Apple and
Google have over the software distribution marketplace on their
mobile ecosystems. The core benefit of mobile app stores—central-
izing and curating software distribution—also gives Apple and
Google control over which apps users discover and can install.
518
As the gateways to the primary way users access content and serv-
ices on mobile devices, the App Store and the Play Store can ex-
tract revenue from and exercise control over everything users do on
their devices.
519
This dominance enables Apple and Google to es-
tablish terms and conditions app developers have to comply with,
leaving developers with the choice of complying or losing access to
consumers. The terms and conditions app stores impose include re-
quirements regarding app functionality, content, interactions with
consumers, collection, and distribution of revenue between the app
and app store.
520
Mobile app stores charge app developers commissions on sales of
paid apps through the app store. Apple and Google, along with
other mobile app stores on Android devices, charge a 30 percent
commission when users install the app.
521
Apple established its 30
percent commission on paid apps in 2009 with the introduction of
the App Store, and that rate has become the industry standard.
522
Apple and Google have both developed mechanisms for collecting
payments from users for purchases within applications—these
transactions are called in-app purchases (IAP). Apple and Google
both charge developers a standard 30 percent for IAP.
523
In col-
lecting IAP, Apple and Google collect user personal and payment
information, process the payment, and then remit the payment to
the app developer, minus a processing fee or commission.
524
Devel-
opers selling digital content through their apps on iOS and Android
devices are required to use the app store operator’s IAP.
525
For
subscription services, like news apps or streaming media, the com-
mission is 15 percent for the second year and thereafter.
526
IAP
systems provide mobile device users with convenience by allowing
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00086 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
81
527
Id. at 7.
528
See Interview with Source 83 (June 30, 2020); Competitors Hearing at 33 (statement of
David Heinemeier Hansson, Cofounder & Chief Tech. Officer, Basecamp).
529
See Letter from Exec. at Source 181, to Members of the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commer-
cial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 9–10 (Oct. 31, 2019) (on file with
Comm.) (internal citations omitted); Submission from Source 736, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
Source 736–00000236 (Oct. 23, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
530
Press Release, Japan Fair Trade Comm’n, Report Regarding Trade Practices on Digital
Platforms: Business-to-Business Transactions on Online Retail Platform and App Store 21 (Oct.
2019), https://www.jftc.go.jp/en/pressreleases/yearly-2019/October/191031Report.pdf.
531
See, e.g., Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 22, 31–32, 69, 89–90, 95–99.
532
Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 29–30.
consumers to make transactions in their apps and only enter their
payment details a single time, and they protect user privacy by
limiting sharing of sensitive financial information.
527
However, de-
velopers have noted that the lack of competition in pricing by app
stores, particularly given the scale the App Store and Play Store
have achieved since introducing their standard commission rates
for paid apps and in-app purchases, demonstrates the lack of com-
petition in the software distribution market on both the iOS and
Android ecosystems.
528
Developers have also said that the 30 per-
cent commissions charged by app stores have led them to increase
prices for consumers and diminished innovation by software devel-
opers.
529
Apple and Google also develop and distribute apps that directly
compete against third-party developers in their app stores.
530
This
dynamic, coupled with the fact that App Store and Play Store are
dominant distribution channels and can exert gatekeeper power
over their platforms, has the potential to distort competition, lead
to discrimination and higher entry barriers for third-party devel-
opers, and result in the app store operator self-preferencing its own
apps, harming consumers and competition.
531
New app stores face high barriers to entry. It is unlikely that a
third strong mobile app ecosystem can emerge. To offer a new mo-
bile app store that is compelling to consumers, the app store must
have a built-in customer base to attract developers to build apps
for the store and must have popular apps to attract customers. Be-
fore the introduction of the App Store, third-party apps were not
a central component of the user experience on mobile devices. New
entrants, such as Apple, could disrupt the mobile device and oper-
ating system market by offering superior handset design, user
interface, and first-party applications. Now, third-party apps are
critical to the success of any mobile ecosystem. Millions of apps are
developed for iOS and Android, and leading device manufacturers
have built their device ecosystems around those operating systems.
As a result, it is unlikely that a new mobile operating system en-
trant can disrupt the current market dynamics.
532
Because of the
control that Apple and Google exert over software distribution on
their mobile ecosystems and the unlikelihood of entry by a new
competitive mobile operating system, it is unlikely that a new, com-
petitive app store will be able to successfully challenge the existing,
dominant app store operators.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00087 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
82
533
See Steven Bo
¨
hm, Fabian Adam & Wendy Colleen Farrell, Impact of the Mobile Operating
System on Smartphone Buying Decisions: A Conjoint-Based Empirical Analysis, in M
OBILE
W
EB
AND
I
NTELLIGENT
I
NFORMATION
S
YSTEMS
198, 198–210 (Muhammad Younas, Irfan Awan &
Massimo Mecella eds., 2015), https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-23144-0l18.
534
See GSMA I
NTEL
., G
LOBAL
M
OBILE
T
RENDS
2020: N
EW
D
ECADE
, N
EW
I
NDUSTRY
?, 6, 26
(2019), https://data.gsmaintelligence.com/api-web/v2/research-file-download?id=47743151&
file=2863-071119-GMT-2019.pdf.
535
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 15; see also Dig. Competition Expert Panel
Report at 29 (‘‘However market shares are measured, Google (Android) and Apple (iOS) have
a global duopoly over mobile phone operating systems.’’); Michael Muchmore, Android vs. iOS:
Which Mobile OS Is Best?, PCM
AG
(Aug. 11, 2020), https://www.pcmag.com/comparisons/
android-vs-ios-which-mobile-os-is-best (‘‘[W]e’re locked in a duopoly when it comes to mobile op-
erating system choice.’’).
536
A Short History of KaiOS, K
AI
OS, https://developer.kaiostech.com/introduction/history
(last visited Oct. 4, 2020); Stephen Shankland, Mozilla Helps Modernize Feature Phones Powered
by Firefox Tech, CNET (Mar. 11, 2020), https://www.cnet.com/news/mozilla-helps-modernize-
feature-phones-powered-by-firefox-tech/.
537
See Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJClAPPLEl000021 (Oct.
14, 2019) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Many smartphone brands around the world compete with
iPhone on the basis of price, performance, features, and design. These smartphones generally
incorporate Google’s Android operating system.’’).
E. Mobile Operating Systems
A mobile operating system (OS) provides a mobile device with its
underlying functionality, such as user interface, motion commands,
and button controls, and it facilitates the operation of the device’s
features, such as the microphone, camera, and GPS. The mobile OS
is the interface between the mobile device hardware, such as the
smartphone handset or tablet, and the applications that run on the
device, like email or streaming apps. The mobile OS is pre-installed
on mobile devices; an alternative mobile OS cannot be installed or
substituted. The characteristics of the mobile OS determine aspects
of the mobile device’s performance and functionality, including the
app stores and apps that can run on the device. The mobile OS also
determines which company’s ecosystem of products and services the
device is integrated with.
533
Google’s Android and Apple’s iOS are the two dominant mobile
operating systems.
534
Combined, they run on more than 99 percent
of all smartphones in the world.
535
The third-largest mobile oper-
ating system is KaiOS, which runs on feature phones (i.e., non-
smartphone mobile devices).
536
Apple’s mobile devices run on Ap-
ple’s proprietary iOS operating system, while other leading handset
manufacturers, such as Samsung, LG, and Motorola, run on An-
droid.
537
iOS is not available on non-Apple devices.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00088 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
83
538
Prepared by the Subcommittee based on Felix Richter, The Smartphone Market: The
Smartphone Duopoly, S
TATISTA
(July 27, 2020), https://www.statista.com/chart/3268/
smartphone-os-market-share/ (citing Mobile Operating System Market Share Worldwide,
S
TAT
C
OUNTER
G
LOBAL
S
TATS
) (StatCounter ‘‘calculates the data based on more than 1.7 billion
page views per month worldwide. StatCounter defines a mobile device as a pocket-sized com-
puting device. As a result, tablets are not included .... Nokia devices (including some S40 de-
vices) had been grouped largely under Symbian OS.’’).
539
See Felix Richter, The Smartphone Market: The Smartphone Duopoly, S
TATISTA
(July 27,
2020), https://www.statista.com/chart/3268/smartphone-os-market-share/ (citing Mobile Oper-
ating System Market Share Worldwide, S
TAT
C
OUNTER
G
LOBAL
S
TATS
) (‘‘Having started out as a
multi-platform market, the smartphone landscape has effectively turned into a duopoly in recent
years, after Apple’s iOS and Google’s Android crowded out any other platform including
Microsoft’s Windows Phone, BlackBerry OS and Samsung’s mobile operating system called
Bada.’’); Data and Privacy Hearing at 147 (statement of Maurice E. Stucke, Prof. of Law, Univ.
of Tenn, & Ariel Ezrachi, Slaughter & May Prof. of Competition Law, Univ. of Oxford, Fellow,
Pembroke Coll., Dir., Oxford Ctr. for Competition Law & Pol’y) (‘‘The mobile operating system
market went from multiple competitors in 2010 (with Google and Apple collectively accounting
for 39 percent of unit sales), to a duopoly eight years later.’’); Matthew Feld, Microsoft Is Finally
Killing Off the Windows Phone, T
ELEGRAPH
(Oct. 9, 2017), https://www.telegraph.co.uk/tech-
nology/2017/10/09/microsoft-finally-killing-windows-phone/; Arjun Kharpal, TCL Launches
New $549 Smartphone Under BlackBerry’s Banner, Featuring Android Software, CNBC (Feb. 25,
2017), https://www.cnbc.com/2017/02/25/blackberry-keyone-launch-physical-keyboard-android-
specs-price.html); Jack Schofield, Can I Buy a Phone that Doesn’t Use Anything from Google or
Apple?, G
UARDIAN
(July 4, 2019), https://www.theguardian.com/technology/askjack/2019/jul/
04/can-i-buy-a-phone-that-does-not-use-anything-from-google-or-apple.
540
See, e.g., Simon O’Dea, Market Share of Mobile Operating Systems in the United States
from January 2012 to December 2019, S
TATISTA
(Feb. 27, 2020), https://www.statista.com/sta-
tistics/272700/market-share-held-by-mobile-operating-systems-in-the-us-since-2009/.
Mobile OS Market Share Worldwide
538
Over the past decade, once-strong competitors have exited the
mobile OS market, and Google and Apple have built dominant posi-
tions that are durable and persistent.
539
While there are other mo-
bile OSs—such as Tizen, Sailfish OS, and Ubuntu Touch—those
OSs make up less than 1 percent of the global mobile OS mar-
ket.
540
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00089 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 3 here 11701.003
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
84
541
Prepared by the Subcommittee based on Simon O’Dea, Market Share of Mobile Operating
Systems in the United States from January 2012 to December 2019, S
TATISTA
(Feb. 27, 2020),
https://www.statista.com/statistics/272700/market-share-held-by-mobile-operating-systems-in-
the-us-since-2009/ (citing Mobile Operating System Market Share in United States of America,
S
TAT
C
OUNTER
).
542
Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Fines Google Ö4.34 Billion for Illegal
Practices Regarding Android Mobile Devices to Strengthen Dominance of Google’s Search En-
gine (July 18, 2018), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/IPl18l4581.
543
M
ORNINGSTAR
E
QUITY
A
NALYST
R
EPORT
: A
PPLE
I
NC
1 (Aug. 6, 2020) (on file with
Comm.).
544
iPhone vs. Android—Cell Phone Brand Loyalty Survey 2019, S
ELL
C
ELL
(Aug. 20, 2019),
https://www.sellcell.com/blog/iphone-vs-android-cell-phone-brand-loyalty-survey-2019/; see also
M
ORNINGSTAR
E
QUITY
A
NALYST
R
EPORT
: A
PPLE
I
NC
2 (Aug. 6, 2020) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Re-
cent survey data shows that iPhone customers are not even contemplating switching brands
today. In a December 2018 survey by Kantar, 90% of U.S.-based iPhone users said they planned
to remain loyal to future Apple devices.’’).
Market Share of Mobile Operating Systems
in the U.S.
541
Although Google Android and Apple iOS both have dominant po-
sitions in the mobile OS market, high switching costs and a lack
of on-device competition mean that neither firm’s market power is
disciplined by the presence of the other. The European Commis-
sion’s investigation into Google’s Android platform found that, be-
cause iOS is not available on non-Apple devices, it cannot constrain
Google’s dominance in the mobile OS market.
542
Conversely, An-
droid is not available on Apple devices and does not constrain Ap-
ple’s dominant position and conduct on Apple mobile devices. An
investment research firm recently noted that switching costs were
high for Apple users because iOS is not available on non-Apple de-
vices.
543
There are significant barriers to switching between the dominant
mobile operating systems. As a general matter, consumers rarely
switch mobile operating systems. SellCell’s 2019 survey found that
more than 90 percent of users with iPhones tend to stick with
Apple when they replace their current device.
544
In 2018, Con-
sumer Intelligence Research Partners reported that more than 85
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00090 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 4 here 11701.004
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
85
545
Press Release, Consumer Intel. Rsch. Partners, LLC, Mobile Operating System Loyalty:
High and Steady (Mar. 8, 2018), http://files.constantcontact.com/150f9af2201/4bca9a19-a8b0-
46bd-95bd-85740ff3fb5d.pdf.
546
Martin Armstrong, Most iPhone Users Never Look Back, S
TATISTA
(May 22, 2017), https://
www.statista.com/chart/9496/most-iphone-users-never-look-back/.
547
Interview with Source 72 (June 23, 2020).
548
Interview with Source 83 (June 30, 2020).
549
Press Release, Consumer Intel. Rsch. Partners, LLC, Mobile Operating System Loyalty:
High and Steady (Mar. 8, 2018), http://files.constantcontact.com/150f9af2201/4bca9a19-a8b0-
46bd-95bd-85740ff3fb5d.pdf.
550
See Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 55–56; Press Release, Eur. Comm’n,
Antitrust: Commission Fines Google Ö4.34 Billion for Illegal Practices Regarding Android Mobile
Devices to Strengthen Dominance of Google’s Search Engine (July 18, 2018), https://
ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/IPl18l4581; see also iPhone vs. Android—
Cell Phone Brand Loyalty Survey 2019, S
ELL
C
ELL
(Aug. 20, 2019), https://www.sellcell.com/
blog/iphone-vs-android-cell-phone-brand-loyalty-survey-2019/ (finding ‘‘21% of iPhone users
might be tempted to switch if they weren’t too tied into the Apple Ecosystem or it wasn’t so
much hassle changing operating system from iOS to Android’’ and ‘‘13% of Samsung users might
be tempted to switch if they weren’t too tied into the Google/Android Ecosystem or it wasn’t
so much hassle changing operating system’’).
551
Don Reisinger, Steve Jobs Wanted to ‘‘Further Lock Customers’’ into Apple’s ‘‘Ecosystem,’’
CNET (Apr. 2, 2014), https://www.cnet.com/news/steve-jobs-wanted-to-further-lock-customers-
into-apples-ecosystem/.
552
M
ORNINGSTAR
E
QUITY
A
NALYST
R
EPORT
: A
PPLE
I
NC
2 (Aug. 6, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
percent of iOS users who purchased a new device purchased an-
other iOS device, and more than 90 percent of Android users who
bought a new device purchased a new Android device.
545
A 2017
study from Morgan Stanley found that 92 percent of iPhone owners
intending to buy a new mobile device planned to buy another
iPhone.
546
Mobile carriers—a main retail distribution channel for
mobile devices—agreed that it is rare for customers to switch from
one mobile OS because, once customers are used to the mobile OS,
they generally do not switch.
547
App developers also said in inter-
views with the Subcommittee that they observed minimal customer
switching between iOS and Android.
548
In addition to the cost of buying a new mobile device, consumers
encounter other costs to switch to a new operating system. Android
and iOS have different operating concepts, user interface designs,
and setting and configuration options. As a result, instead of
switching operating systems, ‘‘users pick one, learn it, invest in
apps and storage, and stick with it.’’
549
Other barriers to switching include the loss of compatibility with
other smart devices designed to work in conjunction with the mo-
bile device and its OS, the hassle of porting data from one OS to
another, re-installing apps and configuring settings, and learning
an unfamiliar user interface.
550
Apple’s cofounder and former CEO
Steve Jobs advocated for this approach, noting that Apple should
‘‘[t]ie all of our products together, so we further lock customers into
our ecosystem.’’
551
Recently, Morningstar observed that people
using Apple’s other products such as the Apple Watch and AirPods
‘‘lose significant functionality when paired with a smartphone other
than the iPhone,’’ locking iPhone users into the iOS eco-
system.
552
Competition regulators in the Netherlands explained
that this strategy creates ‘‘path dependency’’ for consumers. Al-
though mobile devices have a limited lifespan, and consumers
might be expected to ‘‘break the lock-in cycle’’ when it is time to
upgrade to a new device, consumers often have software, data and
files, and other hardware and accessories that are only compatible
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00091 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
86
553
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 21, 55–56.
554
Interview with Source 407 (Sept. 10, 2020).
555
Submission from Source 385, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Sept. 18, 2020) (on file
with Comm.).
556
Data and Privacy Hearing at 148 (statement of Maurice E. Stucke, Prof. of Law, Univ.
of Tenn., & Ariel Ezrachi, Slaughter & May Prof. of Competition Law, Univ. of Oxford, Fellow,
Pembroke Coll., Dir., Oxford Ctr. for Competition Law & Pol’y); see also Richard Trenholm, Ele-
gant Ubuntu Touch OS Impresses for Phones and Tablets (Hands-On), CNET (Feb. 28, 2013),
https://www.cnet.com/reviews/ubuntu-touch-preview/; Adrian Covert, The Ubuntu Smartphone
(Which No One Will Use) Is a Glimpse of the Future, CNN B
US
. (Jan. 2, 2013), https://
money.cnn.com/2013/01/02/technology/mobile/ubuntu-smartphone-linux/ (explaining success
in the mobile market required more than merely building a superior OS to Android or iOS; it
also requires a robust app ecosystem).
557
M
ORNINGSTAR
E
QUITY
A
NALYST
R
EPORT
: A
PPLE
I
NC
3 (Aug. 6, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
558
Interview with Source 407 (Sept. 10, 2020).
559
Id.
560
M
ORNINGSTAR
E
QUITY
A
NALYST
R
EPORT
: A
PPLE
I
NC
3 (Aug. 1, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
561
Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 29.
with one product ecosystem, making it unlikely that they switch to
a non-compatible mobile device.
553
There are significant entry barriers in the mobile operating sys-
tem market. One former mobile OS competitor observed that its ex-
perience showed that it was doubtful that a new, competitive mo-
bile OS will emerge in the U.S.
554
Another former mobile OS pro-
vider explained that it exited the market after concluding ‘‘the mar-
ket for mobile operating systems was too established for a new
entry.’’
555
To compete, a new OS must offer a superior product
packaged in an attractive handset, as well as a fully realized suite
of apps and compatible devices comparable to what Apple and
Google (and Google’s hardware partners) currently offer. Industry
experts have testified before the Subcommittee that the ‘‘reality is
that it would be very difficult for a new mobile phone operating
system today’’ to compete with Apple and Google, ‘‘even if it offered
better features.’’
556
Investment analysts agree, noting it is likely
Android and iOS ‘‘will continue to power nearly every smartphone
around the world in the long run.’’
557
The mobile OS market is also characterized by strong network
effects. In short, a new mobile OS must have a sufficiently large
user base to attract app developers to build apps to run on the OS.
An OS with an insufficient number of users and developers is un-
likely to receive support from mobile device manufacturers that
will install the OS on their devices, or mobile network operators
that will support those devices on their networks.
558
The most important factor that developers consider before build-
ing apps for an OS is the install base of the OS—how many users
have devices running the OS that can install the app. Developers
will not build apps for an OS with few users.
559
This reinforces the
power of dominant mobile operating systems. The more consumers
use the OS, the more developers will build apps for the OS, in-
creasing the value of the OS for users and attracting more con-
sumers.
560
Consumers are unlikely to purchase a device with an
OS that cannot run the most popular apps and lacks a robust app
ecosystem comparable to what is offered by iOS and Android. Due
to the dominance of Apple and Google in the mobile OS and app
store markets, ‘‘there is little incentive for app developers to go to
the trouble and expense of ensuring their apps work on any small-
er rival operating systems,’’ because the user base would be too
small.
561
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00092 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
87
562
Id. at 40.
563
See Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Fines Google Ö4.34 Billion for Il-
legal Practices Regarding Android Mobile Devices to Strengthen Dominance of Google’s Search
Engine (July 18, 2018), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/IPl18l4581.
564
See GSMA I
NTEL
., G
LOBAL
M
OBILE
T
RENDS
2020: N
EW
D
ECADE
, N
EW
I
NDUSTRY?
26
(2019), https://data.gsmaintelligence.com/api-web/v2/research-file-download?id=47743151&
file=2863-071119-GMT-2019.pdf; Interview with Source 83 (June 30, 2020).
565
See Ryan Mac, What Amazon Can Learn from the Failed Facebook Phone, F
ORBES
(June
17, 2014), https://www.forbes.com/sites/ryanmac/2014/06/17/what-amazon-can-learn-from-
the-failed-facebook-phone/#7f7d402f47de; Roger Cheng, Here’s Why the Facebook Phone Flopped,
CNET (May 8, 2013), https://www.cnet.com/news/heres-why-the-facebook-phone-flopped/;
Marcus Wohlsen, The Amazon Fire Phone Was Always Going to Fail, W
IRED
(Jan. 6, 2015),
https://www.wired.com/2015/01/amazon-fire-phone-always-going-fail/; Austin Carr, The In-
side Story of Jeff Bezos’ Fire Phone Debacle, F
AST
C
O
. (Jan. 6, 2015), https://www.fastcompany
.com/3039887/under-fire.
566
See Austin Carr, The Inside Story of Jeff Bezos’ Fire Phone Debacle, F
AST
C
O
. (Jan. 6,
2015), https://www.fastcompany.com/3039887/under-fire.
567
See J. Sullivan, Firefox OS: Looking Ahead, M
OZILLA
B
LOG
(Jan. 6, 2014), https://
blog.mozilla.org/blog/2014/01/06/firefox-os-looking-ahead/; Ingrid Lunden, Mozilla Will Stop
Developing and Selling Firefox OS Smartphones, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Dec. 8, 2015), https://
techcrunch.com/2015/12/08/mozilla-will-stop-developing-and-selling-firefox-os-smartphones/;
Chris Hoffman, Mozilla Is Stopping All Commercial Development on Firefox OS, PC W
ORLD
(Sept. 28, 2016), https://www.pcworld.com/article/3124563/mozilla-is-stopping-all-commercial-
development-on-firefox-os.html.
568
See Don Reisinger, Acer Taps Alibaba’s Aliyun OS for New Smartphone, CNET (Sept. 12,
2012), https://www.cnet.com/news/acer-taps-alibabas-aliyun-os-for-new-smartphone/; Edward
Moyer, Alibaba: Google Just Plain Wrong About Our OS, CNET (Sept. 15, 2012), https://
www.cnet.com/news/alibaba-google-just-plain-wrong-about-our-os/; Roger Cheng, Alibaba:
Google Forces Acer to Drop Our New Mobile OS, CNET (Sept. 13, 2012), https://www.cnet.com/
news/alibaba-google-forced-acer-to-drop-our-new-mobile-os/; T.C. Sottek, Acer Cancels Phone
Launch with Alibaba, Allegedly in Response to Threats from Google, V
ERGE
(Sept. 13, 2012),
https://www.theverge.com/2012/9/13/3328690/acer-google-alibaba-phone; Dieter Bohn, Google
Explains Why It Stopped Acer’s Aliyun Smartphone Launch (Updated), V
ERGE
(Sept. 14, 2012),
https://www.theverge.com/2012/9/14/3335204/google-statement-acer-smartphone-launch-
aliyun-android; Jon Brodkin, Google Blocked Acer’s Rival Phone to Prevent Android ‘‘Fragmenta-
Continued
Additionally, the third-party app ecosystem advantages of iOS
and Android make new market entry unlikely. The U.K.’s Competi-
tion and Markets Authority explained that, before the iPhone,
third-party apps were not part of the mobile experience. As a re-
sult, new entrants like Apple could enter the market and compete
by offering a superior product. But now, there are ‘‘millions of apps
that have been written for Apple’s iOS and Google’s Android, mak-
ing it hard for a new entrant mobile operating system to offer a
competitive and attractive product.’’
562
The European Commission
(E.C.) has similarly observed that strong network effects have cre-
ated high entry barriers in the mobile OS market.
563
Over the past decade, several large technology companies have
attempted and failed to leverage their large user bases to compete
against Apple and Google in the mobile OS market.
564
Facebook
and Amazon both tried to enter the market with variants of
Google’s Android OS. Both companies quickly exited the market be-
cause consumers were mostly accessing Facebook and Amazon con-
tent through apps on iOS and Android devices.
565
Technology re-
viewers also expressed disappointment that Amazon’s Fire Phone
did not offer the same extensive library of apps and services as iOS
or Android devices.
566
Companies like Mozilla and Alibaba have also attempted to enter
the mobile OS market. Mozilla unveiled its Firefox OS in 2013 and
exited the market altogether by 2016.
567
In 2012, Chinese tech
giant Alibaba developed a mobile OS called Aliyun for the Chinese
market. However, Acer, Alibaba’s hardware partner, abruptly can-
celed its collaboration with Alibaba before the launch of Acer’s de-
vice running the OS.
568
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00093 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
88
tion,’’ ARS T
ECHNICA
(Sept. 14, 2012), https://arstechnica.com/gadgets/2012/09/google-
blocked-acers-rival-phone-to-prevent-android-fragmentation/.
569
See Arjun Kharpal, TCL Launches New $549 Smartphone Under BlackBerry’s Banner,
Featuring Android Software, CNBC (Feb. 27, 2017), https://www.cnbc.com/2017/02/25/black-
berry-keyone-launch-physical-keyboard-android-specs-price.html.
570
See Press Release, Gartner, Gartner Says Worldwide Sales of Smartphones Grew 7 Per-
cent in the Fourth Quarter of 2016 (Feb. 15, 2017), https://www.gartner.com/en/newsroom/
press-releases/2017-02-15-gartner-says-worldwide-sales-of-smartphones-grew-7-percent-in-the-
fourth-quarter-of-2016).
571
Tom Warren, Windows Phone Dies Today, V
ERGE
(July 11, 2017), https://www
.theverge.com/2017/7/11/15952654/microsoft-windows-phone-end-of-support; see also Press Re-
lease, Gartner, Gartner Says Worldwide Sales of Smartphones Grew 7 Percent in the Fourth
Quarter of 2016 (Feb. 15, 2017), https://www.gartner.com/en/newsroom/press-releases/2017-
02-15-gartner-says-worldwide-sales-of-smartphones-grew-7-percent-in-the-fourth-quarter-of-2016;
James Vincent, 99.6 Percent of New Smartphones Run on Android or iOS, V
ERGE
(Feb. 16,
2017), https://www.theverge.com/2017/2/16/14634656/android-ios-market-share-blackberry-
2016.
572
Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 40.
573
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 589 (response to Questions for the Record
by Kyle Andeer, Vice President, Corp. Law, Apple, Inc.); Submission from Google, to H. Comm.
on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04208423 (June 2013) (on file with Comm.) (showing that, prior
to being acquired by Google, a Waze presentation stated, ‘‘There are very few companies in the
world that are making navigable maps, and the process is very expensive.’’); Submission from
Source 531, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 531–000628 (on file with Comm.).
574
Submission from Source 531, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 531–000628 (on file
with Comm.).
Over the past decade, once-competitive mobile operating systems
like Nokia, BlackBerry, and Microsoft struggled to survive as Apple
and Google grew more dominant, eventually exiting the market-
place altogether. BlackBerry—once a leading mobile OS devel-
oper—now licenses the BlackBerry name to TCL to market TCL’s
smartphones. TCL’s BlackBerry phones run on Android.
569
In the
last quarter of 2016, Windows devices accounted for less than half
of 1 percent of new smartphone sales.
570
In 2017, Microsoft aban-
doned its mobile OS business, and by that time, more than 99 per-
cent of all new smartphones were running on iOS or Android, and
market observers expressed no confidence that new competition
would emerge.
571
One key factor leading to Microsoft’s withdrawal
from the mobile marketplace was that developers were reluctant to
develop apps for a third mobile operating system when already
building apps for iOS and Android.
572
These market dynamics re-
main in place today.
F. Digital Mapping
Digital mapping provides users with virtual maps of the physical
world. There are two sets of customers for mapping services: con-
sumers, who use map products for navigation, and businesses, who
use underlying mapping libraries and design tools to produce cus-
tomized maps. With the proliferation of smart devices, digital map-
ping has become a critical resource for users and businesses alike.
The essential input for both types of services is a digital-map
database. Mapping data can be gathered in a few ways, including
through the collection of imagery from satellites and streets, the
tracking of global positioning system (GPS) traces, and the colla-
tion of public domain mapping data. Building a digital map data-
base is costly and time-intensive, requiring significant investment
in mapping technologies and data collection.
573
The leading pro-
vider of digital mapping data is Google. Smaller providers include
HERE and TomTom, as well as open-source providers like
OpenStreetMap (OSM).
574
Waze, which developed navigable maps
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00094 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
89
575
Although Apple Maps licensed U.S. mapping data from TomTom upon launching in 2012,
in 2015, it began developing its own map database by deploying cars with cameras and sensors
to collect images and mapping data that it could combine with anonymized iPhone data to create
an independent underlying base map. Lauren Goode, The Biggest Apple Maps Change Is One
You Can’t See, W
IRED
(Jan. 31, 2020), https://www.wired.com/story/apple-maps-redesign/.
576
Submission from Source 572, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 1 (Oct. 29, 2019) (on file with
Comm.) (‘‘For vehicle navigation, and excluding OEM-provided in-console automotive systems,
Google’s Waze and Google Maps are currently the most used consumer apps by a wide margin.’’);
Submission from Source 333, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Oct. 21, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
577
Daniel Schaal, Google Maps Poised to Be an $11 Billion Business in 4 Years, S
KIFT
(Aug.
30, 2019), https://skift.com/2019/08/30/google-maps-poised-to-be-an-11-billion-business-in-4-
years/; R
OSS
S
ANDLER
, B
ARCLAYS
, A
LPHABET
I
NC
.: S
TEADY
C
OMPOUNDER
, W
ITH
P
LENTY OF
I
N
-
NOVATION
A
HEAD
20 (Mar. 28, 2017) (on file with Comm.).
578
Submission from Source 572, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 1 (Oct. 29, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
579
Id.
580
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04209630 (Nov.
2012) (on file with Comm.).
by relying on driver-generated live maps and crowd-sourced up-
dates, was an additional mapping provider purchased by Google in
June 2013.
Consumer-facing providers of mapping services license map data-
bases and layer search and traffic technologies atop of the map
data. Consumers use these search and traffic tools either through
a standalone turn-by-turn navigation service that licenses the un-
derlying data—like MapQuest or Bing Maps—or through a
vertically integrated provider, like Google Maps, Waze, or Apple
Maps.
575
The dominant providers of consumer mapping applica-
tions are Google Maps and Google-owned Waze, followed by Apple
Maps and MapQuest.
576
Google and Apple set their mapping prod-
ucts as the default options on Android and iOS products—their re-
spective devices—which also enables them to maintain and expand
their market position.
These providers of consumer mapping services generally do not
charge users a monetary fee. Instead, they monetize maps through
selling location-based advertisements or by subsidizing consumer-
facing mapping with enterprise contracts or other lines of business.
Although data on the value of the consumer-facing digital mapping
industry is not publicly available, analysts have estimated that
Google Maps earned Google around $2.95 billion in revenue last
year and that the standalone product is worth up to $60 billion.
577
Business-facing providers serve map design tools and mapping li-
braries required to produce customized maps. The leading pro-
viders of business-to-business mapping software are Google, HERE,
Mapbox, and TomTom, followed by Apple Maps, Bing, ESRI,
Comtech, and Telenav.
578
Some of these providers operate in more
specialized markets. For example, HERE and TomTom primarily
serve automotive customers, while ESRI provides desktop GIS soft-
ware used by governments and spatial analysts.
579
Market participants cite several factors that privilege dominant
digital map incumbents and impede entry. First is the capacity of
dominant firms to invest heavily in creating mapping databases
and technology without needing to turn a profit. For example, prior
to its acquisition by Google, Waze executives observed that Google
Maps had ‘‘disrupted the market’’ primarily through ‘‘financial dis-
ruption,’’ namely that it had ‘‘unlimited funds’’ and was giving
away Google Maps to users for free.
580
Startups seeking to enter
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00095 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
90
581
Submission from Source 531, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 531–000624 (on file
with Comm.). Google made a similar observation in July 2013. In a letter responding to the
FTC’s request for information relating to its acquisition of Waze, Google wrote, ‘‘Apple has ac-
cess to as much or more US GPS traffic data than Google does, with tens of millions of Apple
iOS users potentially providing Apple with real-time traffic speed and flow information through-
out the country.’’ Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04211078
(July 24, 2013) (on file with Comm.).
582
Submission from Source 572, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Oct. 29, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
583
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 15.
this market—yet lacking the financial cushion that permits them
to incur losses while developing the product—will be at a relative
disadvantage.
Another factor is that incumbents that are integrated can collect
relevant map and location data from across complementary lines of
business, feeding this data back into mapping. For example, one
market participant noted that Google ‘‘collects an unparalleled
amount of data used in digital mapping from users of its dominant
search engine and Android smartphone OS.’’
581
Another market
participant stated that Google’s dominant position in search and
advertising incentivizes businesses to closely monitor and maintain
the accuracy of their information in Google’s systems, ‘‘leading to
a dynamic by which Google enjoys a free, crowdsource effort to im-
prove and maintain their data’s quality,’’ thereby improving the
quality of Google Maps.
582
Firms without concurrent positions in
web search and the smartphone market are comparatively dis-
advantaged.
A third factor is the superior distribution that integrated firms
in maps-adjacent lines of business can provide their own mapping
product at the expense of third-party mapping products. Google
gives Google Maps default placement on its Android devices, while
Apple does the same with Apple Maps on iOS devices. Together,
Android and iOS account for 99 percent of the smartphone oper-
ating systems in the United States.
583
Market participants explained that the default placement of
Google Maps on Android devices also disadvantages third-party
mapping providers technologically. If a developer chooses a third-
party mapping provider when building an app, downloading that
app on Android would involve downloading both the app features
and the mapping functionality. Choosing to develop the app with
Google Maps, by contrast, would reduce the app’s file size on An-
droid, as Google Maps is already on the device.
Lastly, incumbents benefited from a lack of prohibitions on col-
lecting location data—an advantage that startups today lack given
the passage of new data restrictions that limit the development of
digital mapping technology. Notably, many of these rules came into
existence following public outrage prompted by Google Street View.
By the time these rules were implemented, Google had already
mapped out most of the planet.
Except for Apple’s independent mapping database, there has
been no recent entry in the market for underlying mapping data.
Similarly, the list of leading providers of consumer mapping serv-
ices and business-to-business services has mostly been unchanged
since 2013.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00096 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
91
584
See generally H
EIDI
M. P
ETERS
, C
ONG
. R
SCH
. S
ERV
., R45847, T
HE
D
EPARTMENT OF
D
E
-
FENSE
S
J
EDI
C
LOUD
P
ROGRAM
(2019).
585
See N
AT
L
I
NST
.
OF
S
TANDARDS &
T
ECH
., T
HE
NIST D
EFINITION OF
C
LOUD
C
OMPUTING
2
(2011), https://nvlpubs.nist.gov/nistpubs/Legacy/SP/nistspecialpublication800-145.pdf.
586
G
ARTNER
, M
ARKET
S
HARE
A
NALYSIS
: I
AAS AND
IUS, W
ORLDWIDE
(July 5, 2019); Submis-
sion from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZONlHJCl00219352 (on file with
Comm.).
587
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 240 (statement of Morgan Reed, President,
ACT | The App Ass’n).
G. Cloud Computing
Cloud computing refers to the service that enables remote stor-
age and software programs on demand through the internet. Prior
to cloud computing, data was stored locally on a computer’s hard
drive, in a local server room, or in a remote data center where com-
panies managed all of the information technology (I.T.) services.
584
Today, companies can essentially rent ‘‘network access to a shared
pool of configurable computing resources . . . [including] networks,
servers, storage, applications and services.’’
585
As a result of the
convenience and cost savings associated with the ability to scale up
or down on demand, cloud computing has grown into one of the
technology sector’s largest and most lucrative businesses.
586
It has
enabled the growth of enterprise businesses such as Netflix,
Airbnb, Lyft, Slack, and the Weather Channel, as well as new
startups that are not yet household names.
Cloud computing is a critical input to many of the digital mar-
kets the Subcommittee investigated, providing infrastructure for
online commerce, social media and networking, digital advertising,
voice assistants, and digital mapping—technologies that benefit
from dynamic storage and computational power. In a future with
smart homes, autonomous vehicles, and artificial intelligence appli-
cations in nearly every sector from agriculture to healthcare, un-
derstanding the dynamics of the cloud market becomes critical.
These ground-breaking technologies work because they can access
and analyze massive amounts of data in real time. Companies look-
ing to innovate in these spaces will struggle to rely solely on tradi-
tional I.T. and will likely turn to public cloud vendors. The testi-
mony of Morgan Reed on behalf of ACT, the App Association, illus-
trates how important ‘‘continuous cloud access [is] to create custom
software solutions that adapt quickly and rival the products and
services of larger SaaS companies.’’
587
Cloud computing service models vary by vendor, and new models
are being developed continually. The Subcommittee’s investigation
focused on the dynamics between the three models most referenced
and defined by the National Institute of Standards and Technology.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00097 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
92
588
Prepared by the Subcommittee based on data from the National Institute of Standards
and Technology.
589
N
AT
L
I
NST
.
OF
S
TANDARDS &
T
ECH
., T
HE
NIST D
EFINITION OF
C
LOUD
C
OMPUTING
2
(2011), https://nvlpubs.nist.gov/nistpubs/Legacy/SP/nistspecialpublication800-145.pdf.
590
Id.
591
Id. at 3.
592
H
EIDI
M. P
ETERS
, C
ONG
. R
SCH
. S
ERV
., R45847, T
HE
D
EPARTMENT OF
D
EFENSE
S
J
EDI
C
LOUD
P
ROGRAM
1 (2019).
593
N
AT
L
I
NST
.
OF
S
TANDARDS &
T
ECH
., T
HE
NIST D
EFINITION OF
C
LOUD
C
OMPUTING
3
(2011), https://nvlpubs.nist.gov/nistpubs/Legacy/SP/nistspecialpublication800-145.pdf.
594
Id.
Cloud Computing Services
588
In the Software as a Service (SaaS) model, the user accesses ap-
plications from various client devices ‘‘through either a thin client
interface, such as a web browser, or a program interface.’’
589
Com-
mon examples include Google Docs, Slack, and Mailchimp. In the
Platform as a Service (PaaS) model, the user, most often a cloud
application developer, builds new applications by accessing pro-
gramming languages, libraries, services, and tools supported by the
cloud provider.
590
Common PaaS tools include AWS Elastic Bean-
stalk, Google App Engine, and Salesforce’s Heroku. In the Infra-
structure as a Service (IaaS) model, the user, most often an engi-
neer, can deploy and run software, which can include operating
systems and applications while the cloud provider provisions funda-
mental computing resources including processing, storage, and net-
work applications.
591
Common IaaS tools include Amazon Elastic
Compute Cloud (EC2), Google Compute Engine, and Microsoft
Azure.
592
SaaS, PaaS, and IaaS can be deployed through several different
models.
593
The Subcommittee focused primarily on the market for
public cloud services in which the cloud provider provisions infra-
structure for open use by the general public. The infrastructure re-
sides on the premises of the cloud provider.
594
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00098 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 5 here 11701.005
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
93
595
Id.
596
See, e.g., Kelly Cochran, Simplify Your Customer Engagement with AWS and Salesforce
Heroku, AWS P
ARTNER
N
ETWORK (
APN
)
B
LOG
(June 9, 2017), https://aws.amazon.com/blogs/
apn/simplify-your-customer-engagement-with-aws-and-salesforce-heroku/.
597
Mark Innes, Salesforce Is Live on AWS Cloud Infrastructure in Australia, S
ALESFORCE
B
LOG
(Oct. 17, 2017), https://www.salesforce.com/au/blog/2017/10/salesforce-is-live-on-aws-
cloud-infrastructure-in-australia.html. For example, for many years Salesforce.com’s CRM ran
on self-managed infrastructure but when the company expanded to Australia in 2007, they en-
tered into a contract with AWS.
598
Letter from David Zapolsky, Gen. Couns., Amazon.com, Inc., to Hon. David N. Cicilline,
Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
6 (July 26, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
599
Press Release, Gartner, Gartner Says Global IT Spending to Reach $3.7 Trillion in 2018
(July 29, 2019), https://www.gartner.com/en/newsroom/press-releases/2019-07-29-gartner-says-
worldwide-iaas-public-cloud-services-market-grew-31point3-percent-in-2018.
To review market dynamics, the Subcommittee examined two
types of cloud service providers. The first type is infrastructure pro-
viders. Amazon Web Services (AWS), Microsoft Azure, and Google
Cloud Platform (GCP) are the most common domestic infrastruc-
ture providers. They offer customers IaaS, PaaS, and SaaS offer-
ings through their customer consoles or portals, but are distinct in
their ability to offer IaaS at scale. This Report refers to them as
infrastructure providers. They also operate online marketplaces for
third-party software vendors to list cloud offerings that integrate
with their infrastructure services.
The second type is third-party software vendors, sometimes re-
ferred to as Independent Software Vendors (ISVs). Companies such
as Salesforce, MariaDB, and The Apache Foundation provide oper-
ating systems, databases, security, and applications. Third-party
software can be delivered as a packaged software or managed serv-
ice. When a third party provides packaged software, it can be in-
stalled onto a customer’s existing cloud infrastructure. The pack-
aged software can be listed on the infrastructure provider’s market-
place or through a third-party vendor’s website.
When third-party software is sold as a managed service, the cus-
tomer pays a subscription based on the number of services used,
and the third-party software vendor manages all the underlying in-
frastructure.
595
In this scenario, the software has become a cloud
offering sold ‘‘as-a-service.’’ The underlying infrastructure can be
owned and managed by the third-party software vendor or the
third-party software vendor may have contracts with an infrastruc-
ture provider, and in some cases, the software vendor uses a com-
bination of owned and rented servers. For example, Salesforce’s
Heroku—a PaaS product—is built using AWS IaaS offerings.
596
When a company purchases a Heroku license, Salesforce’s use of
AWS is included in the price. In the case that a PaaS or SaaS offer-
ing uses its own infrastructure, it is likely it will need to be able
to integrate with products managed by the infrastructure providers
as it grows and, to expand to new regions, it will need to contract
with infrastructure providers.
597
In 2018, public cloud services, including IaaS, PaaS, SaaS, and
management services, accounted for $182.4 billion of the overall
$3.7 trillion I.T. infrastructure spending worldwide—less than one
percent.
598
Despite being a small fraction of I.T. spending, Gartner
projects the market size of the cloud services industry to increase
at nearly three times the rate of overall I.T. services through 2022,
to reach $331 billion.
599
AWS is the market leader, capturing ap-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00099 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
94
600
Letter from David Zapolsky, Gen. Couns., Amazon.com, Inc., to Hon. David N. Cicilline,
Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
6 (July 26, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
601
Submission from Source 170, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 6 (Nov. 21, 2011) (on file with
Comm.).
602
Press Release, Gartner, Gartner Forecasts Worldwide Public Cloud Revenue to Grow 17.5
Percent in 2019 (Apr. 2, 2019), https://www.gartner.com/en/newsroom/press-releases/2019-07-
29-gartner-says-worldwide-iaas-public-cloud-services-market-grew-31point3-percent-in-2018.
603
Id.
604
Prepared by the Subcommittee based on Press Release, Gartner, Gartner Forecasts World-
wide Public Cloud Revenue to Grow 17.5 Percent in 2019 (Apr. 2, 2019), https://www
.gartner.com/en/newsroom/press-releases/2019-07-29-gartner-says-worldwide-iaas-public-cloud-
services-market-grew-31point3-percent-in-2018.
605
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00219350 (July
5, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
proximately 24 percent of the U.S. spending on cloud computing in
2018.
600
Amazon—the leading cloud platform—is dominant in the cloud
market due to the concentration of the IaaS market.
601
According
to Gartner, ‘‘the worldwide IaaS market grew 31.3% in 2018 to
total $32.4 billion, up from $24.7 billion in 2017.’’
602
As seen in the
chart below, AWS is the unquestioned leader in the cloud com-
puting infrastructure market, with triple the market share of
Microsoft. Alibaba, Google, and Microsoft are growing at the fastest
rates—rates double that of Amazon. Gartner expects the IaaS
worldwide public cloud service revenue to grow faster than any
other set of services, and to be worth $76.6 billion in 2022.
603
IaaS Worldwide Public Cloud Services Revenue
(Millions of U.S. Dollars)
604
Industry reports suggest that the cloud computing market is con-
solidating around three providers domestically—AWS, Microsoft
Azure, and Google Cloud Platform.
605
Market leaders benefit from early-mover advantage coupled with
network effects and high switching costs that lock-in customers.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00100 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 6 here 11701.006
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
95
606
What’s New, A
MAZON
(Oct. 4, 2006), https://aws.amazon.com/about-aws/whats-new/
2006/.
607
Press Release, Microsoft, Microsoft Unveils Windows Azure at Professional Developers
Conference (Oct. 27, 2008), https://news.microsoft.com/2008/10/27/microsoft-unveils-windows-
azure-at-professional-developers-conference/#IP8XlBTCMpvORgaV.97.
608
Paul McDonald, Introducing Google App Engine + Our New Blog, G
OOGLE
D
EV
. B
LOG
(Apr.
7, 2008), http://googleappengine.blogspot.com/2008/04/introducing-google-app-engine-our-new
.html.
609
Ryan Lawler, Google Launches Computer Engine to Take on Amazon Web Services,
T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(June 28, 2012), https://techcrunch.com/2012/06/28/google-compute-engine/.
610
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–01777633 (on file
with Comm.).
611
Id.
612
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04167638 to –04167666 (June 3, 2019).
613
Roundtable Discussion of Mar. 17, 2020, Before the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial
and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 116th Cong. (2020) (statement of Mark
Tracy, CEO, Cloudacronomics) (on file with Comm.).
614
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJ–00183326 (Dec.
4, 2018) (on file with Comm.) (showing a 2018 RBC Capital Markets Report which analyzed the
cost of IaaS across five usage scenarios—Standard, High Compute, High Memory, High Storage,
and High Input/Output (I/O)—and three workload sizes—small, medium and large—to create 15
cases).
AWS pioneered cloud computing, launching officially in March
2006 with Simple Storage Service (S3) and Elastic Compute Cloud
(EC2), two fundamental IaaS offerings.
606
Microsoft announced
Azure in October 2008 along with core services that made up the
‘‘Azure Services Platform.’’
607
Google’s first public cloud service,
App Engine, a PaaS offering, was released in 2008.
608
Google’s
Compute Engine, an AWS Elastic Compute Cloud and Microsoft
Azure Virtual Machines competitor, went live as a preview in June
2012.
609
A 2010 Google strategy document predicted that the cloud com-
puting market would concentrate. An internal document, titled
‘‘Where Industry is Headed in 5 Years,’’ stated that there would be
some concentration in the market within five years, with
cloudservice providers consisting of Google, Amazon, Microsoft, and
a hybrid of Cisco and VMWare.
610
According to this document, each
company would offer cloud-based apps and other tools.
611
Later, in
a 2018 strategy document, Google emphasized the importance of
first-mover advantage in the space, writing ‘‘AWS and Azure have
had more years to gain customers, and cloud customers typically
grow [in] scale over time; in contrast’’ reiterating the tendency for
cloud customers to choose a single vendor as their primary cloud
service provider.
612
In a roundtable held by Subcommittee Chair
Cicilline, Mark Tracy, the CEO of Cloudacronomics, described these
concerns:
We pull down terabytes of data, and they have to upload it to the cloud to im-
prove farmers practices. The two cloud providers are AWS and Azure. Since so
many businesses and so much value can be extracted by improving health and
data, this concentration of cloud services is a concern.
613
As seen in the figure below, IaaS prices have decreased over
time, with the three dominant U.S. providers able to price their
services at less than $30/GB RAM according to a 2018 RBC Capital
Markets report.
614
Market participants reference economies of scale
and a focus on increasing revenue from PaaS and SaaS offerings,
as opposed to IaaS offerings, as an explanation for this trend. IaaS
vendors benefit from economies of scale both with regards to the
size of the data centers and the ability to operate multiple data
centers across the globe. To enter the market and reach the econo-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00101 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
96
615
Prepared by the Subcommittee based on the Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on
the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00183326 (Dec. 4, 2018) (on file with Comm.) (2018 RBC Capital
Markets Report which analyzed the cost of IaaS across five usage scenarios—Standard, High
Compute, High Memory, High Storage, and High Input/Output (I/O)—and three workload
sizes—small, medium and large—to create 15 cases).
616
Submission from Source 170, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 8 (Nov. 21, 2011) (on file with
Comm.).
617
Interview with Source 144 (April 17, 2020).
618
O
FF
.
OF
M
GMT
.
&
B
UDGET
, E
XEC
. O
FF
.
OF THE
P
RESIDENT
, S
ECURITY
A
UTHORIZATION OF
I
NFORMATION
S
YSTEMS IN
C
LOUD
C
OMPUTING
E
NVIRONMENTS
(2011), https://www.fedramp.gov/
assets/resources/documents/FedRAMPlPolicylMemo.pdf.
mies of scale needed to compete with the incumbents, infrastruc-
ture providers must invest significant capital and be able to offer
competitive prices to lure customers.
Average Monthly Costs Per GB RAM Across 15 Use Cases
615
The ‘‘cloud’’ is a system of cables connected to a wide network of
data centers—all underground, underwater, or in large industrial
buildings. Building data centers in dozens of regions worldwide
costs billions of dollars.
616
Market participants described the in-
vestment as ‘‘bigger than building a cellular network’’ and only ‘‘for
countries and major companies.’’
617
Two additional inputs that can provide a barrier to becoming a
leading infrastructure provider are compliance certifications and
reputation. Federal Risk and Authorization Management Program
(FedRAMP) authorization is required for any service that holds
U.S. federal data.
618
The FedRAMP authorization process can be
resource intensive and time consuming as vendors have to undergo
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00102 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 7 here 11701.007
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
97
619
Get Authorized: Joint Authorization Board, F
ED
RAMP, https://www.fedramp.gov/jab-
authorization/ (last visited Sept. 26, 2020).
620
Interview with Source 407 (Sept. 10, 2020).
621
Submission from Source 264, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 58 (Nov. 21, 2011) (on file
with Comm.).
622
AWS Marketplace, A
MAZON
, https://aws.amazon.com/marketplace (last visited Oct. 4
2020); Find Solutions to Support Innovation, M
ICROSOFT
A
ZURE
, https://azure.microsoft.com/en-
us/marketplace/ (last visited Oct. 4, 2020); G
OOGLE
C
LOUD
P
LATFORM
, https://console
.cloud.google.com/marketplace (last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
623
Submission from Source 170, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Nov. 21, 2011) (on file with
Comm.); Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–02456801 (2010)
(on file with Comm.).
624
AWS Marketplace, A
MAZON
, https://aws.amazon.com/marketplace (last visited Oct. 4,
2020).
625
Partners, A
MAZON
, https://aws.amazon.com/partners/ (last visited Sept. 26, 2020).
resource intensive and time consuming as vendors have to undergo
a process of technical and security reviews and audits.
619
When customers choose to use cloud computing, they must trust
that their data will be secure and available to access quickly. The
leading cloud infrastructure providers are major technology compa-
nies that handle massive amounts of data and run large technical
operations before offering managed services. Market participants
said in interviews with the Subcommittee that a smaller company
attempting to enter the IaaS market to contest these firms must
convince large customers that they can provide a reliable service
that is compliant with industry-specific regulations.
620
Market participants and industry reports highlight that IaaS of-
ferings have become commoditized. To compete, infrastructure pro-
viders must offer a range of PaaS and SaaS services to attract
users and developers to their platform.
621
First-party PaaS and
SaaS offerings are made available in the infrastructure provider’s
console. As of this Report, AWS, Azure, and GCP all list over 100
first-party cloud offerings.
622
Each cloud infrastructure provider
has taken its own approach to building its platform, but all involve
acquisitions, in-house software development, and the use of open-
source software. Google and Azure have also relied on their com-
pany’s existing products—Microsoft leveraging its Office 360 Suite
and Google leveraging its collection of APIs.
623
In the case that a new entrant can overcome this entry barrier,
it must also invest substantial resources to overcome network ef-
fects within the market. Infrastructure providers benefit from net-
work effects—the more customers on a platform, the more third
parties build services that integrate well with that platform leading
to more services to attract customers. Amazon, Microsoft, and
Google all have hundreds of products listed in their third-party
marketplace, while Amazon lists 9,250.
624
In interviews with the
Subcommittee, third-party software vendors said that they had lit-
tle choice but to integrate their products with the incumbents, most
notably, AWS.
Cloud infrastructure providers also need to ensure that the
knowledge and expertise of their platform’s technology are avail-
able to their customers. To achieve this, cloud infrastructure pro-
viders launch partner networks that include consulting firms
trained to help enterprise customers move to the public cloud, such
as AWS Partner Network (APN) Consulting Partners
625
and
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00103 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
98
626
Solution Providers, M
ICROSOFT
, https://www.microsoft.com/en-us/solution-providers/
home (last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
627
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04215099 (Dec. 31,
2018) (on file with Comm.).
628
See, e.g., AWS Free Tier, A
MAZON
, https://aws.amazon.com/free/ (last visited Oct. 4,
2020).
629
All Network Pricing, G
OOGLE
C
LOUD
, https://cloud.google.com/vpc/network-pricing (last
visited Oct. 4, 2020).
630
Interview with Source 465 (May 27, 2020).
631
Submission from Source 264, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 6 (Nov. 21, 2011) (on file with
Comm.).
Microsoft Solution Providers.
626
Cloud infrastructure providers
also offer trainings and exams to certify members of the workforce
as proficient in various uses of their technology. Additionally, infra-
structure providers have programs to support third-party software
vendors working to integrate with the infrastructure provider’s
cloud.
Many market participants interviewed by the Subcommittee be-
lieve that surpassing the incumbents in the market will be chal-
lenging because of the potential for vendor lock-in. Other evidence
reviewed by the Subcommittee bolsters this concern, suggesting
that lock-in exists because switching costs for cloud computing cus-
tomers are high.
627
The Subcommittee has identified several common techniques in-
frastructure providers use to initially lock-in customers, including
contract terms, free tier offerings, and egress fees. The first is long-
term contracts. In several responses to the Committee’s requests
for information, third parties explained they have contracts lasting
from three to five years with the infrastructure providers.
Another common technique is using free tier products, where
each cloud platform offers a free tier of services ranging from al-
ways free to trial offers.
628
Market participants suggest that while
the free tier products vary slightly among the major firms, they are
relatively similar. When a customer’s free trial expires, it is faced
with switching to another provider or starting to pay for service.
Switching requires an investment of time and resources to adapt
to the new service provider, as well as possibly paying egress fees
to the prior vendor. As a result, customers may decline to switch
at the conclusion of free trials.
Whether a customer begins using cloud on free tier products or
not, once they have substantially built and migrated to a platform,
they face high switching costs in the form of fees to move the data,
along with the technical and labor costs associated with switching
the data. When a company moves data into the cloud from hard
drives or private servers, they are often charged ingress fees, which
are generally low or free.
629
When a company, however, chooses to
move data to another infrastructure provider, they are charged an
egress fee. Egress fees vary slightly by company and region.
Market participants explain that egress fees are often not trans-
parent and are sometimes charged even when data is not leaving
the data center.
630
One market participant said that these fees
‘‘can create significant financial barriers to migrating away from
particular cloud storage providers.’’
631
Additionally, when a customer decides to move any of its oper-
ations to a different infrastructure provider, it often must overcome
technical design challenges. Several market participants spoke to
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00104 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
99
632
Id. at 5.
633
Snap Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 11 (Dec. 31, 2019), http://d18rn0p25nwr6d
.cloudfront.net/CIK-0001564408/0cfebc98-816e-44ac-8351-5067b4f88f0c.pdf.
634
Getting Started, A
MAZON
W
EB
S
ERVS
., https://docs.aws.amazon.com/awsaccount
billing/latest/aboutv2/billing-getting-started.html (last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
635
Submission from Source 170, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 7 (Oct. 18, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
the challenges of finding cloud developers that know the underlying
technology of multiple cloud infrastructures as a barrier to both
switching, either from one cloud to another or to set up multi-cloud
operations. As one third party describes, ‘‘businesses often have to
calibrate a complex set of technical frameworks, settings, and cus-
tomized interfaces to adapt their business to the potentially unique
way the cloud storage provider has chosen to operate their serv-
ice.’’
632
For example, in an investor statement in 2020, Snap ex-
plained:
[T]he vast majority of our computing [runs] on Google Cloud and AWS, and our
systems are not fully redundant on the two platforms. Any transition of the
cloud services currently provided by either Google Cloud or AWS to the other
platform or to another cloud provider would be difficult to implement and will
cause us to incur significant time and expense.
633
When asked about lock-in, many market participants discussed
how in response to the rise of a few dominant platforms in the
cloud market, new strategies have emerged to increase portability
between vendors and allow customers to use multiple clouds. Mar-
ket participants note, however, that today interoperability is a
challenge, and it is unclear how cooperative dominant cloud infra-
structure providers will be in supporting partnerships and stand-
ards to facilitate these strategies. Given the current trends toward
concentration in the cloud infrastructure market, further scrutiny
of the role standards play toward decreasing switching costs and
enabling portability and interoperability is warranted.
Finally, the Subcommittee interviewed market participants about
related competition concerns facing third-party software vendors.
Many third-party software vendors compete with first-party prod-
ucts listed in the infrastructure provider’s console. Market partici-
pants explain that these competitive offerings are often the first
products customers see because they are displayed within the cus-
tomer’s existing console in a format that makes it easier for users
to add to their existing cloud stack, seamlessly including the prod-
uct in their billing and licenses and with minimal technical set-
up.
634
As a result, it is difficult for customers to compare prices and fea-
tures included in the offerings when they are not listed side-by-
side. Although third-party vendors can sell their service directly to
consumers through their own websites, many smaller cloud vendors
use the marketplaces of the dominant infrastructure providers to
reach customers, which require fees and are subject to competition
concerns that are similar to other marketplaces examined by the
Subcommittee during the investigation. Market participants have
raised concerns that cloud infrastructure providers can preference
their own offerings, or offer these products with exceedingly steep
discounts, making it difficult for third-party software vendors with
fewer products to compete.
635
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00105 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
100
636
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 488 (response to Questions for the Record
of Adam Cohen, Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC), id. at 540–41 (response to Questions for the
Record of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
637
See Alistair Barr, Amazon Finds Startup Investments in the ‘‘Cloud,’’ R
EUTERS
(Nov. 9,
2011), http://www.reuters.com/article/amazon-cloud-idUSN1E7A727Q20111109.
638
Submission from Source 301, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 301–00000080, at 2
(Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
639
Submission from Source 918, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Nov. 4, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
640
Id. at Source 918–0002029.
641
Submission from Source 711, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 711–00000080, at 13
(Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
642
Id.
643
Thomas Ricker, Sonos Buys Snips, a Privacy-Focused Voice Assistant, V
ERGE
(Nov. 21,
2019), https://www.theverge.com/2019/11/21/20975607/sonos-buys-snips-ai-voice-assistant-
privacy.
644
Hyunji Chung, Jungheum Park & Sangjin Lee, Digital Forensic Approaches for Amazon
Alexa Ecosystem, 22 D
IGIT
. I
NVESTIGATIONS
S15 (2017), https://dfrws.org/wp-content/uploads/
2019/06/paperldigitallforensiclapproacheslforlamazonlalexalecosystem.pdf.
Significantly, because the leading infrastructure providers have
access to competitively significant data in the marketplace, they
have insight into usage metrics regarding any managed service
that runs on their infrastructure.
636
Market participants told the
Subcommittee that they have concerns that this data can be used
by infrastructure providers to make decisions regarding which
types of software to acquire or replicate to offer through their first-
party console.
637
H. Voice Assistant
Voice assistants act as a user interface that enables exchanges
between computing devices through a person’s voice.
638
Today
users can ask their electronic devices to play the morning news or
start a conference call.
639
When combined with smart speakers,
voice assistants can become a gateway to the internet, and can also
be used to connect other ‘‘smart’’ devices, such as lighting, thermo-
stats, security monitors, and even kitchen appliances.
640
While
voice assistants began as mobile phone apps, they have become in-
tegrated into other devices, including cars and homes.
641
There are two types of voice assistants on the market: general
and specialized. General voice assistants—such as Siri, Alexa, and
Google Assistant—can respond to queries and interact with a range
of applications. Specialized voice assistants focus on a specific
vertical—such as healthcare or banking—where there is a limited
vocabulary universe and more specific responses.
642
For example,
Snips, a privacy-centric voice assistant owned by Sonos, specializes
in commands for playing music on smart speakers.
643
Today, voice assistants interact with humans by receiving spe-
cific requests and sending feedback through a voice response. The
first step is to deliver the ‘‘wake word’’—such as ‘‘hey, Siri’’ on
iPhones—designed to activate the system. Once activated, a voice
assistant can execute a command, which triggers a voice applica-
tion.
644
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00106 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
101
645
Prepared by the Subcommittee based on Hyunji Chung, Jungheum Park & Sangjin Lee,
Digital Forensic Approaches for Amazon Alexa Ecosystem, 22 D
IGIT
. I
NVESTIGATIONS
S15 (2017),
https://dfrws.org/wp-content/uploads/2019/06/paperldigitallforensiclapproacheslforl
amazonlalexalecosystem.pdf.
646
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04257931 (Mar. 9,
2017) (on file with Comm.).
647
Id.
648
Id.
649
Alison DeNisco Rayome, How to Monetize Your IoT Project, T
ECH
R
EPUBLIC
(June 20, 2018),
https://www.techrepublic.com/article/6-steps-to-monetizing-your-iot-project/.
650
Submission from Source 918, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 918–0002763 (Nov.
4, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
Voice Assistant Ecosystem
645
Although there are multiple types of voice assistants within the
ecosystem, the Subcommittee focused primarily on voice assistant
platform vendors and third-party hardware manufacturers, includ-
ing smart speaker manufacturers and internet of Things (IoT) com-
patible device manufacturers. The business model for these two
groups varies. A voice assistant platform vendor can monetize its
platform by using its ecosystem to drive revenue to complementary
lines of business such as e-commerce, search, or entertain-
ment.
646
It can also charge voice-application developers to be the
recommended application for a specific command.
647
As they be-
come widely adopted, stores on voice assistant platforms—such as
the ‘‘Alexa Skills Store’’—can offer premium content and collect
revenue share on payments.
648
Third-party hardware manufactur-
ers generate income by selling hardware, and in some cases, by of-
fering subscription services such as home monitoring.
649
Voice assistants have grown in popularity over recent years due
to technological advancements in natural language processing. Al-
though the market is nascent, market participants and industry ex-
perts view voice-enabled devices as an opportunity to lock con-
sumers into information ecosystems. The smartphone and smart
speaker are the two main portals for voice assistants. Apple and
Google lead in the smartphone market, and Amazon leads in the
smart speaker market.
650
According to one consulting firm, of the
1.1 billion shipments of virtual assistants in 2019, Apple’s Siri (35
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00107 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 8 here 11701.008
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
102
651
Press Release, Futuresource Consulting, Virtual Assistants to Exceed 2.5 Billion Ship-
ments in 2023 (Dec. 18, 2019), https://www.futuresource-consulting.com/press-release/
consumer-electronics-press/virtual-assistants-to-exceed-25-billion-shipments-in-2023/.
652
Id.; Mary Jo Foley, Microsoft CEO Nadella Makes It Official: Cortana Is an App, not a
Standalone Assistant, ZDN
ET
(Jan. 18, 2019), https://www.zdnet.com/article/microsoft-ceo-
nadella-makes-it-official-cortana-is-an-app-not-a-standalone-assistant/.
653
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04258666 (Jan. 28,
2019) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Speakers are still going to be very important. [Company] cited stats
that suggested that only 20 percent of their ‘smart home’ customers are new to the category.
And it’s fair to say that many/most of these existing smart home customers started with
sound.’’).
654
See generally Submission from Source 918, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Nov. 4, 2019)
(on file with Comm.).
655
Id. at 7.
656
Submission from Source 918, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 918–0002024 (Nov.
4, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
657
See, e.g., Christopher Mims, All Ears: Always-On Listening Devices Could Soon Be Every-
where, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (July 12, 2018), https://www.wsj.com/articles/all-ears-always-on-listening-
devices-could-soon-be-everywhere-1531411250.
658
Submission from Source 918, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 918–0002025, at 12
(Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
percent) has the highest market share globally, followed by Google
Assistant (9 percent) and Amazon Alexa (4 percent).
651
Although a
significant share of shipments is attributed to Microsoft Cortana
(22 percent) because of the popularity of Windows PCs globally,
Cortana is generally not considered a voice assistant platform.
652
Market participants emphasize that smart speakers represent an
essential ‘‘hub’’ or gateway for smart homes and are driving voice-
assistant adoption.
653
Smart speakers are estimated to currently
have 35 percent U.S. household penetration, which is predicted to
grow to 75 percent by 2025.
654
As of January 2019, Amazon had
a significant lead in the U.S. market at 61.1 percent, followed by
Google at 23.8 percent, Apple at 2.7 percent, and Sonos at 2.2 per-
cent.
655
A voice assistant platform vendor can expand its ecosystem by
adding IoT devices and voice applications. Both IoT devices and
voice applications can be first-party—owned by the voice assistant
platform vendor—or third-party, if the vendor has set up services
to allow for manufacturers to create voice assistant-enabled de-
vices. Amazon’s Alexa ecosystem, measured in terms of compatible
IoT devices and voice applications, is the largest of the three pri-
mary ecosystems. In 2017, voice assistants made their first serious
moves beyond smart speakers into other product categories.
656
The
voice assistant-compatible device market is vast and includes kitch-
en appliances, security cameras, and even trash cans.
657
Market participants suggest there are several barriers to entry
to compete with general voice assistant platforms. These include
overcoming the network effects early entrants have benefited from,
including financial investment in hardware, software, and infra-
structure, and the ability to sell voice assistant-enabled devices at
a discount.
Like many platform-based businesses, the voice assistant market
benefits from network effects. The more users on a platform, the
more third-party devices and applications become available, which
attracts more users to the platform.
658
These network effects for
voice assistant platforms are amplified by machine learning and ar-
tificial intelligence (AI). Improvements in Natural Language Proc-
essing (NLP) and AI are expected to improve the quality of voice
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00108 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
103
659
Submission from Source 711, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 711–00000080, at 12
(Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
660
Data and Privacy Hearing at 146–47 (statement of Maurice E. Stucke, Prof. of Law, Univ.
of Tenn., & Ariel Ezrachi, Slaughter & May Prof. of Competition Law, Univ. of Oxford, Fellow,
Pembroke Coll., Dir., Oxford Ctr. for Competition Law & Pol’y).
661
Submission from Source 918, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 918–0002763, at 12
(Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
662
Submission from Source 918, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 37 (Sept. 1, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
663
See, e.g., How Big Tech Is Battling to Own the $49B Voice Market, CB I
NSIGHTS
(Feb. 13,
2019), https://www.cbinsights.com/research/facebook-amazon-microsoft-google-apple-voice/.
664
F
UTURE
T
ODAY
I
NST
., 2020 T
ECH
T
RENDS
R
EPORT
(2020), https://futuretoday
institute.com/2020-tech-trends/.
assistants and contribute to wider adoption.
659
Voice assistant
technology improves at a faster rate when there are more users
providing the voice samples needed to train AI. In testimony to the
Subcommittee, Professors Maurice Stucke and Ariel Ezrachi de-
scribe this as ‘‘Learning-by-Doing.’’ As they note:
Learning-by-doing network effect is not limited to online searches, but will be
present in any environment in which algorithms evolve and adapt based on expe-
rience, such [as], for example, the development of voice recognition or other in-
stances based on machine learning.
660
The scale of users generating data is arguably the most important
asset in terms of AI.
661
The incumbents have access to large data
sets that—when combined with machine learning and AI—position
them to benefit from economies of scope in the smart home.
662
Competing as a voice assistant platform also requires significant
financial resources. A firm must make significant investments to
design and train a voice assistant, as well as to acquire the phys-
ical infrastructure: hardware and cloud computing. Additionally,
incumbents have also acquired various firms that specialize in
voice recognition and natural language processing, a functionality
that is used in their voice assistants. For example, both Apple and
Amazon acquired companies to develop their core voice recognition
technologies, and every incumbent has continually invested in AI
startups to improve their voice assistant ecosystem.
663
Currently, voice assistant software is built on cloud computing
infrastructure. In the case of Amazon Alexa and Google Assistant,
the voice assistant platforms also own the underlying cloud infra-
structure, AWS and GCP, respectively. Market participants note
that advancements in voice assistant ecosystems are beginning to
rely on edge computing technology, which brings the computation
and data storage closer to the device and is a technology in which
the incumbent cloud market leaders have a head start.
664
Market participants have also raised concerns about incumbent
firms offering voice-enabled hardware—specifically hubs such as
smart speakers—to both collect large amounts of personal user
data and strengthen other lines of business. At the Subcommittee’s
field hearing, Sonos CEO Patrick Spence explained:
Google and Amazon have flooded the market with dramatically price-subsidized
products. Indeed, they make no pretense of the fact that the products themselves
are money losers and they routinely give them away at steep discounts, even for
free. It is difficult to predict the impact that voice assistants will have on search
and e-commerce, but voice activated speakers have the potential to dramatically
alter the way that consumers interact with the internet. We believe that Google
and Amazon have been willing to forgo profits in smart speakers for this reason,
in addition to their ability to monetize the valuable household data that these
products vacuum up. And if voice purchasing and voice search do become the
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00109 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
104
665
Competitors Hearing at 11 (statement of Patrick Spence, CEO, Sonos, Inc.).
666
Submission from Source 711, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 711–00000080, at 20
(Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
667
Id. at 17.
668
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 481–82 (response to Questions for the
Record of Adam Cohen, Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC).
669
See generally S
HOSHANA
Z
UBOFF
, T
HE
A
GE OF
S
URVEILLANCE
C
APITALISM
(2019).
670
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 536 (response to Questions for the Record
of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
next big thing, they will own the market because their strategy is succeeding.
Those two companies now control roughly 85% of the U.S. smart speaker market
.... It’s not because their hardware businesses are profitable in and of them-
selves.
665
As the voice assistant market expands, it may be difficult for
users to switch between platforms. Because voice assistant plat-
forms are not always interoperable, users would incur costs to pur-
chase one or more new devices. Moreover, voice assistant tech-
nology is designed to learn its user’s preferences over time. These
preferences range from settings like billing information and default
services for responding to music commands to more advanced
learning like past voice commands and shopping history. As a voice
assistant improves its ‘‘understanding’’ of its user, it may increase
the costs associated with switching to another platform. As one
market participant noted in a submission to the Subcommittee,
‘‘the user may become more dependent on that particular voice as-
sistant and be far less likely to use a rival voice assistant that has
not yet ‘caught up’ with the user’s preferences.’’
666
The design of most voice assistants—specifically on screenless de-
vices—amplifies the ability of voice assistant platforms to favor
their services as a default or as a response with limited choice.
667
This dynamic makes it easier for popular voice assistants to favor
their first-party services.
There is also a significant potential for misuse of data to harm
competition or consumers. Similar to other platforms, such as cloud
and operating systems, voice assistant platforms collect and store
users’ interactions with the voice assistant.
668
During the inves-
tigation, several companies shared concerns that voice assistant
platforms would be able to use this vantage to glean competitive
insights from third-party voice applications or smart appliances
that are performing well. As a result, platforms could use that data
to acquire competitive threats or integrate their features into the
company’s product.
Privacy and data experts have also commented that the smart
home ecosystem has access to some of the most sensitive data that
can be collected.
669
Voice assistant platforms not only record voice
interactions, but also receive information about the skills used—
‘‘whether a light is on or off. Or, if a customer links Alexa to a
third-party calendar skill, Alexa may receive information about the
events on the customer’s calendar.’’
670
This raises significant con-
cerns regarding whether a person has provided consent to data col-
lection. Voice assistants not only collect information on the primary
user, but also people in their environment, including children.
Finally, leaders in the voice assistant ecosystem set the rules for
third parties. To make a voice assistant enabled device, market
participants must comply with voice assistant platform vendor
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00110 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
105
671
Competitors Hearing at 12 (statement of Patrick Spence, CEO, Sonos, Inc.).
672
Submission from Source 301, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 301–00000080, at 23
(Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
673
Submission from Source 385, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Oct. 11, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
674
Id. at 4.
675
Standards, W3C, https://www.w3.org/standards/ (last visited Sept. 26, 2020).
676
Submission from Source 993, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Oct. 11, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
677
Process for 2020, W3C, https://www.w3.org/wiki/Process2020 (last visited Sept. 26,
2020).
specifications. As Mr. Spence of Sonos noted in his testimony before
the Subcommittee:
To gain access to their platforms and integrate with their services, these compa-
nies issue all manner of take-it-or-leave-it demands, from early and technically
detailed access to our product roadmaps, to proprietary business data, including
sales forecasts, to waivers of essential contractual rights.
671
The Subcommittee also heard from multiple voice assistant de-
velopers that have struggled to gain access to key functionality
needed to build their applications, such as the unprocessed user
commands.
672
While still developing, the voice assistant market
shows early signs of market concentration.
I. Web Browsers
A web browser is software that retrieves and displays pages from
the internet. People often use browsers to navigate to and spend
time on websites and to search the web. Most other activities on-
line, whether it is on a mobile phone or a television screen, are
made possible through a browser.
673
Behind every browser is a ‘‘browser engine,’’ also known as a lay-
out engine or rendering engine. A browser engine is the central
software component of a web browser, transforming content hosted
on web servers into a graphic depiction that people can interact
with. Browsers interpret control codes within web pages, which in-
dicate the structure of the data, such as the beginning and end of
an item, and the way to present it to the user, such as headings,
paragraphs, lists, or embedded images. The browser engine takes
this code to ‘‘draw the web page’’ on the user’s screen and notes
which parts of it are interactive. The non-engine components of the
browser typically include the menus, toolbars, and other user-fac-
ing features, which are layered on top of the engine.
674
Browsers abide by standards to ensure that anyone can properly
use features within a website on any browser. For example, stand-
ards such as CSS and XML help ensure that a website functions
the same in every browser.
675
Web browser standards organiza-
tions include the World Wide Web Consortium (W3C), Web Hyper-
text Application Technology Working Group (WHATWG), and
Internet Engineering Task Force (IETF). Through these organiza-
tions, stakeholders work in partnership to ensure that browser en-
gines and web pages are interoperable.
676
W3C has become one of
the most important organizations for browser standards. W3C
standards undergo a rigorous review process prior to implementa-
tion.
677
Browser vendors monetize their access to users, usually through
search royalties. For example, whenever someone types a search
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00111 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
106
678
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 437 (response to Questions for the Record
of Adam Cohen, Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC).
679
Expand Your Business with Brave Ads, B
RAVE
, https://brave.com/brave-ads-waitlist/
(last visited Sept. 26, 2020).
680
U.S. Browser Market Share, S
TAT
C
OUNTER
, https://gs.statcounter.com/browser-market-
share/all/united-states-of-america (last visited Sept. 26, 2020).
681
U.S. Desktop Market Share, S
TAT
C
OUNTER
, https://gs.statcounter.com/browser-market-
share/desktop/united-states-of-america (last visited Sept. 26, 2020).
682
U.S. Mobile Market Share, S
TAT
C
OUNTER
, https://gs.statcounter.com/browser-market-
share/mobile/united-states-of-america (last visited Sept. 26, 2020).
683
Submission from Source 993, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Oct. 11, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
684
T
HE
C
HROMIUM
P
ROJECTS
, https://www.chromium.org/ (last visited Sept. 26, 2020).
685
Submission from Source 993, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Oct. 11, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
686
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 584–85 (response to Questions for the
Record of Kyle Andeer, Vice President, Corp. Law, Apple, Inc.).
687
Interview with Source 27 (June 29, 2020).
688
Tyler Lacoma, The Best Google Chrome Extensions, D
IG
. T
RENDS
(Apr. 4, 2020), https://
www.digitaltrends.com/computing/best-google-chrome-extensions/.
689
Submission from Source 993, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Oct. 11, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
query into the search bar on Firefox, Google records that action,
and the Mozilla corporation receives a royalty.
678
Browsers also
bring in ad revenues. For example, Brave sells advertisers the op-
tion to run desktop notification ads to users who choose to see
ads.
679
The browser market is highly concentrated. Google’s Chrome and
Apple’s Safari control roughly 80 percent of the browser market.
680
As of August 2020, Chrome is the leader in the U.S. desktop brows-
er market (58.6 percent), followed by Safari (15.8 percent), Edge
(8.76 percent), Firefox (7.6 percent), and Internet Explorer (5.36
percent).
681
On mobile devices, Safari (55.5 percent) and Chrome
(37.4 percent) have significant leads on their rivals, such as
Samsung Internet (5.01 percent), Firefox (0.77 percent), and Opera
(0.44 percent).
682
Additionally, the browser market has con-
centrated around three browser engines: Gecko, WebKit, and Blink,
used in Firefox, Apple’s Safari, and Google’s Chrome, respec-
tively.
683
Google’s hold on the browser market extends beyond Chrome.
Google releases the code base used to make the Chrome browser
as the free, open-source project Chromium.
684
Chromium is used in
Microsoft’s Edge browser, Amazon’s Silk browser, Opera, and other
browsers that are often referred to as ‘‘Chromium-based.’’
685
Simi-
larly, Apple extends its power by mandating that all browser appli-
cations on the iPhone use Apple’s browser engine, WebKit.
686
Browser competition has also led to the creation of a browser ex-
tension submarket. A browser extension adds additional features to
a web browser, including user interface modifications and ad-block-
ing. They can also provide for niche browser customization and ex-
perimentation of new functionality before it is implemented into
the main browser functionality.
687
Popular add-ons include ad
blockers, LastPass, and Grammarly.
688
Competition in this market is important to promoting innovation
online. In a submission to the Subcommittee, a market participant
explained:
Competing browser engines push each other for innovations in raw performance
in several respects, including faster rendering, greater reliability, and a number
of other technical improvements; this competition is qualitatively different from,
and greater than, competition over just the browser product.
689
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00112 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
107
690
Id.
691
Rust Language, M
OZILLA
R
SCH
., https://research.mozilla.org/rust/ (last visited Sept. 26,
2020).
692
Id.
693
Interview with Source 481 (July 2, 2020).
694
Submission from Source 993, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 10–11 (Oct. 11, 2019) (on file
with Comm.); Submission from Source 269, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2–3 (July 23, 2019)
(on file with Comm.).
695
Submission from Source 993, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 10 (Oct. 11, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
696
Id. at 5; Submission from Source 269, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (July 23, 2019)
(on file with Comm.).
697
Submission from Source 465, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 6 (June 3, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
698
Id.
Browser diversity is also important for ensuring an open internet
and reduces the risk that web developers will build sites optimized
for the leading engine as opposed to web standards.
690
Moreover,
as developers work on advancing browser engine technology, they
create technologies that can improve the overall internet eco-
system. For example, Rust is a programming language that Mozilla
engineers developed while writing the Servo layout technology for
browser engines.
691
Developers use Rust for other applications
today, including gaming, operating systems, and other new soft-
ware applications.
692
There is a general concern that, without vi-
brant competition, this form of innovation will suffer, discouraging
the development of new browser engine technology.
693
Browsers protect their dominance through default settings,
which create a barrier to entry.
694
Defaults exist in both desktop
and mobile markets. Although users can set different browsers
more easily for desktop computers than on mobile devices, ‘‘settings
can impact the stickiness over time,’’ such as when a software up-
date overrides a user’s preference, requiring them to take ‘‘complex
steps to restore their browser choice.’’
695
In some cases, consumers
are unable to delete the preloaded browser. For example, on Apple
iOS devices and Facebook’s Oculus, users are unable to delete the
preloaded browser. Some popular mobile applications can preset
webpage links to a predetermined browser, such as the Apple Mail
App (Safari) and the Search widget on an Android device
(Chrome).
696
J. Digital Advertising
There are two principal forms of digital advertising: search ad-
vertising and display advertising. Search advertising refers to dig-
ital ads on desktop or mobile search engines, such as the
Google.com homepage, displayed via ‘‘search ad tech’’ alongside
search engine results. Search advertising is often bought and sold
via real-time bidding (RTB) auctions among advertisers, where ad-
vertisers set the prices they are willing to pay for a specific key-
word in a query.
697
Display advertising refers to the delivery of dig-
ital ad content to ad space on websites and mobile apps, which is
referred to as ‘‘inventory.’’ Like search advertising, buying and sell-
ing display ads often involves real-time bidding.
698
Within display advertising, there are two separate ‘‘ad tech’’ mar-
kets that the Subcommittee reviewed during the investigation:
first-party and third-party. ‘‘First-party’’ platforms refer to compa-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00113 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
108
699
Id. at 5.
700
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 266.
701
Dina Srinivasan, Why Google Dominates Advertising Markets, 24 S
TAN
. T
ECH
. L. R
EV
. 55,
63–64 (2020).
702
Id. at 64.
703
Interview with Source 004 (Apr. 23, 2020).
704
Prepared by the Subcommittee based on Dina Srinivasan, Why Google Dominates Adver-
tising Markets, 24 S
TAN
. T
ECH
. L. R
EV
. 55, 77 (2020).
705
Submission from Source 465, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 9 (June 3, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
706
Id.
nies such as Facebook, Twitter, and Snap, which sell ad space on
their own platforms directly to advertisers. Google also uses first-
party ad tech to sell display ads on its own properties, most notably
YouTube. Third-party display ad tech platforms are run by inter-
mediary vendors and facilitate the transaction between third-party
advertisers, such as the local dry cleaner or a Fortune 500 com-
pany, and third-party publishers, such as The Washington Post or
a blog.
699
Third-party ad tech providers include Google, Flash-
talking, Sizmek (owned by Amazon), and the Trade Desk, among
others.
700
Software in display ads is programmatic, meaning that special-
ized software automates the buying and selling of digital ads. Mar-
ket participants explain that this automated approach provides
greater liquidity, better return-on-investment metrics, more precise
ad targeting, and lower transaction costs. One major drawback,
however, is that this process lacks transparency.
701
Google, specifi-
cally, ‘‘does not disclose to the publishers on the other ends of these
trades what their space ultimately sold for and how much Google
keeps as its share.’’
702
As another market participant told the Sub-
committee, Google could make the process ‘‘more transparent,’’ but
given Google’s financial stake in maintaining secrecy, ‘‘there is no
incentive to.’’
703
The Ad-Tech Suite
704
Ad exchanges refer to the ‘‘ad trafficking system that connects
advertisers looking to buy inventory with publishers selling inven-
tory.’’
705
Sales on ad exchanges occur primarily through: (1) open
real-time bidding auctions; (2) closed real-time bidding auctions; or
(3) programmatic direct deals.
706
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00114 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 9 here 11701.009
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
109
707
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 263.
708
Submission from Source 465, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 8 (June 3, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
709
Id. at 9.
710
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 263.
711
Submission from Source 888, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 8 (June 3, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
712
Id. at 10.
713
Alex Heath, Facebook and Google Completely Dominate the Digital Ad Industry, B
US
. I
N
-
SIDER
(Apr. 26, 2017), https://www.businessinsider.com/facebook-and-google-dominate-ad-
industry-with-a-combined-99-of-growth-2017-4.
714
Dina Srinivasan, Why Google Dominates Advertising Markets, 24 S
TAN
. T
ECH
. L. R
EV
. 55,
59 (2020).
Sell-side software includes publisher ad servers.
707
The primary
function of a publisher ad server is to fill ad space on a publisher’s
website that is personalized to the interests of a specific website
viewer.
708
Sell-side software also includes ad networks, which ag-
gregate ad inventory from many different publishers and divide
that inventory based on user characteristics—such as age or loca-
tion. Ad networks sell the pool of inventory through ad exchanges
or demand-side platforms (DSPs).
709
Buy-side software includes advertiser ad servers—software that
stores, maintains, and delivers digital ads to the available inven-
tory. Ad servers facilitate the programmatic process that makes in-
stantaneous decisions about which ads to display on which
websites to which users and helps display the ad on that site. Ad
servers collect and report data, such as ad impressions and clicks,
for advertisers to monitor ad performance and track conversion
metrics.
710
Buy-side software also includes demand-side plat-
forms—software that allows advertisers to buy advertising inven-
tory from a range of publishers. Demand-side platforms use data
to create targeted ad audiences and engage in purchasing and bid-
ding.
711
The ad tech suite also includes analytics tools that allow adver-
tisers and publishers to measure ad campaign efficiency, including
consumers’ interactions with an ad. Similarly, data management
platforms (DMPs) aggregate and store consumer data from various
sources and process the data for analysis. Advertisers and pub-
lishers use data management platforms to track, partition, and tar-
get consumer audiences across websites.
712
Over the last decade, the digital advertising market has experi-
enced double-digit year-over-year growth. The market, however,
has become increasingly concentrated since the advent of pro-
grammatic trading. In 2017, Business Insider reported that Google
and Facebook accounted for 99 percent of year-over-year growth in
U.S. digital advertising revenue.
713
Today, advertisers and pub-
lishers alike have few options when deciding how to buy and sell
online ad space.
714
Market participants suggest this concentration likely exists in
part due to high barriers to entry. Google and Facebook both have
a significant lead in the market due to their significant collection
of behavioral data online, which can be used in targeted adver-
tising. Additionally, Google and Facebook do not provide access to
this unique data in open data exchanges. Advertisers’ only access
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00115 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
110
715
Id. at 93.
716
Kiri Masters, What’s Driving Amazon’s $10 Billion Advertising Business, F
ORBES
(July 26,
2019), https://www.forbes.com/sites/kirimasters/2019/07/26/whats-driving-amazons-10bn-
advertising-business/#4cc9c84aa043.
717
Id.
718
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 282.
719
S
TEVEN
L
EVY
, F
ACEBOOK
: T
HE
I
NSIDE
S
TORY
65–69 (2020).
720
Facebook, Inc., Quarterly Report (Form 10–Q) 29 (July 31, 2020), https://investor
.fb.com/financials/sec-filings-details/default.aspx?FilingId=14302237.
721
Id. at 30.
722
Id. at 32.
723
Id. at 35. See generally Howard A. Shelanski & J. Gregory Sidak, Antitrust Divestiture
in Network Industries, 68 U. C
HI
. L. R
EV
. 1, 6 (2001) (‘‘High profit margins might appear to
be the benign and necessary recovery of legitimate investment returns in a Schumpeterian
framework, but they might represent exploitation of customer lock-in and monopoly power when
viewed through the lens of network economics.’’).
724
Facebook, Inc., Quarterly Report (Form 10–Q) 25 (July 31, 2020), https://investor
.fb.com/financials/sec-filings-details/default.aspx?FilingId=14302237.
725
Id. at 35.
to this information is indirect—through engagement with Google
and Facebook’s ad tech.
715
Amazon’s advertising business is starting to obtain a portion of
the U.S. year-over-year digital advertising revenue growth.
716
Amazon has been able to enter the market because it has its own
trove of user data—namely, competitively significant first-party
data related to retail searches and purchases. Moreover, Amazon’s
50 percent penetration across U.S. households and its reach with
high-income customers are likely to help drive its ad revenue
growth.
717
While Amazon can leverage its ecosystem to overcome
some of the barriers to entry in ad tech, the recent U.K. Competi-
tion and Markets Authority report found that, as of today, Ama-
zon’s ad tech likely only has advantages in the retail sector.
718
V. DOMINANT ONLINE PLATFORMS
A. Facebook
1. Overview
Founded in 2004 by Mark Zuckerberg, Eduardo Saverin, Chris
Hughes, and Dustin Moskowitz,
719
Facebook is the largest social
networking platform in the world. Its business operates around five
primary product offerings, including: (1) Facebook, a social network
platform; (2) Instagram, a social network app for photos and vid-
eos; (3) Messenger, a cross-platform messaging app for Facebook
users; (4) WhatsApp, a cross-platform messaging app; and (5)
Oculus, a virtual reality gaming system.
Facebook reported in July 2020 that its platform includes 1.79
billion daily active users (DAUs),
720
2.7 billion monthly active
users (MAUs),
721
and an average revenue per user (ARPU) of
$7.05.
722
Last year, Facebook’s businesses collected about $70 bil-
lion in revenue—a 27 percent increase from the prior year—earn-
ing about $24 billion in income from its operations.
723
Facebook re-
ported that its family of products—including Facebook, Instagram,
Messenger, and WhatsApp—includes 2.47 billion daily active peo-
ple (DAP),
724
3.14 billion monthly active people (MAP), and a fam-
ily average revenue per person (ARPP) of $6.10.
725
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00116 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
111
726
Facebook, Inc., Quarterly Report (Form 10–Q) 42 (July 24, 2019), https://investor
.fb.com/financials/sec-filings-details/default.aspx?FilingId=13550646.
727
Id. at 53.
728
Press Release, N.Y. Att’y Gen., AG James Investigating Facebook for Possible Antitrust
Violations (Sept. 6, 2009), https://ag.ny.gov/press-release/2019/ag-james-investigating-facebook-
possible-antitrust-violations.
729
Press Release, N.Y. Att’y Gen., Attorney General James Gives Update On Facebook Anti-
trust Investigation (Oct. 22, 2019), https://ag.ny.gov/press-release/2019/attorney-general-james-
gives-update-facebook-antitrust-investigation.
730
Facebook has argued to other antitrust enforcement bodies that limiting the product mar-
ket to social networks at the exclusion of other markets, such as user attention, ‘‘would be artifi-
cial and would not reflect the competitive realities,’’ and that ‘‘competitive pressures to which
Facebook reacts are global in nature.’’ See, e.g., Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the
Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00012074 (2016) (on file with Comm.) (White Paper on Relevant
Markets and Lack of Dominance for Federal Cartel Office).
731
Omidyar Network Report.
732
Cunningham Memo at 16 (‘‘Facebook has high reach and time-spent in most countries.
User growth is tracking internet growth: global reach is roughly stable.’’).
733
Instead of competing directly with Facebook, such as Google attempted but failed to do
with Google+, other social platforms provide niche products with social graphs that are orthog-
onal to Facebook’s graph. See id. at 4 (‘‘LinkedIn[ ] and Nextdoor coexist in the US with similar
userbases but orthogonal graphs: Facebook connects friends and family, LinkedIn connects co-
workers, Nextdoor connects neighbors.’’).
In addition to the Subcommittee’s investigation of Facebook’s mo-
nopoly power, state and federal antitrust authorities are inves-
tigating Facebook for potential violations of the U.S. antitrust laws.
In July 2019, Facebook disclosed that the Federal Trade Commis-
sion (FTC) had opened an antitrust investigation of Facebook in
June 2019.
726
Facebook also disclosed that in July 2019 the De-
partment of Justice announced that it would begin an antitrust re-
view of market-leading online platforms.
727
In September 2019,
New York Attorney General Letitia James announced that she
joined with eight other attorneys general to lead a multistate inves-
tigation of Facebook.
728
In October 2019, Attorney General James
reported that the investigation into Facebook had grown to include
47 attorneys general.
729
2. Social Networking
(a) Market Power. Facebook has monopoly power in the market
for social networking.
730
According to internal documents produced
by Facebook to the Committee, it has high reach, time-spent, and
significantly more users than its rivals in this market. Despite sig-
nificant changes in the market—such as the advent of mobile de-
vices, applications, and operating systems—Facebook has held an
unassailable position in the social network market for nearly a dec-
ade, demonstrating its monopoly power.
731
Facebook’s monopoly power is firmly entrenched and unlikely to
be eroded by competitive pressure from new entrants or existing
firms. Documents produced during the investigation by Facebook,
including communications among its senior executives on market
strategy, as well as a memorandum by a senior data scientist and
economist at Facebook,
732
support the conclusion that Facebook’s
monopoly is insulated from competitive threats. The social network
market has high entry barriers—including strong network effects,
high switching costs, and Facebook’s significant data advantage—
that discourage direct competition by other firms to offer new prod-
ucts and services.
733
Facebook has also maintained and expanded
its dominance through a series of acquisitions of companies it
viewed as competitive threats, and selectively excluded competitors
from using its platform to insulate itself from competitive pressure.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00117 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
112
734
See B
UNDESKARTELLAMT
, C
ASE
S
UMMARY
: F
ACEBOOK
, E
XPLOITATIVE
B
USINESS
T
ERMS
P
UR
-
SUANT TO
S
ECTION
19(1) GWB
FOR
I
NADEQUATE
D
ATA
P
ROCESSING
6 (2019) (‘‘The facts that com-
petitors can be seen to exit the market and that there is a downward trend in the user-based
market shares of the remaining competitors strongly indicate a market tipping process which
will result in Facebook.com becoming a monopolist.’’), https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/
SharedDocs/Entscheidung/EN/Fallberichte/Missbrauchsaufsicht/2019/B6-22-16.pdf?lblob=
publicationFile&v=4.
735
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 26.
736
In addition to Facebook’s high market share, the Bundeskartellamt also found that
Facebook has market power based on other measures, including its ‘‘access to competitively rel-
evant data, economies of scale based on network effects, the behaviour of users who can use
several different services or only one service and the power of innovation-driven competitive
pressure.’’ Press Release, Bundeskartellamt, Bundeskartellamt Prohibits Facebook from Com-
bining User Data from Different Sources 4 (Feb. 7, 2019), https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/
SharedDocs/Publikation/EN/Pressemitteilungen/2019/07l02l2019lFacebooklFAQs.pdf?
llblob=publicationFile&v=6. The Bundeskartellamt also noted that, in terms of assessing
market share by time spent on the network, ‘‘the Facebook group would have a combined mar-
ket share far beyond the market dominance threshold pursuant to Section 18(4) GWB, even if
YouTube, Snapchat, Twitter, WhatsApp, and Instagram were included in the relevant market.’’
Id. at 6.
737
Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n Report at 9; see also id. at 78 (adopting a broader
view on Facebook’s product market to include Twitter and Snapchat).
738
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–APP0004 (Oct.
14, 2019); Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 17 (statement of Matt Perault, Dir. of
Pub. Pol’y, Facebook, Inc.).
739
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 567 (response to Questions for the Record
of Matt Perault, Dir. of Pub. Pol’y, Facebook, Inc.).
740
Id.
741
See, e.g., Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–
00012074 (2016) (on file with Comm.).
Together, these factors have tipped the social networking market
toward a monopoly.
734
Several antitrust enforcement agencies have examined
Facebook’s monopoly in recent years and reached similar conclu-
sions. In July 2020, the United Kingdom’s Competition and Mar-
kets Authority (CMA) found that Facebook is dominant in the mar-
kets for social networks and digital display ads, and that its mar-
ket power ‘‘derives in large part from strong network effects stem-
ming from its large network of connected users and the limited
interoperability it allows to other social media platforms.’’
735
In
July 2019, Germany’s Federal Cartel Office (Bundeskartellamt)
found that ‘‘Facebook is the dominant company in the market for
social networks,’’ and that in Germany’s social network market,
‘‘Facebook achieves a user-based market share of more than
90%.’’
736
And in June 2019, the Australian Competition & Con-
sumer Commission (ACCC) found that ‘‘Facebook has substantial
market power in a number of markets and that this market power
is unlikely to erode in the short to medium terms.’’
737
Facebook’s responses to the Committee’s requests for information
claimed that it competes in a ‘‘rapidly evolving and dynamic mar-
ketplace in which competition is vigorous,’’ citing Twitter,
Snapchat, Pinterest, and TikTok as examples of competition
Facebook faces for ‘‘every product and service’’ that it offers.
738
Ac-
cording to Facebook, its users ‘‘have many choices and can leave
Facebook if they’re not happy,’’
739
allowing people to quickly aban-
don it. The ability of users to ‘‘explore the myriad other options
available . . . creates strong competition for every product and serv-
ice Facebook offers, as well as pressure to develop new products to
attract and retain users.’’
740
In response to other antitrust inquiries, Facebook said that it
competes for users’ attention broadly.
741
In a 2016 white paper
prepared in response to an investigation by Germany’s Federal
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00118 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
113
742
Id.
743
F
ACEBOOK
, F
ACEBOOK
S
R
ESPONSE TO THE
D
IGITAL
P
LATFORMS
I
NQUIRY FOR
A
USTRALIAN
C
OMPETITION AND
C
ONSUMER
C
OMMISSION
25 (Sept. 12, 2019), https://fbnewsroomus.files
.wordpress.com/2019/09/facebook-submission-to-treasury-on-digital-platforms-inquiry.pdf.
744
Interview with Former Instagram Employee (Oct. 2, 2020).
745
Id.
746
Id.
747
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 121 n.152.
748
The Subcommittee made a supplemental request after identifying Facebook’s industry up-
dates during the review of documents produced in response to the Committee’s September 2019
request for information.
749
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–000025 (Mar.
5, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
750
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00012074, FB–HJC–ACAL–00012090 (2016) (on file with Comm.).
751
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00054944 (Apr. 27, 2012) (on file with Comm.).
Cartel Office, Facebook stated that it ‘‘faces intense competition for
user attention and engagement at every level,’’ listing companies as
diverse as Candy Crush and Clash of the Clans—popular mobile
gaming apps—along with YouTube, Twitter, Pinterest, Snapchat
and others as competitors for users’ attention.
742
Facebook simi-
larly submitted to the ACCC that, if the company does not compete
vigorously, users will go to other ‘‘platforms, websites, apps, and
other services—not just social media services—that compete for
their attention.’’
743
In an interview conducted by the Sub-
committee, a former employee explained that, as a product man-
ager at Facebook, ‘‘your only job is to get an extra minute. It’s im-
moral. They don’t ask where it’s coming from. They can monetize
a minute of activity at a certain rate. So the only metric is getting
another minute.’’
744
Facebook describes a diverse list of other firms as competitive
substitutes for Facebook, including Microsoft’s Bing, a search en-
gine; Yelp, a publisher of crowd-sourced business reviews; and
BuzzFeed, a digital news publisher.
745
According to Facebook,
these firms exert competitive pressure on Facebook in the market
for users’ attention.
746
Most recently, in response to an inquiry by
the United Kingdom’s Competition and Markets Authority,
Facebook calculated its market share as ‘‘time captured by
Facebook as a percentage of total user time spent on the internet,
including social media, dating, news and search platforms.’’
747
Based on these measures, Facebook concluded that it lacks monop-
oly power.
Facebook’s position that it lacks monopoly power and competes
in a dynamic market is not supported by the documents it pro-
duced to the Committee during the investigation. Instead,
Facebook’s internal business metrics show that Facebook wields
monopoly power. In response to a supplemental information re-
quest by the Subcommittee,
748
Facebook produced industry updates
prepared in the ordinary course of business by Facebook’s Market
Strategy team.
749
It has described these reports as both ‘‘internal
competitive metrics’’ and as a ‘‘competitive survey regularly pre-
pared for Facebook’s management team [that] tracks a variable set
of competitors not by specific products or features, but by the de-
gree of user attention and engagement that they command in
terms of monthly active users (‘MAU’) and daily active users
(‘DAU’).’’
750
Facebook’s industry updates were shared internally with senior
executives, including Mark Zuckerberg, Facebook’s CEO.
751
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00119 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
114
752
Although it does not include data from users of Apple’s iMessage, which is relevant for
purposes of usage on WhatsApp and Messenger, Facebook’s documents note that iMessage’s
growth is limited by the adoption of iPhones, whereas Facebook’s products can be used across
different devices. See generally Cunningham Memo at 15.
753
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00012090
(2016) (on file with Comm.).
754
Cunningham Memo at 9 (citing data from MINT, another name used for Onavo within
Facebook, Inc.).
755
Id. at 2; see also id. at 16 (‘‘Facebook has high reach and time-spent in most countries.
User growth is tracking internet growth: global reach is roughly stable.’’).
756
Submission from Facebook, to Comm. on the Judiciary, 38 (Jan. 2020) (on file with
Comm.) (Monthly Update for December 2019, based on Facebook’s internal calibrations of App
Annie data). According to Facebook, the monthly active persons (MAP) metric is ‘‘based on the
activity of users who visited at least one of Facebook, Instagram, Messenger, and WhatsApp
(collectively, our ‘Family’ of products) during the applicable period of measurement.’’ Facebook,
Inc., Quarterly Report (Form 10–Q) 4 (Apr. 30, 2020), http://d18rn0p25nwr6d.cloudfront.net/
CIK-0001326801/5fc46b22-5cb5-4014-bcb7-7edc64f2d963.pdf.
757
Interview with Former Instagram Employee (Oct. 2, 2020) (‘‘Reach is closer to market pen-
etration [than usage and engagement]. It applies to the number of internet users we think are
in that country, how many use a Facebook Family app and have taken one meaningful action.
What people forget is that Facebook believes its total addressable market being anyone that has
access to the internet.’’).
758
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 38 (Jan. 2020) (on file with
Comm.) (Monthly Update for December 2019); Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the
Judiciary, 32 (Oct. 2019) (on file with Comm.) (Monthly Update for September 2019, based on
Facebook’s internal calibrations of App Annie data).
759
Id.
760
Id.
761
Id.
762
See generally Omidyar Network Report at 11.
763
Cunningham Memo at 2.
Facebook used data collected through Onavo, a virtual private net-
work (VPN) app, to provide detailed competitive insights into the
usage and engagement of other firms.
752
Facebook also relied on
this data in response to inquiries by the European Commission and
the Bundeskartellamt,
753
as well as to prepare detailed internal re-
ports on market strategy.
754
(i) Usage and Reach. Facebook has monopoly power in the social
networking market. Based on its internal documents, Facebook and
its family of products—Facebook, Instagram, Messenger, and
WhatsApp—control a significant share of users and have high
reach in the social networking market.
755
Facebook’s family of
products includes three of the seven most popular mobile apps in
the United States by monthly active persons, reach, and percentage
of daily and monthly active persons.
756
As a standalone product, the Facebook app had the third highest
reach of all mobile apps,
757
with 200.3 million users in the United
States, reaching 74 percent of smartphone users as of December
2019.
758
Facebook Messenger had the fourth highest reach, with
183.6 million monthly active persons, reaching 54.1 percent of U.S.
smartphone users.
759
Finally, Instagram had the sixth highest
reach, with 119.2 million users, reaching 35.3 percent of
smartphone users.
760
In contrast, Snapchat, the mobile app with
the seventh highest reach, had 106.5 million users in the United
States, reaching 31.4 percent of smartphone users.
761
Facebook’s maintenance of these high market shares over a long
time period demonstrates its monopoly power.
762
From September
2017 to September 2018, Facebook reached more than 75 percent
of users internationally with at or near 100 percent market pene-
tration in nine of the twenty most populous countries in the
world.
763
In the United States, Facebook alone reached more than
75 percent of internet users during this period, while Messenger
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00120 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
115
764
Id.
765
Id. at 12.
766
Id. at 16 (emphasis added).
767
Id. (‘‘Facebook has high reach and time-spent in most countries. User growth is tracking
internet growth: global reach is roughly stable.’’).
768
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00086798
(Aug. 22, 2020) (on file with Comm.) (Monthly Update for August 2018).
769
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00057113, https://judiciary.house.gov/uploadedfiles/00057113l
picture.pdf; id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00049006 (Jan. 28, 2012) (on file with Comm.).
770
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00057113, https://judiciary.house.gov/uploadedfiles/00057113l
picture.pdf.
771
Prepared by Subcommittee staff based on id.
and Instagram both achieved significant reach as well.
764
Accord-
ing to a white paper prepared by a senior data scientist and econo-
mist at Facebook, the Facebook app has high reach in most coun-
tries, and its growth is in line with that of the internet, whereas
Instagram and WhatsApp are still growing ‘‘very rapidly.’’
765
For
Instagram, ‘‘there appear to be no countries in which growth has
hit a ceiling.’’
766
Facebook’s family of products are more immersive of users’ atten-
tion.
767
According to Facebook’s internal market data, its users
spend significantly more time on its family of products than on
competing services. For example, social media users spent more
time on Facebook (48.6 minutes) than on Snapchat (21 minutes) or
Twitter (21.6 minutes) in 2018.
768
Since at least 2012, Facebook’s documents show that Facebook
believed it controlled a high share of the social networking mar-
ket.
769
In a presentation prepared for Sheryl Sandberg, Facebook’s
Chief Operating Officer, to deliver at a large telecommunications
firm, Facebook said that it controlled ‘‘95% of all social media’’ in
the United States in terms of monthly minutes of use—as com-
pared to Twitter, Tumblr, Myspace, and all other social media—
and noted that the ‘‘industry consolidates as it matures.’’
770
Facebook Investor Presentation
771
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00121 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 10 here 11701.010
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
116
772
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00049006 (Apr. 30, 2012) (on file with Comm.).
773
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00064320 (Apr. 18, 2012).
774
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00049006 (Apr. 30, 2012) (on file with Comm.).
775
Id.
776
Id.
777
Id. (‘‘Imagine 10 years from now . . . [a] [l]ocal TV show asking an entrepreneur how he
can hope to compete with Facebook.’’).
778
CEO Hearing at 85 (question of Rep. Joe Neguse (D–CO), Vice Chair, Subcomm. on Anti-
trust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm on the Judiciary).
779
Id. at 86.
780
Id.
781
Id. (statement of Mark Zuckerberg, CEO, Facebook, Inc.).
782
F
ACEBOOK
, F
ACEBOOK
S
R
ESPONSE TO THE
CMA’
S
I
NTERIM
R
EPORT
13–14 (Feb. 14, 2020),
https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/media/5e8c827ae90e070774c61fdb/Facebooklresponse
ltolinterimlreportlwithlcoverlletter.pdf.
783
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00012074
(2016) (on file with Comm.).
784
See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 51–52 (D.C. Cir. 2001); see also Com-
petition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 117–18 (‘‘[T]he closeness of competition between different plat-
forms depends on the degree to which consumers consider them substitutes, rather than the ex-
tent to which they share common functionalities.’’).
A 2012 investor presentation prepared for Facebook described it
as having an ‘‘enduring competitive advantage’’ similar to other
historically dominant firms.
772
According to this document, which
was reviewed and edited by Facebook’s Chief Financial Officer to
present to investors,
773
Facebook had nearly 100 percent market
penetration among 25–34 year-olds in the United States.
774
It also
had more than 85 percent penetration in certain countries.
775
As
noted in the presentation, ‘‘In every country we’ve tipped, we have
maintained that penetration.’’
776
This point was underscored by a
suggestion in the presentation that within a decade, it would be
doubtful that entrepreneurs could compete with Facebook.
777
At the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Subcommittee Vice Chair
Joe Neguse (D–CO) asked Mr. Zuckerberg about Facebook’s monop-
oly power.
778
As Mr. Neguse noted, based on this evidence, ‘‘most
folks would concede Facebook was a monopoly as early as
2012.’’
779
Since then, he added that Facebook’s strategy has been
to ‘‘protect what I describe as a monopoly’’ by acquiring, copying,
or eliminating its competitors.
780
Mr. Zuckerberg responded by
characterizing the social networking market as ‘‘a very large
space.’’
781
However, Facebook did not corroborate this claim
through the evidence it produced during the investigation.
Lastly, after reviewing relevant market data and documents pro-
vided during the investigation, the Subcommittee found that there
are distinct, relevant markets for social networking and social
media. Facebook proposes that online services with social functions,
such as YouTube, are social networks that compete in the same
product market as Facebook and its other products for user atten-
tion.
782
For example, in a white paper submission, Facebook com-
pares its News Feed, which includes a stream of posts and videos
uploaded by users, as similar to the content feed that users encoun-
ter on YouTube.
783
However, longstanding antitrust doctrine de-
scribes relevant product markets as those that are ‘‘reasonably
interchangeable by consumers for the same purposes.’’
784
Although
YouTube is a dominant social app, it is primarily used to consume
video content online. It does not provide the core functionality of
Facebook or its family of products, such as Pages, Marketplace, or
limited sharing within a person’s network.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00122 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
117
785
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 120 (‘‘[T]here are particularly important differences
between YouTube, which most consumers use for video streaming, and platforms such as those
of Facebook, which focus more on consumer needs related to social networking.’’).
786
Id. at 126, 128.
787
Id. at 127.
788
See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 84 F. Supp. 2d 9, 20 (D.D.C. 1999) (‘‘A positive net-
work effect is a phenomenon by which the attractiveness of a product increases with the number
of people using it.’’). The corollary is that, when fewer people use the product, it becomes less
attractive, which can tip the market in favor of another firm if there are low entry barriers.
Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 35.
789
See generally Omidyar Network Report at 18.
790
See, e.g., Cunningham Memo at 7 (‘‘Messenger and WhatsApp clearly compete for time-
spent.’’). While Facebook’s overall penetration and network effects are high in the United States
and across many other large countries, Facebook appears to have intermediate reach in some
countries due to differing levels of adoption among users of certain ages. Id. at 12 (‘‘In Japan
and South Korea Facebook has significantly higher penetration among youth than among elder-
ly. The role of an intergenerational social network is partly filled by other apps (LINE and
Kakao).’’).
791
The Subcommittee requested the 2018 memorandum prepared by Tom Cunningham on
July 1, 2020 in response to earlier reporting about the memorandum. See Alex Heath, Facebook
Secret Research Warned of ‘‘Tipping Point’’ Threat to Core App, I
NFORMATION
(July 23, 2020),
https://www.theinformation.com/articles/facebook-secret-research-warned-of-tipping-point-
threat-to-core-app. The Subcommittee appreciates that Facebook cooperated with this supple-
mental request.
792
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00063222
(Feb. 27, 2012), https://judiciary.house.gov/uploadedfiles/0006322000063223.pdf.
793
Cunningham Memo at 1, 3.
794
During this period, Facebook referred to data derived from Onavo as MINT data.
The United Kingdom’s Competition and Markets Authority
reached a similar conclusion, finding that YouTube is primarily a
market for consuming video content rather than a market for com-
munication.
785
As it noted, ‘‘consumers use YouTube for particu-
larly distinctive reasons .... YouTube does not currently appear to
provide a strong competitive constraint on Facebook, despite its
comparable reach and levels of consumer engagement.’’
786
Internal
documents produced to the United Kingdom bolstered this finding,
indicating ‘‘that the most common reasons consumers in the UK ac-
cess YouTube are for entertainment and to view ‘how-to’ videos on
the platform.’’
787
(ii) Barriers to Entry. Facebook’s persistently high market share
is not contestable due to high barriers to entry that discourage
competition. These barriers to entry include its strong network ef-
fects, high switching costs for consumers, and data advantages.
(1) Network Effects. Facebook’s significant reach among users,
and high levels of engagement, create very strong network ef-
fects.
788
As a result, Facebook has tipped the market in its favor,
789
pri-
marily facing competitive pressure from within its own family of
products—such as through Instagram competing with Facebook or
WhatsApp competing with Messenger—rather than actual competi-
tion from other firms in the market.
790
This finding is supported
by Facebook’s documents and internal analysis. These include a
memorandum on Facebook’s family of products prepared in October
2018 by Thomas Cunningham, a senior data scientist and econo-
mist,
791
as well as communications among senior executives.
792
Mr. Cunningham’s 2018 memorandum on ‘‘Possible End States
for the Family of Apps’’ is an analysis of user trends among
Facebook’s products and other competitors.
793
It is based on the
company’s Onavo data from September 2017 to September
2018.
794
It was prepared for review by Facebook’s senior execu-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00123 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
118
795
Interview with Former Instagram Employee (Oct. 2, 2020).
796
Id.
797
Id.
798
Cunningham Memo at 11.
799
Id. at 9.
800
To underscore this point, the Cunningham Memo does not characterize YouTube as a di-
rect competitor, noting that YouTube would only be a danger if it ‘‘becomes more social.’’ Id.
at 16.
801
Id. at 9.
802
Id. at 10; see also id. at 14 (‘‘Most countries have a single messaging app with 70%+ daily
reach. The most common app is WhatsApp. Others include Messenger, LINE, and Kakotalk.’’).
803
Id. at 3.
804
Id.
805
Id. at 12 (‘‘WhatsApp does very well when it is the market-leader (in many Latin Amer-
ican countries WhatsApp has nearly 90% daily reach and users spend 60 minutes/day), this sug-
gests that it would be worth a substantial investment to try to push WhatsApp over its tipping
point in other countries.’’). An exception to this trend appears to be where a messaging app ex-
ists as part of a social network—such as messaging services on Snapchat—but these apps oper-
ate with reduced reach. Another exception is in markets with high penetration by Apple’s
iPhone, but this growth is limited by adoption of iPhones since iMessage is its native app. Id.
at 15.
806
Id. at 16 (‘‘Facebook has high reach and time-spent in most countries. User growth is
tracking internet growth: global reach is roughly stable. DAP is showing weakness in developed
countries and especially teens.’’).
tives, including Mr. Zuckerberg and Mr. Olivan, Facebook’s Direc-
tor of Growth.
795
The Subcommittee’s staff interviewed a former
senior employee at the company who attended meetings preparing
the document for presentation to Mr. Zuckerberg and Mr. Olivan.
The former employee noted that ‘‘this specific working group—and
Tom Cunningham’s work in particular—was guiding Mark’s views’’
on the company’s growth strategy.
796
The former employee ex-
plained the purpose of the Cunningham Memo:
The question was how do we position Facebook and Instagram to not compete
with each other. The concern was that Instagram would hit a tipping point ....
There was brutal in-fighting between Instagram and Facebook at the time. It
was very tense. It was back when Kevin Systrom was still at the company. He
wanted Instagram to grow naturally and as widely as possible. But Mark was
clearly saying ‘‘do not compete with us.’’ . . . It was collusion, but within an inter-
nal monopoly. If you own two social media utilities, they should not be allowed
to shore each other up. It’s unclear to me why this should not be illegal. You
can collude by acquiring competitors and forbidding competition.
797
The Cunningham Memo characterized the network effects of
Facebook, WhatsApp, and Messenger as ‘‘very strong.’’
798
The
memorandum notes that social apps have tipping points such that
‘‘either everyone uses them, or no-one uses them.’’
799
Importantly,
it distinguishes between apps with a social graph that are used for
broadcast sharing and messaging—Facebook, Instagram, Mes-
senger, WhatsApp, and Snapchat—and social apps for music or
video consumption, such as YouTube or Spotify.
800
In contrast,
non-social apps ‘‘can exist along a continuum of adoption.’’
801
Network effects and tipping points are particularly strong in
messaging apps. Because WhatsApp and other regional messaging
apps have bimodal distribution of reach in countries—an all-or-
nothing reach at above 90 percent or below 10 percent—messaging
tends toward consolidation and market tipping.
802
Most countries
have a single messaging app or protocol because they cannot sup-
port multiple messaging apps.
803
As a result of this dynamic, there
are ‘‘tradeoffs in time-spent between Messenger and WhatsApp,’’
804
demonstrating ‘‘very strong tipping points.’’
805
Facebook already has high reach in many countries,
806
including
the United States, so a primary concern addressed in Mr.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00124 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
119
807
The Cunningham Memo refers to Facebook’s flagship product as ‘‘Facebook-Blue’’ or ‘‘Blue’’
as a reference to the app’s color. Id. at 15. There is overlap and cross-use among Facebook’s
products in the United States. While 40 percent of Instagram users’ friends are also their
friends on Facebook, only 12 percent of Facebook users’ friends are ‘‘reciprocal follows’’ on
Instagram. Id. at 9.
808
Id. at 9.
809
Id. at 6. A recent investor report similarly noted that although ‘‘many users access more
than one social network per day, it does not appear to be at the cost of declining users or user
engagements within the Facebook ecosystem.’’ M
ORNINGSTAR
E
QUITY
A
NALYST
R
EPORT
:
F
ACEBOOK
I
NC
3 (Aug. 3, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
810
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00063222
(Feb. 28, 2012), https://judiciary.house.gov/uploadedfiles/0006322000063223.pdf.
811
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00046826 to –00046834 (Dec. 13, 2013) (on file with Comm.).
Cunningham’s ‘‘Possible End States’’ memorandum is whether
cross-app sharing among Facebook’s family of products poses a
competitive threat to its flagship product, the Facebook app.
807
While the Cunningham Memo concluded that it is unclear whether
Instagram and Facebook can coexist, it is much less concerned with
Facebook’s user loss due to cannibalization by Instagram than with
market tipping (i.e., Instagram tipping the market in its favor and
Facebook rapidly losing value due to network effects). It notes:
The most important concern should be network effects, not within-user cannibal-
ization. We have reviewed many studies which estimate cannibalization among
apps for individual users, all of which find positive incrementality across the
family: i.e. when a user increases their use of one app, they tend to decrease
their use of other apps, but the total family effect is positive. This should not
be surprising—it is unlikely that any of our apps are perfect substitutes for an
individual user. However a serious concern is network effects: when you use an
app less, that makes it less appealing to other people, and at certain times and
places those effects could be very large.
808
As a result of this dynamic, even though there may be several
social apps that exist in an ecosystem, they are unlikely to gain
traction among users once a firm has tipped the market in its favor
or is otherwise dominant. As the study notes, while mobile phone
users tend to use five different social maps in a month, they only
use ‘‘1.5 messaging apps and 1 social app, out of 10 total apps per
day.’’
809
Facebook’s executives—including Mr. Zuckerberg—have exten-
sively discussed the role of network effects and tipping points as
part of the company’s acquisition strategy and overall competitive
outlook. For example, Mr. Zuckerberg told the company’s Chief Fi-
nancial Officer in 2012 that network effects and winner-take-all
markets were a motivating factor in acquiring competitive threats
like Instagram. He said:
[T]here are network effects around social products and a finite number of dif-
ferent social mechanics to invent. Once someone wins at a specific mechanic, it’s
difficult for others to supplant them without doing something different. It’s pos-
sible someone beats Instagram by building something that is better to the point
that they get network migration, but this is harder as long as Instagram keeps
running as a product . . . one way of looking at this is that what we’re really buy-
ing is time. Even if some new competitors springs [sic] up, buying Instagram
now . . . will give us a year or more to integrate their dynamics before anyone
can get close to their scale again. Within that time, if we incorporate the social
mechanics they were using, those new products won’t get much traction since
we’ll already have their mechanics deployed at scale.
810
Mr. Zuckerberg also stressed the competitive significance of hav-
ing a first-mover advantage in terms of network effects prior to ac-
quiring WhatsApp.
811
In the context of market strategies for Mes-
senger competing with WhatsApp, Mr. Zuckerberg told the com-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00125 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
120
812
Id.
813
Id.
814
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00049006
(Apr. 18, 2012) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Network effects make it very difficult to compete with
us—In every country we’ve tipped we are still winning.’’).
815
Id.
816
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00086834 to
–00086838 (Apr. 3, 2012) (on file with Comm.) (Citi Summary of Investment Outlook). Comscore
noted in 2012 that ‘‘Facebook has proven to be a dominant global force in social networking that
shows no immediate signs of slowing down.’’ According to Comscore, Facebook was the ‘‘third
largest web property in the world . . . and accounted for approximately 3 in every 4 minutes
spent on social networking sites and 1 in every 7 minutes spent online around the world.’’ FB–
HJC–ACAL–00051905 (Mar. 12, 2012) (Comscore 2012 Report).
817
Omidyar Network Report at 11 (‘‘A very significant reason that Facebook has market
power is that a user cannot change platforms and expect to be able to stay in contact with her
friends. Because Facebook has a near monopoly, the vast majority of the people with whom they
want to exchange feeds are likely on Facebook already. The switching cost for any one user is
therefore enormous.’’).
818
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00045349
(Feb. 15, 2014) (on file with Comm.).
819
See, e.g., Nicole Nguyen, If You Created a Spotify Account with Facebook, It Is Forever
Tied to Facebook, B
UZZ
F
EED
(Oct. 3, 2018), https://www.buzzfeednews.com/article/
nicolenguyen/disconnect-facebook-account-from-spotify.
820
See, e.g., Danny Crichton, Why No One Really Quits Google or Facebook, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Feb. 4, 2019), https://techcrunch.com/2019/02/04/why-no-one-really-quits-google-or-facebook/
(‘‘I have 2,000 contacts on Facebook Messenger—am I just supposed to text them all to use Sig-
nal from now on? Am I supposed to completely relearn a new photos app, when I am habituated
to the taps required from years of practice on Instagram?’’); United States v. Microsoft Corp.,
84 F. Supp. 2d 9, 15 (D.D.C. 1999) (noting that switching costs include ‘‘the effort of learning
to use the new system, the cost of acquiring a new set of compatible applications, and the work
of replacing files and documents that were associated with the old applications’’).
821
See generally Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n Report at 99; Dig. Competition Ex-
pert Panel Report at 42.
pany’s growth and product management teams that ‘‘being first is
how you build a brand and a network effect.’’
812
He also told them
that Facebook has ‘‘an opportunity to do this at scale, but that op-
portunity won’t last forever. I doubt we have even a year before
WhatsApp starts moving in this direction.’’
813
In 2012, the company described its network effects as a
‘‘flywheel’’ in an internal presentation prepared for Facebook at the
direction of its Chief Financial Officer.
814
This presentation also
said that Facebook’s network effects get ‘‘stronger every day.’’
815
Around that time, prominent investors similarly noted that the so-
cial networking market had ‘‘extreme network effects,’’ making it
‘‘increasingly hard to see a materially successful new entrant, even
with all of Google’s resources.’’
816
(2) Switching Costs. In addition to the competitive insulation re-
sulting from strong network effects, Facebook is also unlikely to
face direct competition from other firms or new entrants due to the
high costs for users to switch from Facebook to a competing social
network.
817
Other social network platforms are not interoperable with
Facebook. Facebook users invest significant time building their net-
works on Facebook. This investment includes uploading and
curating photos; engaging with their friends, other users, and busi-
nesses; and otherwise interacting with their social graph.
818
To
switch to another platform, Facebook users have to rebuild their
social graph elsewhere. In the process, they lose access to their
data—including photos, posts, and other content—along with other
elements of their social graph.
819
They also have to learn how to
use a new service and rebuild their network.
820
As a result,
Facebook’s users are effectively ‘‘locked in’’ to its platform.
821
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00126 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
121
822
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00045349
(Feb. 15, 2014) (on file with Comm.).
823
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00048755 to –00048757 (Dec. 14, 2011).
824
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00049006 (Apr. 18, 2012).
825
See, e.g., D
ATA
T
RANSFER
P
ROJECT
, https://datatransferproject.dev/ (last visited Sept. 28,
2020).
826
Interview with Former Instagram Employee (Oct. 2, 2020).
827
Facebook Login Help, S
POTIFY
, https://support.spotify.com/us/article/using-spotify-with-
facebook/ (last visited Oct. 5, 2020).
828
Id.
829
Spotify users can manually attempt to recreate playlists or request that Spotify transfer
their data, but this is not intuitive. Samantha Cole, How to Unlink Spotify from Your Facebook
Continued
Facebook’s internal documents and communications reveal that
Facebook employees recognize that high switching costs insulate
Facebook from competition. In 2014, Facebook’s Chief Financial Of-
ficer told the company’s director of growth that investors like this
quality about Facebook and ‘‘the idea is that after you have in-
vested hours and hours in your friend graph or interest graph or
follower graph, you are less likely to leave for a new or different
service that offers similar functionality.’’
822
Similarly, an internal
survey prepared for Facebook’s senior management team about
Google+ explained that ‘‘[p]eople who are big fans of G+ are having
a hard time convincing their friends to participate because . . .
switching costs would be high due to friend density on
Facebook.’’
823
And in 2012, the company indicated that people’s
significant time investment on Facebook building their identity and
connections on the platform increased the company’s ‘‘sticki-
ness.’’
824
In contrast to its public statements, Facebook has not done
enough to facilitate data portability for its consumers. Facebook of-
fers a tool called ‘‘Download Your Information,’’ which provides
users with a limited ability to download their data and upload it
elsewhere. But in practice, this tool is unusable for switching pur-
poses given that it allows users to do little other than move their
photos from Facebook to Google Photos. Another barrier for switch-
ing associated with this tool is that Facebook’s users can only
download their data in PDF or .zip format. The result is that, while
Facebook publicly claims to support data portability,
825
its users
seldom leave Facebook due to the challenges of migrating their
data. An interview with a former employee at the company rein-
forces this conclusion. As the former employee noted, this tool is be-
hind a series of menus, explaining:
If you hide something behind more than one menu, no one sees it and they know
it. Then they advertise features that they don’t expect anyone to find or use.
They say: ‘‘It’s data portable, you can send it to Google drive?’’ But who cares?
They’ve just done it to generate talking points. They are not allowing you to ex-
port your social graph, which is actually valuable.
826
Leaving Facebook may create additional costs in other key re-
spects. Switching from Facebook may degrade a person’s other so-
cial apps that integrate with Facebook’s Platform APIs. For exam-
ple, Spotify users who signed up with Facebook ‘‘can’t disconnect
it.’’
827
To leave Facebook, they must set up a new account on
Spotify.
828
In the process, they lose access to their playlists, listen-
ing history, social graph of other friends on Spotify, and their other
data on the app.
829
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00127 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
122
Account, V
ICE
(Dec. 21, 2018), https://www.vice.com/enlus/article/wj3anm/how-to-unlink-
spotify-from-your-facebook-account.
830
See Cunningham Memo at 3.
831
See, e.g., Tiffany Hsu, For Many Facebook Users, a ‘‘Last Straw’’ that Led Them to Quit,
N.Y. T
IMES
(Mar. 21, 2018), https://www.nytimes.com/2018/03/21/technology/users-abandon-
facebook.html (‘‘The Cambridge Analytica scandal led her to remove the Facebook app from her
phone .... But she is keeping the messaging function open for professional purposes and will
continue using Instagram.’’).
832
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 179, 256.
833
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 567 (response to Questions for the Record
of Matt Perault, Dir. of Pub. Pol’y, Facebook, Inc.).
834
E
RIN
E
GAN
, F
ACEBOOK
, C
HARTING A
W
AY
F
ORWARD
: D
ATA
P
ORTABILITY AND
P
RIVACY
6
(2019), https://about.fb.com/wp-content/uploads/2020/02/data-portability-privacy-white-paper
.pdf.
835
Id.
836
Mark Zuckerberg, The Internet Needs New Rules, W
ASH
. P
OST
(Mar. 29, 2019), https://
www.washingtonpost.com/opinions/mark-zuckerberg-the-internet-needs-new-rules-lets-start-in-
these-four-areas/2019/03/29/9e6f0504-521a-11e9-a3f7-78b7525a8d5flstory.html.
837
Id.
838
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 137.
839
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00045364
(Feb. 4, 2014) (on file with Comm.).
840
Id.
People who leave Facebook may also lose access to popular fea-
tures on Facebook that, due to its scale and network effects, are
not available on other social apps (e.g., events, marketplace, and
groups).
830
For example, a church may actively maintain a
Facebook page for its parishioners and not on other social apps.
Furthermore, some Facebook users who believe they are switching
from the company’s platform may nevertheless continue using its
family of products, such as Instagram or WhatsApp.
831
As the
United Kingdom’s Competition and Markets Authority noted, this
reinforces Facebook’s market power.
832
In response to the concern about switching costs, Facebook re-
plied that its users have meaningful choices and alternatives to
Facebook.
833
Additionally, Facebook notes that its users have been
able to download their data since 2010.
834
The company describes
its users’ ability to download their data as a ‘‘robust portability
tool.’’
835
However, in March 2019, Mr. Zuckerberg explained that
a Facebook user’s ability to download their data is not ‘‘[t]rue data
portability.’’
836
Instead, he said its users should be able to sign in
to other services in ‘‘the way people use our platform to sign into
an app.’’
837
Currently, Facebook’s users lack the ability to port their social
networks to a different platform. To switch social networking plat-
forms, a Facebook user can import their contacts from their mobile
devices, such as email addresses or phone numbers, to build a net-
work on a different platform. But importing contacts is not a sub-
stitute for a person’s social graph and, as the CMA concluded, this
method is likely limited to a person’s close friends.
838
In recogni-
tion of this, Javier Olivan, Facebook’s Director of Growth, told the
company’s senior management team that information from a per-
son’s address book on their mobile device is ‘‘incomplete’’ because
people typically only store limited information in their contacts
(e.g., a person’s first name, last name, and their phone num-
ber).
839
In contrast, Facebook users ‘‘have a much richer profile—
which creates a much richer experience (we have data that shows
how . . . profile pictures make for better/more functional [user inter-
faces]).’’
840
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00128 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
123
841
Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 33.
842
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 143–44.
843
Id.
844
Omidyar Network Report at 18.
845
See, e.g., M
AURICE
S
TUCKE &
A
LLEN
G
RUNES
, B
IG
D
ATA AND
C
OMPETITION
P
OLICY
46
(2017).
846
Also referred to as Facebook Login, Facebook Connect allowed its users to connect their
Facebook identity—their profile, friends, and other data—to other social apps through
Facebook’s APIs. The company explained in 2008 that, ‘‘[w]ith Facebook Connect, users can
bring their real identity information with them wherever they go on the Web, including: basic
profile information, profile picture, name, friends, photos, events, groups, and more.’’ Dave
Morin, Announcing Facebook Connect, F
ACEBOOK
(Mar. 9, 2008), https://developers.facebook
.com/blog/post/2008/05/09/announcing-facebook-connect/.
847
Ben Popper, Startup Steroids: Pinterest Feels the Burn of Facebook’s Open Graph, V
ERGE
(May 3, 2012), https://www.theverge.com/2012/5/3/2993999/pinterest-burn-facebook-open-
graph-startup-steroids.
(3) Access to Data. Facebook has a significant data advantage in
the social networking market. While data may be non-rivalrous—
meaning users can provide the same piece of data to more than one
platform—it creates another entry barrier, reinforcing Facebook’s
monopoly power.
The Subcommittee conducted interviews with market partici-
pants that described Facebook as having nearly perfect market in-
telligence. Facebook’s data dominance creates self-reinforcing ad-
vantages through two types of ‘‘feedback loops.’’
841
First, by virtue
of its significant number of users, Facebook has access to and col-
lects more user data than its competitors.
842
And second, Facebook
uses this data to create a more targeted user experience, which in
turn attracts more users and leads those users to spend more time
on the platform.
843
In contrast, smaller platforms with less access
to data must compete by providing a different user experience with
less targeting capacity. Facebook’s data advantage is thus com-
pounded over time, cementing Facebook’s market position and
making it even more difficult for new platforms to provide a com-
petitive user experience.
Facebook’s data advantages also provide a monetization feedback
loop. Revenue generated through targeted advertising to existing
users can be reinvested into the platform, thereby attracting more
users. Facebook’s ability to provide targeted advertising is highly
valuable to advertisers and allows Facebook to monetize its service.
Meanwhile, smaller entrants are less attractive to advertisers since
‘‘no de novo entrant [has] access to anywhere near the volume or
quality of data’’ as Facebook.
844
As with its user feedback loop,
Facebook’s monetization feedback loop creates a runaway virtuous
circle that serves as a powerful barrier to entry.
Facebook’s data also enables it to act as a gatekeeper because
Facebook can exclude other firms from accessing its users’ data.
845
Beginning in 2010, Facebook’s Open Graph provided other compa-
nies with the ability to scale through its user base by inter-
connecting with Facebook’s platform. Some companies benefited
immensely from this relationship, experiencing significant user
growth from Open Graph and in-app signups through Facebook
Connect, now called Facebook Login.
846
Around that time, inves-
tors commented that Open Graph gave some companies ‘‘monstrous
growth,’’ referring to it as ‘‘steroids for startups.’’
847
For example,
documents produced by Facebook indicate that it was the top refer-
rer of traffic to Spotify, driving seven million people ‘‘to install
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00129 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
124
848
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00049471 (on
file with Comm.) (Script of Keynote for Mobile World Congress).
849
Id.
850
See, e.g., M
AURICE
S
TUCKE &
A
LLEN
G
RUNES
, B
IG
D
ATA AND
C
OMPETITION
P
OLICY
46
(2017).
851
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–FTC–CID–00364078 to
–00364147 (Mar. 24, 2012) (on file with Comm.) (email on Daily Metrics Report).
852
See Stigler Report at 43.
853
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 15.
854
See Aoife White, Facebook Told by U.K. Watchdog to Monitor Giphy Independence,
B
LOOMBERG
(Aug. 10, 2020), https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2020-08-10/facebook-
told-by-u-k-watchdog-to-monitor-giphy-independence.
855
Id.; B
ERKELEY
, T
HE
A
CQUISITION
T
AKEOVER BY THE
5 T
ECH
G
IANTS
, http://people.
ischool.berkeley.edu/#neha01mittal/infoviz/dashboard/ (last visited Sept. 28, 2020).
856
See, e.g., Josh Constine, Facebook’s $2 Billion Acquisition of Oculus Closes, Now Official,
T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(July 21, 2014), https://techcrunch.com/2014/07/21/facebooks-acquisition-of-
oculus-closes-now-official/.
857
See, e.g., Jacob Kastrenakes, Facebook Is Shutting Down a Teen App It Bought Eight
Months Ago, V
ERGE
(July 2, 2018), https://www.theverge.com/2018/7/2/17528896/facebook-
tbh-moves-hello-shut-down-low-usage.
858
Stan Schroeder, Facebook Acquires Team Behind Blockchain Startup Chainspace,
M
ASHABLE
(Dec. 5, 2019), https://mashable.com/article/facebook-acquires-blockchain-team-
chainspace/.
859
Dean Takahashi, Facebook Acquires Lone Echo VR Game Maker Ready at Dawn, V
ENTURE
B
EAT
(June 22, 2020), https://venturebeat.com/2020/06/22/facebook-acquires-lone-echo-vr-
game-maker-ready-at-dawn/; Lucas Matney, Facebook Acquires the VR Game Studio Behind
One of the Rift’s Best Titles, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Feb. 25, 2020), https://techcrunch.com/2020/02/25/
facebook-acquires-the-vr-game-studio-behind-one-of-the-rifts-best-games/.
860
Chaim Gartenberg, Facebook Is Buying Giphy and Integrating It with Instagram, V
ERGE
(May 15, 2020), https://www.theverge.com/2020/5/15/21259965/facebook-giphy-gif-acquisition
-buy-instagram-integration-cost.
Spotify in the month after [Facebook] launched Open Graph.’’
848
At
one point, nearly all of Spotify’s growth originated from Facebook,
while Pinterest ‘‘grew to 10 million users faster than any stand-
alone site in the history of the Internet.’’
849
Conversely, interconnecting with the Facebook Platform also
gave the company the ability to prioritize access to its social
graph—effectively picking winners and losers online.
850
These tools
also gave Facebook advanced data insights into other companies’
growth and usage trends. For example, a daily report on metrics
for Facebook Login included daily and monthly active users for
companies interconnecting with Facebook, referral traffic, and daily
clicks, among other metrics. As this report noted, 8.3 million dis-
tinct sites used Facebook Connect on a monthly basis in March
2012.
851
Facebook was also able to exclude others from accessing
this data.
852
As the United Kingdom’s Competition and Markets
Authority observed, ‘‘the inability of smaller platforms and pub-
lishers to access user data creates a significant barrier to entry.’’
853
(b) Relevant Acquisitions
(i) Overview. Since its founding in 2004, Facebook has acquired
at least 63 companies.
854
The majority of these acquisitions have
involved software firms, such as Instagram, WhatsApp, Face.com,
Atlas, LiveWire, and Onavo.
855
Facebook has also acquired several
virtual reality and hardware companies, such as Oculus.
856
More
recently, the company has acquired several niche social apps,
857
a
blockchain platform,
858
Oculus game developers,
859
and a promi-
nent GIF-making and sharing company.
860
Facebook’s internal documents indicate that the company ac-
quired firms it viewed as competitive threats to protect and expand
its dominance in the social networking market. As discussed earlier
in this Report, Facebook’s senior executives described the com-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00130 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
125
861
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00045388
(Feb. 18, 2014), https://judiciary.house.gov/uploadedfiles/0004538800045389.pdf (‘‘[W]e are
going to spend 5–10% of our market cap every couple years to shore up our position .... I hate
the word ‘land grab’ but I think that is the best convincing argument and we should own that.’’).
Mr. Wehner is currently Facebook’s Chief Financial Officer. He replaced David Ebersman,
Facebook’s former Chief Financial Officer, in June 2014. David Cohen, Facebook CFO David
Ebersman Leaving Company; David Wehner to Assume Post June 1, A
D
W
EEK
(Apr. 23, 2014),
https://www.adweek.com/digital/cfo-david-ebersman-leaving-david-wehner/.
862
Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n Report at 81 (‘‘While any of these acquisitions
may not have amounted to a substantial lessening of competition, there appears to be a pattern
of Facebook acquiring businesses in related markets which may or may not evolve into potential
competitors, which has the effect of entrenching its market power.’’).
863
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00087590
(July 19, 2011) (on file with Comm.) (Valuation of Burbn, Inc. as of May 31, 2011).
864
Id.
865
MG Siegler, Instagram Launches with the Hope of Igniting Communication Through Im-
ages, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Oct. 6, 2010), https://techcrunch.com/2010/10/06/instagram-launch/. The
company received $500,000 in seed funding in March 2010 from Baseline Ventures and
Andreessen Horowitz. It later received $7 million in another round of financing in December
2010 primarily from Benchmark Capital and Baseline Ventures. Submission from Facebook, to
H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00101426 (Dec. 5, 2011) (on file with Comm.)
(Instagram Financial History and Projections).
866
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00106124
(Apr. 13, 2012) (on file with Comm.) (Instagram Chat Log); see also Matt Burns, Instagram’s
User Count Now at 40 Million, Saw 10 Million New Users in Last 10 Days, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Apr.
13, 2012), https://techcrunch.com/2012/04/13/instagrams-user-count-now-at-40-million-saw-
10-million-new-users-in-last-10-days/.
867
The transaction’s value was approximately $300 million in cash and roughly $700 million
in shares of Facebook at the time of the transaction. Due to changes in the company’s value
following the launch of its IPO, the final transaction value was worth about $300 million in cash
and $460 million in Facebook stock. See Facebook, Inc., Quarterly Report (Form 10–Q) 9 (Sept.
30, 2012), https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1326801/000132680112000006/fb-
9302012x10q.htm.
868
Facebook, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 5 (Dec. 31, 2012), https://www.sec.gov/
Archives/edgar/data/1326801/000132680113000003/fb-12312012x10k.htm.
869
Letter from April Tabor, Acting Sec’y, Fed. Trade Comm’n, to Thomas Barnett, Covington
& Burling LLP (Aug. 22, 2012), https://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/closingl
letters/facebook-inc./instagram-inc./120822barnettfacebookcltr.pdf.
pany’s mergers and acquisitions strategy in 2014 as a ‘‘land grab’’
to ‘‘shore up our position.’’
861
In 2012, Mr. Zuckerberg told
Facebook’s former Chief Financial Officer that the purpose of ac-
quiring nascent competitors like Instagram was to neutralize com-
petitive threats and to maintain Facebook’s position. Documents
show that when Facebook acquired WhatsApp, Mr. Zuckerberg and
other senior executives, as well as data scientists, viewed
WhatsApp as a potential threat to Facebook Messenger, as well as
an opportunity to further entrench Facebook’s dominance.
Facebook used critical acquisitions to increase the adoption of its
social graph and expand its reach in markets. Finally, Facebook’s
serial acquisitions reflect the company’s interest in purchasing
firms that had the potential to develop into rivals before they could
fully mature into strong competitive threats.
862
(ii) Instagram. Instagram was founded in February 2010 by
Kevin Systrom and Mike Krieger.
863
Originally launched as Burbn,
a location-sharing social app,
864
the company released Instagram
as a photo-sharing app for Apple iPhones in October 2010,
865
and
released its app in the Google Play Store on April 3, 2012.
866
On April 9, 2012, Facebook proposed its acquisition of Instagram
for approximately $1 billion.
867
Facebook formally acquired
Instagram in August 2012.
868
The Federal Trade Commission
(FTC) opened an investigation into the acquisition but closed it in
August 2012 without taking action.
869
According to the FTC, ‘‘Upon
further review of this matter, it now appears that no further action
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00131 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
126
870
Id.
871
Id.
872
See, e.g., Mike Isaac, Zuckerberg Plans to Integrate WhatsApp, Instagram and Facebook
Messenger, N.Y. T
IMES
(Jan. 25, 2019), https://www.nytimes.com/2019/01/25/technology/
facebook-instagram-whatsapp-messenger.html.
873
See, e.g., Makena Kelly, Facebook’s Messaging Merger Leaves Lawmakers Questioning the
Company’s Power, V
ERGE
(Jan. 28, 2019), https://www.theverge.com/2019/1/28/18200658/
facebook-messenger-instagram-whatsapp-google-congress-markey-blumenthal-schatz-william-barr-
doj-ftc.
874
Email from Former Instagram Employee (Oct. 4, 2020).
875
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00063220 to
–00063223 (Feb. 27, 2012) (on file with Comm.).
876
Id.
877
Id.
is warranted by the Commission at this time.’’
870
The letter added
that the FTC’s closing of the investigation ‘‘is not to be construed
as a determination that a violation may not have occurred .... The
Commission reserves the right to take such further action as the
public interest may require.’’
871
In the context of reports that Facebook was planning to integrate
Whatsapp, Instagram, and Facebook Messenger,
872
and concerns
about the company’s motives for doing so,
873
a former employee of
Instagram explained the ease with which Facebook and Instagram
came together—and could potentially be pulled apart. They ex-
plained:
Why can’t Facebook fork the backend of the product? Facebook makes an odd
argument that they use the same system. But you can just copy and paste code,
make a copy of the system, and give it to the new company. If you can put them
together, you can pull them apart. Facebook can always pull out the data that
Instagram would not need. They spent the last year pushing the two products
together, it just simply doesn’t make sense that they can’t work back to where
they were in 2019. It’s not like building a skyscraper and then suddenly needing
to knock the building down again. They can just roll back the changes they’ve
been making over the past year and you’d have two different apps again. It’s not
about the pipeline. It’s an intangible object. You can just copy and paste. Right
now, they have a switch inside the app. They could just change something from
true to false and it would work. It’s not building a skyscraper; it’s turning some-
thing on and off.
874
According to Facebook’s internal documents, Facebook acquired
Instagram to neutralize a nascent competitive threat. In 2012,
Mark Zuckerberg wrote to several Facebook executives citing con-
cerns that Instagram posed a risk to Facebook. In February 2012,
he said to David Ebersman, Facebook’s Chief Financial Officer,
that he had ‘‘been thinking about . . . how much [Facebook] should
be willing to pay to acquire mobile app companies like Instagram
. . . that are building networks that are competitive with our
own.’’
875
Mr. Zuckerberg told Mr. Ebersman that these ‘‘businesses
are nascent but the networks are established, the brands are al-
ready meaningful and if they grow to a large scale they could be
very disruptive to us.’’
876
In response, Mr. Ebersman asked Mr. Zuckerberg whether the
goals of the acquisition would be to: (1) neutralize a potential com-
petitor; (2) acquire talent; or (3) integrate Instagram’s product with
Facebook’s to improve its service.
877
Mr. Zuckerberg replied that a
purpose of the transaction would be to neutralize Instagram, say-
ing that the goals of the deal were ‘‘a combination of (1) and (3).’’
He explained:
One thing that may make (1) more reasonable here is that there are network
effects around social products and a finite number of different social mechanics
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00132 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
127
878
Id.
879
Id.
880
Id. (emphasis added).
881
Mr. Schroepfer was Facebook’s Vice President of Engineering at the time of the Instagram
acquisition. He was elevated to Chief Technology Officer in March 2013. See Tomio Geron,
Facebook Names Mike Schroepfer CTO, F
ORBES
(Mar. 15, 2013), https://www.forbes.com/sites/
tomiogeron/2013/03/15/facebook-names-mike-schroepfer-cto/#1a88880b20e3.
882
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00063184 to
–00063185 (Mar. 9, 2012), https://judiciary.house.gov/uploadedfiles/0006318000063197.pdf.
These documents are consistent with reporting. Following the acquisition, Gregor Hochmuth, an
Instagram engineer, was reportedly told by employees on the Facebook Camera team that ‘‘our
job was to kill you guys.’’ Following the acquisition, Instagram’s employees were also reportedly
told by Facebook’s growth team ‘‘Instagram wouldn’t get any help adding users unless they
could determine, through data, that the product wasn’t competitive with Facebook.’’ S
ARAH
F
RIER
, N
O
F
ILTER
90 (2020).
883
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00063180,
https://judiciary.house.gov/uploadedfiles/0006318 000063197.pdf.
884
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00063184 to –00063185, https://judiciary.house.gov/uploadedfiles/
0006318 000063197.pdf.
885
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00063319, https://judiciary.house.gov/uploadedfiles/00063316
00063321.pdf.
886
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00063319 to –00063320 (Apr. 5, 2012), https://judiciary.house.gov/
uploaded files/0006331600063321.pdf.
887
Id.
888
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00047340 (Apr. 6, 2012) (on file with Comm.).
to invent. Once someone wins at a specific mechanic, it’s difficult for others to
supplant them without doing something different. It’s possible someone beats
Instagram by building something that is better to the point that they get net-
work migration, but this is harder as long as Instagram keeps running as a
product.
878
Mr. Zuckerberg wrote that acquiring Instagram would allow
Facebook to integrate the product to improve its service. But, he
added, that ‘‘in reality we already know these companies’ social dy-
namics and will integrate them over the next 12–24 months any-
way.’’
879
He explained:
By a combination of (1) and (3), one way of looking at this is that what we’re
really buying is time. Even if some new competitors springs [sic] up, buying
Instagram, Path, Foursquare, etc. [sic] now will give us a year or more to inte-
grate their dynamics before anyone can get close to their scale again. Within
that time, if we incorporate the social mechanics they were using, those new
products won’t get much traction since we’ll already have their mechanics de-
ployed at scale.
880
In March 2012, Mr. Zuckerberg told Mike Schroepfer, Facebook’s
Chief Technology Officer,
881
that acquiring Instagram would pro-
vide the company with ‘‘[i]nsurance’’ for Facebook’s main prod-
uct.
882
Mr. Schroepfer agreed, responding that ‘‘not losing strategic
position in photos is worth a lot of money.’’
883
He added that the
‘‘biggest risk’’ would be if Facebook were to ‘‘kill’’ Instagram ‘‘by not
investing in the company and thereby opening a window for a new
entrant.’’
884
In a message to another Facebook employee on April 5, 2012, Mr.
Zuckerberg said that ‘‘Instagram can hurt us meaningfully without
becoming a huge business.’’
885
In contrast, he did not view other
smaller firms, such as Pinterest and Foursquare, as comparable
competitive threats.
886
As he noted, if these companies ‘‘become big
we’ll just regret not doing them .... Or we can buy them then, or
build them along the way.’’
887
In an all-hands meeting the fol-
lowing day, Mr. Zuckerberg responded to a question about
Instagram’s rapid growth by saying that ‘‘we need to dig ourselves
out of a hole.’’
888
He also told employees at the company that
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00133 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
128
889
Id.
890
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00067600 (Apr. 9, 2012), https://judiciary.house.gov/uploaded
files/0006760000067601.pdf.
891
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00063341 (Apr. 9, 2012), https://judiciary.house.gov/uploaded
files/0006334000063341.pdf.
892
CEO Hearing at 43 (question of Rep. Jerrold Nadler (D–NY), Chair, H. Comm. on the Ju-
diciary).
893
Id. at 44 (statement of Mark Zuckerberg, CEO, Facebook, Inc.).
894
Id.
895
Id. at 45 (question of Rep. Jerrold Nadler (D–NY), Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
896
Id. at 46 (statement of Mark Zuckerberg, CEO, Facebook, Inc.).
897
Id.
898
Id. (statement of the Rep. Jerrold Nadler (D–NY), Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary)
(‘‘Facebook, by Mr. Zuckerberg’s own admission and by the documents we have from the time,
Facebook saw Instagram as a threat that could potentially syphon business away from
Facebook. And so, rather than compete with it, Facebook bought it. This is exactly the type of
anticompetitive acquisition that the antitrust laws were designed to prevent. This should never
have happened in the first place. It should never have been permitted to happen, and it cannot
happen again.’’).
899
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00101426
(Dec. 5, 2011) (on file with Comm.) (Instagram Financial History and Projections).
900
Id.
901
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00101473 (Dec. 5, 2011) (Instagram Budget).
Instagram is ‘‘growing really quickly’’ and that it would be ‘‘tough
to dislodge them.’’
889
Following the announcement of the transaction, Mr. Zuckerberg
said internally that Facebook ‘‘can likely always just buy any com-
petitive startups,’’ and agreed with one of the company’s senior en-
gineers that Instagram was a ‘‘threat’’ to Facebook.
890
Mr.
Zuckerberg concluded that ‘‘[o]ne thing about startups though is
you can often acquire them.’’
891
At the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Judiciary Committee Chair
Jerrold Nadler (D–NY) asked Mr. Zuckerberg about his character-
ization of Instagram as a competitive threat prior to the acquisi-
tion.
892
In response, Mr. Zuckerberg said that Facebook has al-
ways viewed Instagram as ‘‘both a competitor and as a complement
to our services.’’
893
He added that at the time of the transaction,
Instagram was a competitor in mobile photos and camera apps.
894
Chair Nadler also asked that if this ‘‘was an illegal merger at the
time of the transaction, why shouldn’t Instagram now be broken off
into a separate company?’’
895
In response, Mr. Zuckerberg said
that ‘‘with hindsight, it probably looks obvious that Instagram
would have reached the scale that it has today.’’
896
But he elabo-
rated:
It was not a guarantee that Instagram was going to succeed. The acquisition has
done wildly well, largely because not just of the founders’ talent but because we
invested heavily in building up the infrastructure and promoting it and working
on security and working on a lot of things around this, and I think that this has
been an American success story.
897
This response, however, is not consistent with many of the docu-
ments Facebook provided to the Subcommittee.
898
Instagram was growing significantly at the time of the trans-
action. In December 2011, with only 13 employees, Instagram al-
ready had 14 million users.
899
Instagram’s internal financial his-
tory and projections noted that it did not plan to charge for its app
or for downloading filters due to its ‘‘rapid user growth’’ and ‘‘im-
plied network value.’’
900
Instagram’s internal market projections
showed the company growing to nearly 20 million users by January
2012 with a 22 percent monthly growth rate.
901
By March 31, 2012,
Instagram had 30.2 million users and a 17 percent user growth
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00134 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
129
902
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–0110268 (2012) (Instagram Growth and Projections).
903
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00106124 (Apr. 13, 2012) (Instagram Chat Log).
904
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00106131 (Apr. 30, 2012).
905
Facebook, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 5 (Dec. 31, 2012), https://www.sec.gov/
Archives/edgar/data/1326801/000132680113000003/fb-12312012x10k.htm.
906
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00110279
(Apr. 16, 2012) (on file with Comm.) (Instagram’s Growth Projections); see generally S
ARAH
F
RIER
, N
O
F
ILTER
(2020) (‘‘Every hour, Instagram seemed to grow faster. D’Angelo eventually
helped the company transition to renting server space from Amazon Web Services instead of
buying their own.’’).
907
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00110279
(Apr. 16, 2012) (on file with Comm.) (Instagram’s Growth Projections).
908
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00063184 to –00063185 (Mar. 9, 2012), https://judiciary
.house.gov/uploadedfiles/0006318000063197.pdf.
909
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–0110268 (2012) (on file with Comm.) (Instagram’s Growth Projec-
tions).
910
Id.
911
S
TEVEN
L
EVY
, F
ACEBOOK
: T
HE
I
NSIDE
S
TORY
317–18 (2020).
912
Id. at 319.
913
Letter from Reginald Brown & Jon Yarowsky to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Oct. 14,
2019), FB–AJC–ACAL–APP00003.
914
Id. Although WhatsApp originally charged a subscription fee after the first year of use,
it removed fees in January 2016. See Making WhatsApp Free and More Useful, W
HATS
A
PP
(Jan.
18, 2016), https://blog.whatsapp.com/making-whats-app-free-and-more-useful.
rate.
902
After releasing its app in the Google Play Store on April
3, 2012, Instagram added ten million users within ten days,
903
growing to nearly 50 million users by April 30, 2012,
904
and 100
million users by the time the acquisition closed in August 2012.
905
Instagram’s growth also appeared to be sustainable. In an email
between senior executives at both companies on April 16, 2012,
Instagram’s head of business operations said that Instagram had
not had difficulties with scaling or cloud storage availability, noting
that ‘‘[s]caling has been really easy’’ despite the need to ‘‘keep add-
ing machine capacity.’’
906
They also noted that user uptake on An-
droid devices exceeded the company’s expectations, but did not
raise concerns about their ability to scale in response to this de-
mand.
907
Facebook’s support of Instagram’s growth after acquiring it is
overstated. Before acquiring Instagram, Mr. Zuckerberg said that
Facebook should ‘‘invest a few more engineers in it’’ but let
Instagram ‘‘run relatively independently.’’
908
Prior to being ac-
quired, Instagram’s internal projections showed the company gain-
ing nearly 88 million users by January 2013,
909
and that its growth
trajectory would not be significantly affected by the transaction.
910
(iii) WhatsApp
(1) Overview. WhatsApp was founded in February 2009 by Jan
Koum and Brian Acton.
911
Originally designed to allow users to
provide temporary updates to their contacts,
912
WhatsApp is a
cross-platform messaging and calling service.
913
Unlike traditional
text and multimedia messages sent over a cellular network at the
time, WhatsApp messages and calls do not require a cellular con-
nection, and are transmitted by an internet connection.
914
A main
distinction between Facebook Messenger and WhatsApp is the net-
work that people are able to communicate with on each messaging
service. A Facebook user can only send messages to other Facebook
users on the Messenger app, whereas a WhatsApp user can send
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00135 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
130
915
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00042171
(2014) (on file with Comm.).
916
S
TEVEN
L
EVY
, F
ACEBOOK
: T
HE
I
NSIDE
S
TORY
320 (2020) (‘‘ ‘We were building a communica-
tion service,’ says Acton. ‘You pay forty bucks a month to Verizon for their service, I figured
a dollar a year was enough for a messaging service.’ ’’).
917
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00042157
(2014) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘To the best of WhatsApp’s knowledge, Threema is the only other
provider that has adopted a model based on usage fees. In contrast to WhatsApp’s subscription
model, users of Threema pay a one-time fee for a life-time service.’’).
918
Why We Don’t Sell Ads, W
HATS
A
PP
(June 18, 2012), https://blog.whatsapp.com/why-we-
don-t-sell-ads (‘‘Advertising has us chasing cars and clothes, working jobs we hate so we can
buy shit we don’t need.’’).
919
Privacy Notice, W
HATS
A
PP
(July 7, 2012), https://www.whatsapp.com/legal?doc=privacy-
policy&version=20120707.
920
Id.
921
The transaction included $4 billion in cash and approximately $12 billion of Facebook
shares. Facebook to Acquire WhatsApp, F
ACEBOOK
(Feb. 19, 2014), https://about.fb.com/news/
2014/02/facebook-to-acquire-whatsapp/. The final value of WhatsApp exceeded $21 billion due
to changes in the value of Facebook’s stock during the transaction and due to the addition of
granting $3 billion in Facebook shares following the closing of the transaction. Sarah Frier,
Facebook $22 Billion WhatsApp Deal Buys $10 Million in Sales, B
LOOMBERG
(Oct. 29, 2014),
https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2014-10-28/facebook-s-22-billion-whatsapp-deal-
buys-10-million-in-sales.
922
Facebook, W
HATS
A
PP
(Feb. 19, 2014), https://blog.whatsapp.com/facebook (‘‘Here’s what
will change for you, our users: Nothing.’’).
923
Jessica Guynn, Mark Zuckerberg: WhatsApp Worth Even More than $19 Billion, L.A.
T
IMES
(Feb. 24, 2014), https://www.latimes.com/business/la-xpm-2014-feb-24-la-fi-tn-mark-
zuckerberg-whatsapp-worth-even-more-than-19-billion-20140224-story.html.
messages to other people based on contacts on their mobile de-
vice.
915
Until 2016, WhatsApp monetized its service through subscrip-
tions for a nominal fee after the first year of use.
916
Around that
time, WhatsApp was the only messaging app that competed using
this business model.
917
Importantly, WhatsApp’s founders strongly
opposed an advertisement-based business model. In June 2012,
they wrote that ‘‘when advertising is involved you the user are the
product,’’ explaining:
Advertising isn’t just the disruption of aesthetics, the insults to your intelligence
and the interruption of your train of thought. At every company that sells ads,
a significant portion of their engineering team spends their day tuning data min-
ing, writing better code to collect all your personal data, upgrading the servers
that hold all the data and making sure it’s all being logged and collated and
sliced and packaged and shipped out.
918
WhatsApp also maintained robust privacy policies. In its June 2012
privacy policy, WhatsApp stated that it does not collect names,
emails, location data, or the contents of messages sent through
WhatsApp.
919
According to its policy, ‘‘WhatsApp is currently ad-
free and we hope to keep it that way forever.’’
920
(2) Acquisition Review. On February 19, 2014, Facebook an-
nounced its proposed acquisition of WhatsApp for approximately
$16 billion at the time of the announcement.
921
Following the
transaction, WhatsApp’s cofounder wrote that the company would
‘‘remain autonomous and operate independently’’ from Facebook,
and that ‘‘nothing’’ will change for users because there ‘‘would have
been no partnership between our two companies if we had to com-
promise on the core principles that will always define our company,
our vision and our product.’’
922
Mr. Zuckerberg said that ‘‘[w]e are
absolutely not going to change plans around WhatsApp and the
way it uses user data.’’
923
The Federal Trade Commission opened an initial investigation
into the proposed transaction on March 13, 2014. On April 10,
2014, the FTC’s Director of the Bureau of Consumer Protection
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00136 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
131
924
Letter from Jessica Rich, Dir., Bureau of Consumer Prot., Fed. Trade Comm’n, to Erin
Egan, Chief Priv. Officer, Facebook, Inc., & Anne Hoge, Gen. Couns., WhatsApp, 1–2 (Apr. 10,
2014), https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/publiclstatements/297701/140410facebook
whatappltr.pdf.
925
Facebook gave notice of the proposed transaction to the European Commission on August
29, 2014. Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Mergers: Commission Approves Acquisition of WhatsApp
by Facebook (Oct. 3, 2014), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/IPl14l
1088.
926
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00042161 (on
file with Comm.).
927
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00042160.
928
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00042173.
929
Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Mergers: Commission Approves Acquisition of WhatsApp by
Facebook (Oct. 3, 2014), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/IPl14l1088.
930
Id.
931
Case COMP/M.7217, Facebook/WhatsApp, Eur. Comm’n Decision C(2014) 7239, ¶ 52 (Oct.
3, 2014), https://ec.europa.eu/competition/mergers/cases/decisions/m7217l20141003l20310
l3962132lEN.pdf.
932
Id. 54.
sent a letter advising the companies that WhatsApp ‘‘must con-
tinue to honor’’ its privacy data security commitments to its users,
and that ‘‘a failure to keep promises made about privacy con-
stitutes a deceptive practice under section 5 of the FTC Act.’’
924
The Commission did not initiate a full-phase investigation into the
acquisition.
In September 2014, the European Commission initiated a review
of Facebook’s proposed acquisition of WhatsApp.
925
At the time of
the transaction, Facebook calculated that the combined share of
Facebook Messenger and WhatsApp in February 2014 was approxi-
mately 36 percent of the European Economic Area (EEA) mar-
ket.
926
In a filing in support of the transaction, Facebook told the
European Commission that multi-homing—the use of multiple apps
with similar features—was a key characteristic of the messaging
market, saying that ‘‘approximately 70% of consumers use at least
two, and 43% use at least three, communications apps in par-
allel.’’
927
Facebook characterized the WhatsApp product market as
being distinct from the social networking market because
WhatsApp ‘‘does not offer social features,’’ and represented that it
had ‘‘no plans to make changes to WhatsApp’s current strategy’’
after closing the proposed acquisition.
928
On October 3, 2014, the European Commission approved the pro-
posed transaction, finding that ‘‘Facebook Messenger and
WhatsApp are not close competitors and that consumers would con-
tinue to have a wide choice of alternative consumer communica-
tions apps after the transaction.’’
929
Although the European Com-
mission noted that the messaging apps are characterized by net-
work effects, it concluded that Facebook would ‘‘continue to face
sufficient competition after the merger.’’
930
The Commission ac-
knowledged that there is overlap between social networking and
messaging apps. As it noted, the distinction between these apps is
‘‘becoming blurred and each of these services adopts traditional
functionalities of the other.’’
931
However, the Commission con-
cluded that social networking services generally provide more so-
cial features than messaging apps—such as commenting on or ‘‘lik-
ing’’ other users’ posts and photos—whereas messaging apps had
more limited functionality that is focused on real-time communica-
tion.
932
In 2016, the European Commission fined Facebook after it con-
cluded that Facebook provided ‘‘incorrect or misleading informa-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00137 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
132
933
Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Mergers: Commission Fines Facebook Ö110 Million for Pro-
viding Misleading Information About WhatsApp Takeover (May 18, 2017), https://ec.europa.eu/
commission/presscorner/detail/en/IPl17l1369.
934
Id.
935
Id.
936
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00045364
(Feb. 4, 2014) (on file with Comm.).
937
Id.
938
See, e.g., id.
939
Id.
940
Id.
941
Id.
942
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00045363.
943
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00045388
(Feb. 18, 2014), https://judiciary.house.gov/uploadedfiles/0004538800045389.pdf.
944
Id.
945
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00045379 to –00045387 (Feb. 19, 2014) (on file with Comm.).
tion’’ during the Commission’s review of the transaction.
933
In its
Statement of Objections to Facebook, the Commission concluded
that Facebook provided misleading evidence on whether the com-
pany could match its users’ accounts with those of WhatsApp’s
users.
934
In August 2016, WhatsApp had updated its policies to
allow the linking of Facebook user identities with WhatsApp user
phone numbers.
935
As discussed below, Facebook intended to create
this functionality at the time of the transaction.
936
Documents obtained by the Subcommittee indicate that Facebook
acquired WhatsApp to expand its dominance. Prior to acquiring
WhatsApp, Facebook viewed the acquisition as providing an oppor-
tunity to expand its reach in countries with intermediate levels of
penetration.
937
Facebook’s internal documents at the time of the
transaction reveal that WhatsApp had already tipped markets in
its favor where it had high penetration.
938
In an internal email to Facebook’s management team, Facebook
Director of Growth Javier Olivan wrote that WhatsApp had higher
levels of reach and usage than Facebook in countries that it had
penetrated. For example, based on Facebook’s internal data,
WhatsApp reached 99.9 percent of the smartphone population in
Spain, or as Mr. Olivan described it, ‘‘literally everyone.’’
939
By
purchasing WhatsApp, Mr. Olivan suggested that they could ‘‘grow
Facebook even further’’ by exposing new users to Facebook.
940
Ad-
ditionally, by bundling free services with WhatsApp and Facebook’s
other services, the transaction could serve as another mechanism
to expand Facebook’s reach among WhatsApp users.
941
Mr.
Zuckerberg responded supportively, saying that ‘‘I really agree with
this analysis.’’
942
In an email to David Ebersman, Facebook’s Chief Financial Offi-
cer, Mr. Olivan wrote that WhatsApp’s ‘‘reach amongst smartphone
users is actually bigger than ours .... [W]e have close to 100%
overlap, our user-base being a subset of theirs.’’
943
He explained
that, ‘‘in markets where they do well, they literally reach 100% of
smartphone users—which is a big part of the population.’’
944
In
the company’s internal documents describing the transaction ra-
tionale, there was a heavy emphasis on WhatsApp’s growth and
usage—450 million users, a clear path to a billion users, and add-
ing one million new users every day with no marketing—and ex-
panding Facebook’s social graph to phones.
945
Prior to the acquisi-
tion, Mr. Zuckerberg had requested a list of all mobile apps with
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00138 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
133
946
Id.
947
Id.
948
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00045388 (Feb. 18, 2014), https://judiciary.house.gov/uploaded
files/0004538800045389.pdf.
949
Id.
950
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00046826 to –00046834 (Dec. 13, 2013) (on file with Comm.).
951
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00014564 to –00014574 (Mar. 27, 2014).
952
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00014575.
more than 100 million daily and monthly active users globally.
946
Facebook’s data showed that WhatsApp had the second most daily
active users and fourth most monthly active users of any free-
standing mobile app.
947
Finally, a week after announcing the transaction, David Wehner,
then-Vice President of Corporate Finance and Business Planning at
Facebook, said to Mr. Ebersman that ‘‘we are going to spend 5–10%
of our market cap every couple years to shore up our position.’’
948
Mr. Wehner said that ‘‘I hate the word ‘land grab’ but I think that
is the best convincing argument and we should own that.’’
949
Other documents indicate that Facebook viewed WhatsApp as a
maverick competitor. In December 2013, Mr. Zuckerberg sent an
email to Facebook’s management team on competitive issues facing
the company. In this email, he called attention to a feature that
WhatsApp had implemented on its platform, and warned that
Facebook should move quickly:
I want to call out two competitive near term issues we face. The first is
WhatsApp adding a feature like this for public figures .... If the space is going
to move in this direction, being the leader and establishing the brand and net-
work effects matters a lot. This alone should encourage us to consider this soon
.... When the world shifts like this, being first is how you build a brand and
network effect. We have an opportunity to do this at scale, but that opportunity
won’t last forever. I doubt we even have a year before WhatsApp starts moving
in this direction.
950
Facebook’s documents also indicate that the company monitored
WhatsApp closely to determine whether it was a threat to the Mes-
senger app. Prior to consummating the merger, Facebook’s data sci-
entists used Onavo data to model WhatsApp’s engagement and
reach to determine whether it was ‘‘killing Facebook Mes-
senger,’’
951
as well as how its usage trends compared to Snap-
chat.
952
(c) Conduct. In addition to protecting and expanding its domi-
nance by acquiring firms that Facebook identified as competitive
threats over the past decade, Facebook abused its monopoly power
to harm competition in the social networking market. Facebook
used its data advantage to create superior market intelligence to
identify nascent competitive threats and then acquire, copy, or kill
these firms. Once dominant, Facebook selectively enforced its plat-
form policies based on whether it perceived other companies as
competitive threats. In doing so, it advantaged its own services
while weakening other firms.
(i) Facebook’s Use of Non-Public Data to Identify Competitive
Threats. Prior to Facebook’s acquisition of Instagram, Facebook
used internal data to track the growth of Instagram and other pop-
ular apps. While this data was probative for companies that inter-
connected with Facebook through Open Graph, it was incomplete
for studying mobile app usage trends across the entire mobile eco-
system. In April 2012, Facebook’s Director of Growth Javier Olivan
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00139 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
134
953
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00068928 (Apr. 3, 2012).
954
Id.
955
Id.
956
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00068929.
957
Hayley Tsukayama, Facebook Acquires Israeli Start-up Onavo to Bolster Data Compression
and Mobile Tech, W
ASH
. P
OST
(Oct. 14, 2013), https://blogs.wsj.com/digits/2013/10/14/
facebook-deal-gives-it-office-in-israel/.
958
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00072168 (Oct.
9, 2013) (on file with Comm.).
959
Id.
960
Betsy Morris & Deepa Seetharaman, The New Copycats: How Facebook Squashes Competi-
tion from Startups, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (Aug. 9, 2017), https://www.wsj.com/articles/the-new-copycats-
how-facebook-squashes-competition-from-startups-1502293444.
961
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00045412 to
–00045414 (Feb. 16, 2014), https://judiciary.house.gov/uploadedfiles/0004541200045414.pdf.
emailed Mr. Zuckerberg and Facebook Chief Product Officer Chris
Cox about improving Facebook’s ‘‘competitive research.’’
953
He said
that ‘‘getting our data in great shape is going to require effort.’’
954
Although the company had made ‘‘some good progress’’ using data
from Comscore, a data analytics and measurement firm, Mr.
Olivan said that, with a significant investment, Facebook could
build its own custom panel for mobile data that would ‘‘allow us
to get 10× better at understanding’’ the mobile ecosystem:
I keep seeing the same suspects (instagram, pinterest, . . . [sic] both on our com-
petitive radar/platform strategy as wins .... I think having the exact data about
their users [sic] engagement, value they derive from [Facebook] . . . would help
us make more bold decisions on whether they are friends or foes. Back to your
thread about ‘‘copying’’ vs. ‘‘innovating’’ we could also use this info to inspire our
next moves.
955
Mr. Zuckerberg responded: ‘‘Yeah, let’s do it. We can find some
time periodically during my weekly reviews to go over this
stuff.’’
956
A year later, on October 14, 2013, Facebook acquired Onavo, a
virtual private network (VPN), for $115 million and other consider-
ation.
957
In an email to Facebook’s board, Facebook’s Vice Presi-
dent and Deputy General Counsel said the purpose of the acquisi-
tion was to ‘‘enhance our analytics related to cross-app user en-
gagement data, as well as user behavior and market trends, and
also to improve advertising effectiveness through demand data and
audience targeting in the long term.’’
958
Importantly, Facebook
planned to place the incoming Onavo employees, including its co-
founder, Guy Rosen, under Facebook’s Growth team reporting to
Javier Olivan.
959
Facebook’s acquisition of Onavo provided the company with the
ability to track potential competitors through non-public, real-time
data about engagement, usage, and how much time people spend
on apps. Following this acquisition, Facebook used Onavo data as
an ‘‘early bird warning system,’’
960
identifying fast-growing apps
that could potentially threaten Facebook’s market position or en-
able it to protect and expand its dominance. For instance, days
prior to Facebook’s acquisition of WhatsApp in 2014, Facebook sen-
ior executives provided Mark Zuckerberg with a list of all mobile
apps with greater than 90 million monthly active users—
WhatsApp, one of the only top mobile apps not owned at the time
by either Facebook or Google, was fourth on the list.
961
In August 2018, Apple removed Onavo from its app store fol-
lowing reporting that Facebook was using the app to track users
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00140 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
135
962
Deepa Seetharaman, Facebook Removes Data-Security App from Apple Store, W
ALL
S
T
. J.
(Aug. 22, 2018), https://www.wsj.com/articles/facebook-to-remove-data-security-app-from-apple-
store-1534975340.
963
Taylor Hatmaker, Apple Removed Facebook’s Onavo from the App Store for Gatherine App
Data, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Aug. 22, 2018), https://techcrunch.com/2018/08/22/apple-facebook-
onavo/.
964
Josh Constine, Facebook Pays Teens to Install VPN that Spies on Them, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Jan. 29, 2019), https://techcrunch.com/2019/01/29/facebook-project-atlas/; Josh Constine,
Apple Bans Facebook’s Research App that Paid Users for Data, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Jan. 30, 2019),
https://techcrunch.com/2019/01/30/apple-bans-facebook-vpn/.
965
Kurt Wagner & Sarah Frier, Facebook Buys Animated Image Library Giphy for $400 Mil-
lion, B
LOOMBERG
(May 15, 2020), https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2020-05-15/
facebook-buys-animated-image-library-giphy-to-boost-messaging; see, e.g., Vivek Karuturi
(@VivekxK), T
WITTER
(May 15, 2020, 11:43 a.m.), https://twitter.com/VivekxK/status/12613212
01210626048.
966
Owen Williams, How Facebook Could Use Giphy to Collect Your Data, O
NEZERO
(May 15,
2020), https://onezero.medium.com/how-facebook-could-use-giphy-to-collect-your-data-70824
aa2647b.
967
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00053511 to
–00053516 (Mar. 30, 2012) (on file with Comm.).
968
Id.
and other apps.
962
An Apple spokesperson said the company in-
tended to make ‘‘it explicitly clear that apps should not collect in-
formation about which other apps are installed on a user’s device
for the purposes of analytics or advertising/marketing and must
make it clear what user data will be collected and how it will be
used.’’
963
In January 2019, Apple removed Facebook’s functional
successor to Onavo, the Facebook Research app, following reports
by TechCrunch that Facebook paid ‘‘teenagers and adults to
download the Research app and give it root access to network traf-
fic in what may be a violation of Apple policy so the social network
can decrypt and analyze their phone activity.’’
964
Most recently, Facebook acquired Giphy, a platform for sharing
GIFs online and through messaging apps, for $400 million in May
2020.
965
As several reporters have noted, this transaction would
give Facebook competitive insights into other messaging apps. One
commenter said, ‘‘While you may successfully block trackers like
the Facebook ad pixel following you around online, or even delete
your Facebook account, the majority of us wouldn’t suspect we’re
being monitored when we’re sending funny images to friends.’’
966
(ii) Facebook’s Strategy to Acquire, Copy, or Kill Competitors.
Facebook’s internal documents indicate that once it identified a
competitive threat, it attempted to buy or crush them by cloning
their product features or foreclosing them from Facebook’s social
graph. Facebook took these steps to harm competitors and insulate
Facebook from competition, not just to grow or offer better products
and services.
In a March 2012 email to other senior executives at Facebook,
Mr. Zuckerberg wrote that cloning other apps could help Facebook
move faster by ‘‘building out more of the social use cases ourselves
and prevent our competitors from getting footholds.’’
967
Other sen-
ior employees at Facebook agreed with this strategy. Sheryl
Sandberg, Facebook’s Chief Operating Officer, said that ‘‘it is better
to do more and move faster, especially if that means you don’t have
competitors build products that takes some of our users.’’ Sam
Lessin, Facebook’s Product Management Director, added, ‘‘I would
love to be far more aggressive and nimble in copying competitors
.... Let’s ‘copy’ (aka super-set) Pinterest!’’
968
Another senior execu-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00141 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
136
969
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00067549 (Apr. 3, 2012).
970
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00047340 (Apr. 6, 2012).
971
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00063367 (Jan. 26, 2012), https://judiciary.house.gov/uploaded
files/0006336700063373.pdf.
972
Josh Constine, FB Launches Facebook Camera—An Instagram-Style Photo Filtering, Shar-
ing, Viewing iOS App, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(May 24, 2012), https://techcrunch.com/2012/05/24/
facebook-camera/.
973
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00091648 to
–00091650 (Mar. 20, 2012) (on file with Comm.).
974
Id.
975
Id.
976
Id. at FB–AJC–ACAL–0010438 (Feb. 13, 2012), https://judiciary.house.gov/uploaded
files/0010143800101441.pdf.
977
Id.
tive responded, ‘‘I’ve been thinking about why we haven’t moved
faster on Roger and Snap . . . I’m increasingly concerned as I watch
startups siphon our graph and create awesome new experiences
faster than we can.’’
969
Prior to its acquisition of Instagram in 2012, Facebook’s senior
executives had identified Instagram as a growing threat. Mr.
Zuckerberg told employees at an internal meeting that the ‘‘bad
news is that [Instagram is] growing really quickly, they have a lot
of momentum, and it’s going to be tough to dislodge them.’’
970
One
engineer wrote in an internal company chat that ‘‘Instagram is eat-
ing our lunch. We should’ve owned this space but we’re already los-
ing quite badly.’’
971
In response, another engineer asked, ‘‘Isn’t
that why we’re building an Instagram clone?’’ referencing
Facebook’s development of Facebook Camera, a standalone photo
app.
972
During negotiations to acquire Instagram, Mr. Zuckerberg ref-
erenced Facebook’s development of a similar app to Kevin Systrom,
Instagram’s Chief Executive Officer.
973
In messages between Mr.
Zuckerberg and Mr. Systrom, Mr. Systrom said that it was difficult
to evaluate the transaction independently of reports that Facebook
was developing a similar product. He told Mr. Zuckerberg that he
‘‘wouldn’t feel nearly as strongly [about the acquisition] if inde-
pendently you weren’t building a mobile photos app that makes
people choose which engine to use.’’
974
Similarly, Mr. Zuckerberg
suggested that refusing to enter into a partnership with Facebook,
including an acquisition, would have consequences for Instagram,
referencing the product Facebook was developing at the time:
At some point soon, you’ll need to figure out how you actually want to work with
us. This can be an acquisition, through a close relationship with Open Graph,
through an arms length relationship using our traditional APIs, or perhaps not
at all .... Of course, at the same time we’re developing our own photos strategy,
so how we engage now will determine how much we’re partners vs. competitors
down the line—and I’d like to make sure we decide that thoughtfully as well.
975
In an earlier conversation with Matt Cohler, an Instagram inves-
tor and former senior Facebook adviser, Mr. Systrom asked wheth-
er Mr. Zuckerberg would ‘‘go into destroy mode if I say no’’ to being
acquired, saying that the companies ‘‘have overlap in features.’’
976
Mr. Cohler responded ‘‘probably’’ and that Mr. Zuckerberg would
‘‘conclude that it’s best to crush [I]nstagram.’’
977
Facebook’s approach towards rival social networking app
Snapchat is another case study in how Facebook enters ‘‘destroy
mode’’ when its market position is threatened. In 2013, as the com-
pany was growing rapidly, Snapchat cofounder Evan Spiegel
turned down an offer from Mr. Zuckerberg to acquire the company
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00142 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
137
978
Evelyn Rusli & Douglas MacMillan, Messaging Service Snapchat Spurned $3 Billion
Facebook Bid, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (Nov. 13, 2013), https://www.wsj.com/articles/messaging-service-
snapchat-spurned-facebook-bid-1384376628.
979
Casey Newton, Instagram’s New Stories Are a Near-Perfect Copy of Snapchat Stories,
V
ERGE
(Aug. 2, 2016), https://www.theverge.com/2016/8/2/12348354/instagram-stories-
announced-snapchat-kevin-systrom-interview.
980
Kaya Yurieff, Instagram’s Snapchat Clone Is More Popular than Snapchat, CNN B
US
.
(Apr. 13, 2017), https://money.cnn.com/2017/04/13/technology/instagram-stories-snapchat/
index .html.
981
Id.
982
Josh Constine, Instagram on Copying Snapchat: ‘‘This Is the Way the Tech Industry
Works,’’ T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(May 16, 2017), https://techcrunch.com/2017/05/16/to-clone-or-not-to-
clone/.
983
Betsy Morris & Deepa Seetharaman, The New Copycats: How Facebook Squashes Competi-
tion from Startups, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (Aug. 9, 2017), https://www.wsj.com/articles/the-new-copycats-
how-facebook-squashes-competition-from-startups-1502293444.
984
Id.
985
Id.
986
Mansoor Iqbal, Houseparty Revenue and Usage Statistics (2020), B
US
.
OF
A
PPS
(June 23,
2020), https://www.businessofapps.com/data/houseparty-statistics/.
987
CEO Hearing at 147 (question of Rep. Henry C. ‘‘Hank’’ Johnson, Jr. (D–GA), Chair,
Subcomm. on Courts & Intell. Prop., H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
988
Id. at 148 (statement of Mark Zuckerberg, CEO, Facebook, Inc.).
for $3 billion.
978
Thereafter, Instagram—owned by Facebook—in-
troduced the Instagram Stories feature, which allows users to post
content that is available for only 24 hours, and which was ‘‘nearly
identical to the central feed in Snapchat, which [was] also called
Stories.’’
979
Less than a year after its introduction, Instagram Stories had
more daily active users (200 million) than Snapchat Stories (161
million).
980
By 2018, Instagram Stories had doubled the number of
Snapchat Stories daily users.
981
When discussing Instagram’s deci-
sion to clone the Snapchat feature, Instagram VP of Product Kevin
Weil remarked: ‘‘This is the way the tech industry works.’’
982
In another example, Facebook executives approached
Houseparty, a social networking app,
983
about a potential acquisi-
tion. Houseparty’s founders turned down Facebook’s offer, and re-
leased the product they referred to as ‘‘the internet’s living
room.’’
984
Shortly thereafter, Facebook announced that its Mes-
senger app would become a ‘‘virtual living room.’’
985
Houseparty’s
active user base fell by half between 2017 and 2018.
986
At the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Representative Henry C.
‘‘Hank’’ Johnson, Jr. (D–GA) asked Mr. Zuckerberg about
Facebook’s use of data to identify competitive threats. Representa-
tive Johnson noted that ‘‘over nearly a decade, Mr. Zuckerberg, you
led a sustained effort to surveil smaller competitors to benefit
Facebook .... These were steps taken to abuse data, to harm com-
petitors, and to shield Facebook from competition.’’
987
He asked
Mr. Zuckerberg whether Facebook used Onavo data to purchase
WhatsApp. Mr. Zuckerberg responded:
I think every company engages in research to understand what their customers
are enjoying so they can learn and make their products better. And that’s what
we were trying to do. That is what our analytics team was doing. And I think,
in general, that allowed us to make our services better for people to be able to
connect in a whole lot of different ways, which is our goal .... [Onavo] was one
of the signals that we had about WhatsApp’s trajectory, but we didn’t need it.
Without a doubt, it was pretty clear that WhatsApp was a great product.
988
(iii) Facebook Weaponized Access to Its Platform. Internal com-
munications by Facebook’s senior executives and interviews with
former employees at the company indicate that Facebook selec-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00143 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
138
989
David Kirkpatrick, Facebook’s Plan to Hook up the World, CNN M
ONEY
(May 29, 2007),
https://money.cnn.com/2007/05/24/technology/facebook.fortune/.
990
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FBlFTClCIDl00072185–88
(Feb. 14, 2008) (on file with Comm.).
991
Id. at FBlFTClCIDl00072020–23 (Feb. 14, 2013).
992
Id. (emphasis added).
993
Id. at FBlFTClCIDl0008058182 (Sept. 15, 2012).
tively enforced its platform policies based on whether it perceived
other companies as competitive threats.
Facebook developed the Facebook Platform to connect other ap-
plications to Facebook’s social graph. In an interview in 2007, Mr.
Zuckerberg described the goals of the Facebook Platform as making
‘‘Facebook into something of an operating system so you can run
full applications.’’
989
A year later, in an email to senior executives
at Facebook, Mr. Zuckerberg described Facebook Platform as key
to the company’s long term success:
Platform is key to our strategy because we believe that there will be a lot of dif-
ferent social applications and ways that people communicate and share informa-
tion, and we believe we can’t develop all of them ourselves. Therefore, even
though it’s a challenge for us to get this right, it’s important for us to focus on
it because the company that defines this social platform will be in the best posi-
tion to offer the most good ways for people to communicate and succeed in the
long term.
990
Over the next few years, Facebook recognized that access to its so-
cial graph provided other applications with a tool for significant
growth. In exchange, Facebook hosted content that kept users en-
gaged on its social graph, and considered other ways to monetize
this relationship, such as through revenue sharing or advertise-
ments.
By 2012, however, Facebook’s senior executives realized that
apps could use the Facebook Platform to build products that were
competitive with Facebook and ‘‘siphon our users.’’
991
Mike Vernal,
Facebook’s Vice President of Product and Engineer, described this
dynamic to Doug Purdy, Facebook’s Director of Product Manage-
ment:
When we started Facebook Platform, we were small and wanted to make sure
we were an essential part of the fabric of the Internet. We’ve done that—we’re
now the biggest service on earth. When we were small, apps helped drive our
ubiquity. Now that we are big, (many) apps are looking to siphon off our users
to competitive services. We need to be more thoughtful about what integrations
we allow and we need to make sure that we have sustainable, long-term value
exchanges.
992
In another conversation between Sam Lessin, Facebook’s Direc-
tor of Product Engagement, and other executives, Facebook’s senior
employees agreed that competitive apps used Facebook Platform to
‘‘steal our engagement’’ and ‘‘could be viewed as replacing Facebook
functionality,’’ adding that they planned to raise this concern with
Mr. Zuckerberg.
993
Mr. Lessin raised these concerns with Mr.
Zuckerberg in October 2012. In response, Mr. Zuckerberg agreed
with this conclusion:
Reading your responses, I do think you are right .... I would be more com-
fortable with competition if I thought we knew better how to leverage our scale
asset (and if scale weren’t becoming cheaper and cheaper to achieve every day).
What I think is that we should effectively not be helping our competitors more/
much more than how they could get help from elsewhere in the market. They
can acquire users in ways other than us so obviously we shouldn’t be failing to
take their money when they will just give it to someone else and get the same
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00144 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
139
994
Id. at FBlFTClCIDl00491746–63 (Oct. 27, 2012) (emphasis added); see also Elena
Botella, Facebook Earns $132.80 from Your Data per Year, S
LATE
(Nov. 15, 2019), https://
slate.com/technology/2019/11/facebook-six4three-pikinis-lawsuit-emails-data.html.
995
Olivia Solon & Cyrus Farivar, Mark Zuckerberg Leveraged Facebook User Data to Fight
Rivals and Help Friends, Leaked Documents Show, NBC N
EWS
(Apr. 16, 2019), https://
www.nbcnews.com/tech/social-media/mark-zuckerberg-leveraged-facebook-user-data-fight-rivals-
help-friends-n994706.
996
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 569 (response to Questions for the Record
of Matt Perault, Dir. of Pub. Pol’y, Facebook, Inc.).
997
Rachel Kraus, Mark Zuckerberg Gave the Order to Kneecap Vine, Emails Show, M
ASHABLE
(Dec. 5, 2018), https://mashable.com/article/mark-zuckerberg-helped-thwart-vine/.
998
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 141.
999
Casey Newton, Why Vine Died, V
ERGE
(Oct. 28, 2016), https://www.theverge.com/2016/
10/28/13456208/why-vine-died-twitter-shutdown.
1000
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 19 (statement of Matt Perault, Dir. of Pub.
Pol’y, Facebook, Inc.).
1001
Rob Price, Facebook Is Reviewing Hundreds of Its Official ‘‘Facebook Marketing Partners’’
over Instagram Data-Scraping Issues, B
US
. I
NSIDER
(Aug. 23, 2019), https://www.business
insider.com/facebook-review-all-marketing-partners-instagram-data-scraping-2019-8.
1002
Interview with Damien Mahoney, CEO, Stackla (Apr. 14, 2020).
outcome. I do, however, again think that we want as much control here as we
can get. I agree we shouldn’t help our competitors whenever possible. I think the
right solution here is to just be a lot stricter about enforcing our policies and iden-
tifying companies as competitors.
994
Recognizing that some social apps had grown too popular and could
compete with Facebook’s family of products, Facebook cut off their
access to Facebook’s social graph.
995
In 2013, Facebook claimed that the short-form video app Vine, a
video-sharing app that Twitter acquired in 2012, ‘‘replicated
Facebook’s core News Feed functionality.’’
996
In response,
Facebook cut off Vine’s access to Facebook APIs.
997
In doing so,
‘‘Facebook was able to degrade consumers’ experience of Vine and
reduce the platform’s competitive threat.’’
998
Twitter shut down
Vine in 2016.
999
Facebook’s actions in the wake of the Cambridge Analytica scan-
dal raise concerns about pretextual anticompetitive enforcement in
the name of privacy. In 2019, Facebook cut off marketing firm
Stackla’s access to its APIs ‘‘due to data scraping, which violates
[Facebook’s] policies.’’
1000
Damien Mahoney, the Chief Executive
Officer of Stackla, denied these allegations.
1001
In an interview
with the Subcommittee, Mr. Mahoney explained the economic harm
of the company’s foreclosure from the Facebook Platform:
What we went through with Facebook was company altering, and if not for the
resolve of our team and board, would have destroyed it. We had to lay off half
our team. We made huge investments in the company in the previous 12 months,
having raised $4m to increase our sales capacity by 160% and other functions
in the business, then this occurred. It was a critical blow that almost forced us
to close the doors. We were approaching 75 employees and 30% growth after 8
long years of toil. Now we have 26 employees, declining revenue and ongoing col-
lateral damage that we continue to sink time and money into. While we try and
stabilize, and get the company back to a position of growth, it’s a long way off
as we continue, to this very day, [to] deal with the after-effects. The fact this
all resulted from a single erroneous and factually incorrect news article, com-
bined with zero consultation from Facebook prior to their damaging actions, re-
mains baffling and completely unfair.
1002
Around that time, Facebook became aware of MessageMe, a fast-
growing app that used Facebook graph data to support its ‘‘Find
Friends’’ feature. Recognizing that MessageMe could compete with
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00145 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
140
1003
Olivia Solon & Cyrus Farivar, Mark Zuckerberg Leveraged Facebook User Data to Fight
Rivals and Help Friends, Leaked Documents Show, NBC N
EWS
(Apr. 16, 2019), https://
www.nbcnews.com/tech/social-media/mark-zuckerberg-leveraged-facebook-user-data-fight-rivals-
help-friends-n994706.
1004
Interview with Former Facebook Employee (Jan. 14, 2020).
1005
Submission from Former Facebook Employee, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Apr. 2,
2020) (on file with Comm.).
1006
Id.
1007
Olivia Solon & Cyrus Farivar, Mark Zuckerberg Leveraged Facebook User Data to Fight
Rivals and Help Friends, Leaked Documents Show, NBC N
EWS
(Apr. 16, 2019), https://www
.nbcnews.com/tech/social-media/mark-zuckerberg-leveraged-facebook-user-data-fight-rivals-help-
friends-n994706.
1008
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 569 (response to Questions for the Record
of Matt Perault, Dir. of Pub. Pol’y, Facebook, Inc.).
Facebook Messenger, Facebook’s then-director of platform partner-
ships cut off the app’s access to Facebook’s Graph API.
1003
In a submission to the Subcommittee, a former Facebook em-
ployee who handled platform management at the company said
that Facebook unevenly enforced its platform policies based on the
degree of another firm’s competition with Facebook and whether it
could extract concessions from other firms. According to this former
employee, Facebook was primarily concerned with whether a com-
pany was ‘‘a competitive threat,’’ and it ‘‘was biasing its enforce-
ment actions against [firms] they saw as competitors.’’
1004
In a
submission to the Subcommittee, the former Facebook employee
provided an example:
[I]n one Facebook Messages conversation involving the CEO, Mr. Zuckerberg,
and various executives in mid-2012, Mr. Zuckerberg expressed concern about an
app called Ark that was accessing large amounts of user data in a way that
could enable showing user content to people who didn’t have permission to see
the content. An investigation was conducted, and it was determined that Ark
was violating Facebook’s platform policies regarding the use of data from friends
of Facebook users. Ultimately, leadership decided to terminate Ark’s access to
Facebook’s APIs and ban Ark from the platform for six months. This was a harsh
punishment relative to other developers conducting similar activity—indeed, Mr.
Zuckerberg had been informed on the thread that ‘‘tons’’ of other apps were ac-
quiring data the same way and there was not further investigation or action
taken against those apps. Other apps that had been accused of violating data
policies similarly had been treated much more leniently. It seemed clear that
leadership imposed the more severe punishment against Ark because Mr.
Zuckerberg viewed Ark as competitive with Facebook, as Facebook was exploring
an acquisition of Ark at the same time as it was being investigated for policy vio-
lations.
1005
In contrast to punishing rivals, according to the former employee
and other market participants interviewed by the Subcommittee,
Facebook used ‘‘whitelists’’ to give preferential treatment to friends
of the company.
1006
For example, in a report published by NBC,
Facebook gave Amazon extended API access because Amazon was
spending money on advertising and partnering with Facebook on
the launch of its Fire smartphone. Facebook’s Director of Business
Development asked, ‘‘Remind me, why did we allow them to do
this? Do we receive any cut of purchases?’’ In response, a Facebook
employee who worked with Facebook’s ‘‘strategic partners’’ re-
sponded, ‘‘No, but Amazon is an advertiser and supporting this
with advertisement . . . and working with us on deeper integrations
for the Fire.’’
1007
In response to these concerns, Facebook told the Subcommittee
that it ‘‘does not restrict access to its Platform APIs simply because
an app competes with a Facebook product or service; but Facebook
will restrict apps that violate its policies.’’
1008
This is, however, in-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00146 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
141
1009
Transcript of Mark Zuckerberg’s Senate Hearing, W
ASH
. P
OST
(Apr. 10, 2018), https://
www.washingtonpost.com/news/the-switch/wp/2018/04/10/transcript-of-mark-zuckerbergs-
senate-hearing(‘‘ ‘Senator, we run ads,’ Zuckerberg replied.’’).
1010
Id.
1011
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 211.
1012
Competitors Hearing at 36 (statement of David Heinemeier Hansson, Cofounder & Chief
Tech. Officer, Basecamp).
1013
Id.
1014
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 211.
1015
F
ACEBOOK
, F
ACEBOOK
Q2 2020 R
ESULTS
(July 31, 2020), https://s21.q4cdn.com/
399680738/files/doclfinancials/2020/q2/Q2-2020-FB-Earnings-Presentation.pdf.
1016
M
ORNINGSTAR
E
QUITY
A
NALYST
R
EPORT
: F
ACEBOOK
I
NC
2 (Aug. 3, 2020) (on file with
Comm.) (‘‘The value of such data and advertisers’ willingness to use it is demonstrated by the
26% average annual growth of Facebook’s average ad revenue per user, or ARPU, during the
past five years, which we view as indicative of the price that advertisers pay Facebook for ad
placement. During the same period, Facebook’s monthly average users have grown 12% annu-
ally.’’).
consistent with the company’s internal communications and other
evidence examined by the Subcommittee during the investigation.
3. Digital Advertising
(a) Overview. Facebook monetizes its platform through the sales
of digital advertising.
1009
Facebook garnered over $70 billion in
revenue in 2019, a nearly 27 percent increase from 2018.
1010
It
generates this revenue predominately from selling advertisement
placements.
Facebook has monopoly power in online advertising in the social
networking market.
1011
Notwithstanding Google’s dominance,
Facebook also has a significant share of revenue and growth in on-
line advertising with many market participants referring to them
as duopolies in this broad market. Some market participants inter-
viewed by the Subcommittee consider Facebook ‘‘unavoidable’’ or
‘‘must have’’ due to the reach and scale of its platform. In par-
ticular, some businesses consider Facebook’s identity product—its
ability to persistently track users’ online and offline conduct to
serve tailored ads—as a unique feature.
1012
For example, at the
Subcommittee’s fifth hearing, David Heinemeier Hansson, the
Chief Technology Officer and Cofounder of Basecamp, testified that
the nature of Facebook’s targeted advertising makes it difficult to
replace, saying:
At Basecamp, we ultimately ended up swearing off the use of targeted advertise-
ment based on the exploitation of personal data. Facebook’s record of protecting
people’s privacy, and gathering their consent in the exploitation of their data for
advertisement purposes, is atrocious, and we decided that we wanted no part of
it. But choosing to opt out of targeted advertisement on the internet is like com-
peting with one arm behind your back. It is very clear why most companies feel
compelled to do this kind of advertisement, even if it’s a violation of their ethics.
If their competitors are doing it, they’re at a significant disadvantage if they
don’t. And the same is true for us. We have undoubtedly given up growth to com-
petitors because we’ve refrained from pursuing targeted ads.
1013
Facebook’s advantages in terms of access to data and its reach
contribute to its ability to earn higher revenue per user than other
firms in the social networking market.
1014
Facebook reported an
average revenue per user (ARPU) of $7.05 worldwide and $36.49
in the United States and Canada in July 2020.
1015
It has also
averaged significant annual growth—26 percent on average over
the past five years.
1016
In contrast, its closest competitor, Snap, re-
ported in July 2020 that its ARPU ‘‘remained flat’’ at $1.91 world-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00147 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
142
1017
Snap, Inc., Quarterly Report (Form 10–Q) 25, 27 (June 30, 2020), https://d18rn0p
25nwr6d.cloudfront.net/CIK-0001564408/9aacfdca-55a1-4928-9a31-c2462d2386c0.pdf.
1018
M
ORNINGSTAR
E
QUITY
A
NALYST
R
EPORT
: F
ACEBOOK
I
NC
1–2 (Aug. 3, 2020) (on file with
Comm.).
1019
Id.
1020
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00054106
(Apr. 9, 2012) (on file with Comm.).
1021
Id.
1022
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 9.
1023
Id. at 11–12, 211.
1024
F
RENCH
A
UTORITE
´
DE LA
C
ONCURRENCE &
B
UNDESKARTELLAMT
, C
OMPETITION
L
AW AND
D
ATA
(2016), https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Publikation/DE/Berichte/Big%20
Data%20Papier.pdf;jsessionid=D86CD9D13899F2590F84E82092187858.2lcid362?llblob=
publicationFile&v=2.
1025
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 10.
1026
Id.
1027
Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n Report at 97.
1028
Id.
wide and $3.48 in North America.
1017
A recent investment report
underscored this point, noting that Facebook enjoys a significant
economic moat illustrated by the inability of Snap and other firms
to meaningfully challenge its dominance.
1018
As a result, entry or
success by other firms is unlikely:
With more users and usage time than any other social network, Facebook pro-
vides the largest audience and the most valuable data for social network online
advertising. Facebook’s ad revenue per user is growing, demonstrating the value
that advertisers see in working with the firm .... Facebook has also expanded
its user base in the growing mobile market, which positively affected the net-
work effect as it became more valuable to advertisers, and resulted in more ad
revenue growth. The main drivers behind growth in online advertising have been
growths in the mobile ad market and the video ad format. Most Facebook users
are now accessing Facebook and its apps via mobile devices.
1019
Facebook’s internal documents reinforce this finding. In a presen-
tation prepared to deliver to investors ahead of the company’s ini-
tial public offering, Facebook characterized its advertising product
as having a significant advantage over the industry average in ac-
curacy and narrowly targeted campaigns due to its reach, engage-
ment, and using people’s ‘‘real identity—people as their real
selves.’’
1020
In comparison to television broadcasters, the company
noted that in the United States, ‘‘everyday on Facebook is like the
season finale of American [I]dol—the most popular show on TV—
times two.’’
1021
These findings are also consistent with those of Australian,
1022
British,
1023
French,
1024
and German antitrust authorities, which
conducted an extensive examination of Facebook’s market power in
the social networking market and in digital advertising. For exam-
ple, the United Kingdom’s Competition and Markets Authority
(CMA) found in July 2020 that Facebook and Instagram generated
over half of display advertising revenues in 2019 in the United
Kingdom, which it found to be a relevant market.
1025
In contrast
to other firms in the same market, Facebook’s lead was signifi-
cantly larger than its closes competitor, YouTube, which ‘‘earned
between 5 and 10%.’’
1026
In June 2019, the Australian Competi-
tion and Consumer Commission (ACCC) found that Facebook has
‘‘substantial market power in the supply of display advertising in
Australia.’’
1027
Similar to the CMA’s findings, the ACCC concluded
that the share of the display advertising market controlled by
Facebook and Instagram is significant—more than half—and grow-
ing, while the rest of the market is highly fragmented.
1028
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00148 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
143
1029
Submission from Facebook, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, FB–HJC–ACAL–00043659
(Mar. 2013) (on file with Comm.).
1030
Id.
1031
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00043509 (Oct. 18, 2012) (internal punctuation omitted).
1032
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00043660.
1033
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00043680 (emphasis in original).
1034
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00043705.
1035
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00043710.
1036
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00043660.
1037
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00043697.
1038
Id. at FB–HJC–ACAL–00043658.
(b) Relevant Acquisitions. On February 27, 2013, Facebook exe-
cuted an agreement to purchase Atlas, an advertiser-side platform
to manage and measure ad performance, from Microsoft for $100
million.
1029
At the time of the transaction, Atlas captured data to
track conversions—when a specific action is taken in response to
an ad, such as making a purchase—through clicks and impres-
sions.
1030
In other words, if someone saw a BestBuy ad, Atlas en-
abled serving the ad, recording the user seeing the ad via a brows-
er identifier, and recorded the impression as well as if the person
clicked on the ad. Later, if the same user bought the item from
BestBuy.com, Atlas recognized the user through their browser and
would record the conversion if the user purchased the item adver-
tised.
Prior to the acquisition, Amin Zoufonoun, Facebook’s Vice Presi-
dent for Corporate Development, described the ‘‘primary thesis’’ of
the acquisition to Sheryl Sandberg as giving Facebook ‘‘immediate
scale to retarget, provide premium insights, do look-alike modeling,
prove and measure efficacy of [Facebook] as a marketing medium,
[and] enhance custom audiences and associated revenue.’’
1031
Facebook’s primary strategic rationale for integrating Atlas into its
ad product was to improve its ability to measure ad performance
and use identity-based targeting through Facebook Identity—its
unique identifier for Facebook users across all browsers and de-
vices—to serve highly targeted ads.
1032
Facebook described the
value of Facebook Identity as its ability to ‘‘target people across
browsers and devices’’ and to ‘‘activate offline data to enrich online
targeting,’’ among other features.
1033
The company believed that its
‘‘unique data’’ and ‘‘unique reach and engagement (across devices
and platforms)’’ would boost its value to advertisers.
1034
Facebook also noted in its summary of the deal at the time of the transaction
that the major opportunities of the transaction were: (1) to become the ‘‘buy-side
desktop tool that media planners fire up first thing in the day’’; and (2) to ac-
quire ‘‘a deep installed base of pixels which we can immediately turn on to power
conversion tracking and attribution of ads across offerings.’’
1035
Absent the transaction, Facebook raised concerns that Google’s
‘‘lead in this market may become insurmountable’’ and limit
Facebook’s ads in other ways.
1036
The company also raised con-
cerns that Facebook’s Custom Audiences tool would not be able ‘‘to
scale beyond click-oriented advertisers.’’
1037
Among other potential
risks of the deal, such as rebuilding the product on Facebook’s ad
stack, the company identified ‘‘[m]anaging perceptions around pri-
vacy’’ as an area of concern.
1038
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00149 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
144
1039
Google Inc., Registration Statement (Form S–1) 1 (Apr. 29, 2004), https://www.sec.gov/
Archives/edgar/data/1288776/000119312504073639/ds1.htm.
1040
Id. at 65 (‘‘PageRank is a query-independent technique for determining the importance
of web pages by looking at the link structure of the web.’’).
1041
Press Release, Google, Google Launches World’s Largest Search Engine (June 26, 2000),
http://googlepress.blogspot.com/2000/06/google-launches-worlds-largest-search.html (stating
that Google had indexed over 1 billion webpages).
1042
Press Release, Google, Google Launches Self-Service Advertising Program (Oct. 23, 2000),
http://googlepress.blogspot.com/2000/10/google-launches-self-service.html.
1043
Harry McCracken, How Google Photos Joined the Billion-User Club, F
AST
C
O
. (July 24,
2019), https://www.fastcompany.com/90380618/how-google-photos-joined-the-billion-user-club.
1044
See infra Appendix; Leena Rao, Google Spent Nearly $2 Billion on 79 Acquisitions in
2011, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Jan. 27, 2012), https://techcrunch.com/2012/01/27/google-spent-nearly-2-
billion-on-79-acquisitions-in-2011/ (‘‘As of Q3, Google had spent over $1.4 billion on 55 acquisi-
tions for the year. Google ended 2011 spending $1.9 billion (including cash and stock) on com-
pleting 79 acquisitions during the entirety of the year.’’).
B. Google
1. Overview
Google was launched in 1998 as a general online search en-
gine.
1039
Founded by Larry Page and Sergey Brin, the corporation
got its start by serving users web results in response to online que-
ries. Google’s key innovation was its PageRank algorithm, which
ranked the relevance of a webpage by assessing how many other
webpages linked to it.
1040
In contrast with the technology used by
rival search engines, PageRank enabled Google to improve the
quality of its search results even as the web rapidly grew. While
Google had entered a crowded field, by 2000 it had become the
world’s largest search engine.
1041
Later that year, Google launched
AdWords, an online advertising service that let businesses pur-
chase keywords advertising to appear on Google’s search results
page—an offering that would evolve to become the heart of Google’s
business model.
1042
Today, Google is ubiquitous across the digital economy, serving
as the infrastructure for core products and services online. It has
grown and maintained its search engine dominance, such that
‘‘Googling’’ something is now synonymous with online search itself.
The company is now also the largest provider of digital advertising;
a leading web browser; a dominant mobile operating system; and
a major provider of digital mapping, email, cloud computing, and
voice assistant services, alongside dozens of other offerings. Nine of
Google’s products—Android, Chrome, Gmail, Google Search, Google
Drive, Google Maps, Google Photos, Google Play Store, and
YouTube—have more than a billion users each.
1043
Each of these
services provides Google with a trove of user data, reinforcing its
dominance across markets and driving greater monetization
through online ads.
In several markets, Google established its position through ac-
quisition, buying up successful technologies that other businesses
had developed. In a span of 20 years, Google purchased well over
260 companies—a figure that likely understates the full breadth of
Google’s acquisitions, given that many of the firm’s purchases have
gone unreported.
1044
Documents collected by the Subcommittee re-
veal that executives recognized as early as 2006 that Google’s ‘‘tre-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00150 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
145
1045
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04232284, at 2
(Sept. 25, 2006) (on file with Comm.) (stating that Google viewed transactions as falling into
three categories: (1) bolt-on; (2) outside existing efforts; and (3) around existing efforts).
1046
Alphabet Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 26–30 (Feb. 3, 2020), https://www.sec.gov/
Archives/edgar/data/1652044/000165204420000008/goog10-k2019.htm.
1047
Id. at 30.
1048
Id.
1049
Alphabet Inc., Quarterly Report (Form 10–Q) (June 30, 2020), https://abc.xyz/
investor/static/pdf/20200731lalphabetl10Q.pdf?cache=f16f989; Alphabet Q2 Earnings Call,
A
LPHABET
(July 30, 2020), https://abc.xyz/investor/static/pdf/2020lQ2lEarningsl
Transcript.pdf?cache=6bfce23.
1050
See Alphabet Inc., Annual Reports (Form 10–K) (2016–2019); Google Inc., Annual Reports
(Form 10–K) (2009–2016).
1051
M
ARC
S.F. M
AHANEY
, R
OYAL
B
ANK OF
C
AN
., D
IGGING FOR
B
URIED
T
REASURE
—T
HE
G
OOGLE
M
APS
O
PPORTUNITY
2 (2019) (on file with Comm.) [hereinafter Royal Bank of Canada
Report].
1052
Letter from Larry Page, CEO, Alphabet Inc., & Sundar Pichai, CEO, Google LLC, to
Shareholders (2015), https://abc.xyz/investor/founders-letters/2015/index.html#2015-larry-
alphabet-letter.
1053
Id.
1054
Alphabet Inc., Quarterly Report (Form 10–Q) 60 (June 30, 2020), https://abc.xyz/inves-
tor/static/pdf/20200731lalphabetl10Q.pdf?cache=f16f989 (‘‘The concentration of our stock
ownership limits our stockholders’ ability to influence corporate matters. Through their stock
ownership, Larry and Sergey have significant influence over all matters requiring stockholder
approval, including the election of directors and significant corporate transactions, such as a
merger or other sale of our company or our assets, for the foreseeable future.’’).
1055
Letter from Larry Page, CEO, Alphabet Inc., & Sundar Pichai, CEO, Google LLC, to
Shareholders (2015), https://abc.xyz/investor/founders-letters/2015/index.html#2015-larry-
alphabet-letter.
mendous cash resources’’ could be deployed to help execute Google’s
‘‘strategic plan.’’
1045
Google is now one of the world’s largest corporations. For 2019,
Google reported total revenues of $160.7 billion—up 45 percent
from 2017—and more than $33 billion in net income.
1046
Although
Google has diversified its offerings, it generates the vast majority
of its money through digital ads, which accounted for over 83 per-
cent of Google’s revenues in 2019.
1047
Search advertising, in par-
ticular, is critical to Google, accounting for approximately 61 per-
cent of its total sales.
1048
In recent months Google reported a drop
in ad revenue due to pandemic-related cuts in spending, though the
company partly made up for the decline through revenue growth in
Google Cloud, Google Play, and YouTube.
1049
Google has enjoyed
strong and steady profits, with profit margins greater than 20 per-
cent for nine out of the last 10 years, close to three times larger
than the average for a U.S. firm.
1050
Financial analysts predict
that Google is well positioned to maintain its dominance, noting
that ‘‘Alphabet has established unusually deep competitive moats
around its business.’’
1051
In 2015, Google underwent a reorganization, introducing Alpha-
bet as a parent company under which Google would reside as a
wholly owned subsidiary.
1052
Alphabet also houses the company’s
non-search ventures, such as Calico, the biotech company focused
on longevity, and Waymo, which develops self-driving cars.
1053
In
December 2019, Page and Brin stepped down from their manage-
ment roles at Alphabet, though they remain on the board and to-
gether control approximately 51.3 percent of the voting
power.
1054
Sundar Pichai now serves as the CEO of both Google
and Alphabet.
1055
For years Google has been the subject of antitrust investigations
and enforcement actions around the world. From 2011 to 2013, the
Federal Trade Commission investigated Google’s role in search and
advertising markets, culminating in a staff recommendation to file
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00151 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
146
1056
Tony Romm, 50 U.S. States and Territories Announce Broad Antitrust Investigation of
Google, W
ASH
. P
OST
(Sept. 9, 2019), https://www.washingtonpost.com/technology/2019/09/09/
states-us-territories-announce-broad-antitrust-investigation-google/.
1057
Alphabet Inc., Quarterly Report (Form 10–Q) 27 (July 30, 2020), https://abc.xyz/
investor/static/pdf/20200731lalphabetl10Q.pdf?cache=f16f989; Leah Nylen, Trump Adminis-
tration to Launch Antitrust Suit Against Google as Soon as Next Week, P
OLITICO
(Oct. 2, 2020),
https://www.politico.com/news/2020/10/02/trump-doj-google-antitrust-lawsuit-425617.
1058
Aditya Kalra & Aditi Shah, Exclusive: Google Faces Antitrust Case in India Over Pay-
ments App—Sources, R
EUTERS
(May 27, 2020), https://www.reuters.com/article/us-india-google-
antitrust-exclusive/exclusive-google-faces-antitrust-case-in-india-over-pagos-app-sources-idUSK
BN2331G3; Thomas Grove, Russia Fines Google $6.75 Million in Antitrust Case, W
ALL
S
T
. J.
(Aug. 11, 2016), https://www.wsj.com/articles/russia-fines-google-6-75-million-in-antitrust-case-
1470920410; Charles Riley & Ivana Kottasova
´
, Europe Hits Google with a Third, $1.7 Billion
Antitrust Fine, CNN (Mar. 20, 2019), https://www.cnn.com/2019/03/20/tech/google-eu-anti-
trust/index.html; Natasha Lomas, France Slaps Google with $166M Antitrust Fine for Opaque
and Inconsistent Ad Rules, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Dec. 20, 2019), https://techcrunch.com/2019/12/20/
france-slaps-google-with-166m-antitrust-fine-for-opaque-and-inconsistent-ad-rules/.
1059
Search Engine Market Share Worldwide, S
TAT
C
OUNTER
, https://gs.statcounter.com/
search-engine-market-share (last visited Sept. 29, 2020).
1060
Enforcers and courts have found that Google dominates the market for online search in
various cases stretching back over a decade. See, e.g., Press Release, U.S. Dep’t of Justice,
Yahoo! Inc. and Google Inc. Abandon Their Advertising Agreement (Nov. 5, 2008), https://
www.justice.gov/archive/opa/pr/2008/November/08-at-981.html (‘‘The Department’s investiga-
tion revealed that Internet search advertising and Internet search syndication are each relevant
antitrust markets and that Google is by far the largest provider of such services, with shares
of more than 70 percent in both markets.’’); Press Release, U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Statement of
the Department of Justice Antitrust Division on Its Decision to Close Its Investigation of the
Internet Search and Paid Search Advertising Agreement Between Microsoft Corporation and
Yahoo! Inc. (Feb. 18, 2010), https://www.justice.gov/opa/pr/statement-department-justice-anti-
trust-division-its-decision-close-its-investigation-internet (‘‘The proposed transaction will combine
the back-end search and paid search advertising technology of both parties. U.S. market partici-
pants express support for the transaction and believe that combining the parties’ technology
would be likely to increase competition by creating a more viable competitive alternative to
Google, the firm that now dominates these markets.’’); Author’s Guild v. Google Inc., 770 F.
Supp. 2d 666, 683 (S.D.N.Y. 2011) (recognizing ‘‘Google’s market power in the online search
market’’).
a complaint against Google—although the Commission ultimately
decided not to do so. At various points over the last decade, Mis-
sissippi, Missouri, and Texas have each separately investigated
Google for antitrust violations, and, in September 2019, attorneys
general from 50 U.S. states and territories announced that they
were opening a fresh antitrust inquiry into the search and adver-
tising giant.
1056
The Department of Justice has also been inves-
tigating Google since the summer of 2019, and recent news reports
state that a lawsuit may be imminent.
1057
These ongoing U.S. in-
vestigations follow multiple antitrust inquiries worldwide, as well
as antitrust-related penalties levied on Google by the European
Commission, France, India, and Russia.
1058
2. Search
(a) Market Power. Google overwhelmingly dominates the market
for general online search. Publicly available data suggests the firm
captures over 87 percent of U.S. search and over 92 percent of que-
ries worldwide.
1059
Despite notable changes in the market—such as
the switch from desktop to mobile—Google has maintained this
dominance for more than a decade, a period during which its lead
over its most significant competitors has only increased.
1060
Over
that time, Google benefited from economies of scale and the self-
reinforcing advantages of data, as well as from aggressive business
tactics that Google wielded at key moments to thwart competition.
The combined result is that Google now enjoys durable monopoly
power in the market for general online search.
Several factors render Google’s power in online search generally
immune to competition or threat of entry. General online search
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00152 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
147
1061
See Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 396 (response to Questions for the
Record of Adam Cohen, Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC) (‘‘Google Search responds to trillions
of user queries from around the world every year.’’); see also M
AURICE
E. S
TUCKE &
A
LLEN
P.
G
RUNES
, B
IG
D
ATA AND
C
OMPETITION
P
OLICY
12.10 (2016) (‘‘Entry barriers into the search en-
gine market are already high. Microsoft reportedly invested in 2010 ‘more than $4.5 billion into
developing its algorithm and building the physical capacity necessary to operate Bing.’ ’’).
1062
Lisa Marie Segarra, Google to Pay Apple $12 Billion to Remain Safari’s Default Search
Engine in 2019: Report, F
ORTUNE
(Sept. 29, 2018), https://fortune.com/2018/09/29/google-
apple-safari-search-engine/.
1063
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 194.
1064
See, e.g., Submission from Source 481, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Jan. 30, 2020) (on
file with Comm.).
1065
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, A–11 (Nov. 22, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
1066
Id.; see also Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 401 (statement of Adam Cohen,
Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC). Although the specialized search providers that Google lists as
competitors may, in some instances, compete with Google for queries, ‘‘[t]he competition between
Google and vertical search engines’’ is ‘‘to some extent asymmetrical. From a user’s point of
view, a generalist search engine that fully covers a given vertical can be a complete substitute
for the vertical search engine, while the reverse is not generally true. Consequently, Google im-
poses more significant competitive constraints on a vertical search engine than vice versa.’’ Sub-
mission from Source 209, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 209–0000540 (Feb. 17, 2011)
(on file with Comm.).
strongly favors scale due to: (1) the high fixed costs of servers need-
ed for crawling and indexing the entire web; and (2) the self-rein-
forcing advantages of click-and-query data, which let a search en-
gine constantly improve the relevance of search results. Even an
upstart that was able to secure the necessary capital to invest
heavily in computing infrastructure would find itself at a consider-
able disadvantage given that Google’s search algorithm has been
refined through trillions upon trillions of queries.
1061
Meanwhile,
steps that website owners take to block non-Google crawlers have
rendered the task of creating an independent comprehensive index
extremely challenging, if not effectively impossible.
Even search engines that choose to syndicate their search results
rather than create their own index and algorithm face major obsta-
cles. This is primarily because Google—through both integration
and contractual agreements—has established itself as the default
search provider on 87 percent of desktop browsers and the vast ma-
jority of mobile devices. Specifically, Google used its search domi-
nance to promote the use of its Chrome browser on laptops, per-
sonal computers, and workstations, which sets Google Search as its
default. For mobile devices, Google imposed a set of restrictive con-
tractual terms effectively requiring manufacturers of devices that
used its Android operating system to pre-install both Chrome and
Google Search. Additionally, Google pays Apple an undisclosed
amount, estimated to be $12 billion per year, to secure the search
default across iOS devices.
1062
In general, users tend to stick with
the default presented.
1063
Moreover, Google takes steps to hamper
and dissuade even those users that do attempt to switch search en-
gines on Chrome.
1064
With these factors combined, Google’s conduct
significantly impedes other search providers from reaching users at
scale—and further expands and entrenches Google’s dominance.
In submissions to the Committee, Google states that Google
Search ‘‘operates in a highly competitive environment,’’ facing a
‘‘vast array of competitors’’ in general online search, including
Bing, DuckDuckGo, and Yahoo.
1065
Google also claims that, for any
given search query, Google competes against a ‘‘wide range of com-
panies’’ including Amazon, eBay, Kayak, and Yelp.
1066
Google ar-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00153 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
148
1067
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, A–11 (Nov. 22, 2019) (on file
with Comm.). In certain regards, Google’s argument echoes the claim Microsoft made when it
contested the district court’s decision to exclude ‘‘middleware’’ from its definition of the relevant
market. The court found that, although it was true that middleware could ‘‘usurp the operating
system’s platform function and might eventually take over other operating system functions,’’
it was also true that no middleware product ‘‘could now, or would soon, expose enough APIs
to serve as a platform for popular applications, much less take over all operating system func-
tions.’’ United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 53–54 (D.C. Cir. 2001). Similarly, although
certain vertical search providers could under certain circumstances ‘‘usurp’’ the horizontal pro-
vider’s platform function, no vertical provider does or would soon serve this function.
1068
Meeting with Google (Feb. 10, 2020).
1069
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–01967913 (Jan. 27,
2007) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Each quarter we gather comprehensive search and market share
data even though we [do] NOT share it with the board anymore. I am pleased to say that we’ve
finally turned the corner on getting decent data of our own rather than ComScore .... Next
steps include further work on internal sources such as the toolbar and AFC referrals which we
believe will give us more data to model and help us adjust for the biases of external sources.’’);
id. at GOOG–HJC–01529590 (Oct. 11, 2011) (listing ‘‘internal US search share metrics’’ for Q2
2011); Email from Google to Staff of the H. Comm on the Judiciary (Apr. 16, 2020) (on file with
Comm.).
1070
Email from Google to Staff of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Apr. 16, 2020) (on file with
Comm.).
1071
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04231168, at 2 (on
file with Comm.).
1072
Id. at GOOG–HJC–01207063 (Oct. 27, 2009) (attachment to email from Marissa Mayer).
1073
Id. at GOOG–HJC–03815864 (Apr. 23, 2010).
1074
Id.
gues that this broader set of competitors means that public esti-
mates of its share of general online search ‘‘do not capture the full
extent of Google’s competition in search.’’
1067
Despite these statements, Google failed to provide the Sub-
committee with contemporary market share data that would cor-
roborate its claims. In response to the Committee’s written request
for market share data, combined with several follow-ups from the
Subcommittee, Google stated that the company ‘‘doesn’t maintain
information in the normal course of business about market share
in its products.’’
1068
After the Subcommittee identified communica-
tions where Google executives had discussed regularly tracking
search market share data and further developing internal tools for
doing so, Google told the Subcommittee that this data is either no
longer collected or no longer used for examining site traffic.
1069
It
added, ‘‘[W]hile Google may have examined certain ‘shares’ of
usage, clicks, queries, or traffic in limited and incomplete data sets
over time, we do not believe any of this constitutes ‘market share’
analysis.’’
1070
Market share information that Google did provide from over a
decade ago reveals that Google viewed itself as a leader in general
search as early as 2007. One slide deck tracking search query vol-
ume and revenues stated that ‘‘[c]ontinued leadership in search un-
derpins the whole business.’’
1071
In 2009, a top executive cir-
culated market share analysis documenting that Google captured
71.5 percent of general search in the United States, followed by
Yahoo with 17 percent, and Bing with 7.5 percent.
1072
And in 2010,
one Google employee observed, ‘‘Google leads competitors. This is
our bread-and-butter. Our long-tail precision is why users continue
to come to Google. Users may try the bells and whistles of Bing
and other competitors, but Google still produces the best re-
sults.’’
1073
Noting that Bing was ‘‘making clear, significant
progress’’ on ‘‘bringing the two search engines closer to parity,’’ the
employee stated it was ‘‘critical to redouble our efforts to maintain
our lead.’’
1074
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00154 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
149
1075
Submission from Source 209, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 209–0000346, at 351–
52 (Aug. 24, 2009) (on file with Comm.).
1076
Search Engine Market Share Worldwide, S
TAT
C
OUNTER
, https://gs.statcounter.com/
search-engine-market-share (last visited Sept. 29, 2020).
1077
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04259758 to
–04259759 (Apr. 20, 2016) (on file with Comm.).
1078
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 89.
1079
Submission from Source 115, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 6 (Oct. 22, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1080
Interview with J&J Smith (Aug. 24, 2020).
1081
Submission from Foundem, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 4 (Jan. 21, 2018) (on file with
Comm.).
1082
Submission from Source 564, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Nov. 13, 2019) (on file
with Comm.); Submission from Source 3, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 34 (Nov. 22, 2019) (on
file with Comm.).
The Subcommittee has not seen any compelling evidence to sug-
gest that Google’s dominance over the last decade has diminished;
to the contrary, there is compelling evidence that Google has only
strengthened and solidified what was already a leading market po-
sition. For example, in 2009, Microsoft and Yahoo—Google’s closest
competitors—entered an agreement to integrate their search plat-
forms, an effort to team up to tackle Google’s dominance.
1075
A dec-
ade later, the two collectively have a lower share of the general
search market than they did at the time of their deal, whereas
Google’s share has increased.
1076
As of 2016, Google employees
were calculating that Bing had suffered a 30 percent year-over-year
decline in query volume and that Bing’s revenue per million im-
pressions (RPM) was ‘‘70–77% lower’’ than Google’s own U.S.
search RPM.
1077
More recently, the United Kingdom’s Competition
and Markets Authority found that Google’s index of the web is any-
where from three to five times the size of Bing’s.
1078
Furthermore,
the fact that no new general search entrant over the last decade
has ever accounted for more than one percent of all U.S. searches
in any given year further confirms that Google’s monopoly power
is durable and its lead insurmountable.
1079
Google’s claim that it ‘‘operates in a highly competitive environ-
ment’’ is also at odds with the lived reality of market participants.
Numerous companies—spanning major public corporations, small
businesses, and upstart entrepreneurs—told the Subcommittee that
they overwhelmingly depend on Google for traffic and that no alter-
nate search engine even remotely approaches serving as a sub-
stitute. For example, J&J Smith, a printer repair shop based in
Rhode Island, stated, ‘‘Google is our lifeblood.’’
1080
Foundem, a UK-
based comparison shopping search provider, has noted that
Google’s ‘‘overwhelming global dominance’’ of horizontal search cre-
ates for most websites an ‘‘uncomfortable but unavoidable reliance
on Google.’’
1081
Many other companies described their dependence
on Google in similar terms.
Furthermore, some of the same specialized search providers that
Google identifies as competitors stated that their own businesses
heavily rely on Google, in some cases for up to 80 percent of traffic
on both desktop and mobile devices.
1082
One specialized search pro-
vider wrote that Google’s business practices ‘‘have a very material
effect on [our] business, but due to Google’s monopoly power in
search, there is nowhere else for [us] to turn for additional search
traffic. The company is beholden to how Google decides to structure
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00155 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
150
1083
Submission from Source 887, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 4 (Oct. 28, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1084
Submission from Source 626, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1085
Submission from Source 972, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 10 (Dec. 9, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
1086
Interview with Source 147 (June 26, 2019).
1087
Competitors Hearing at 28 (statement of David Heinemeier Hansson, Cofounder & Chief
Tech. Officer, Basecamp).
1088
Id.
1089
Id.
1090
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 595 (response to Questions for the Record
by Kyle Andeer, Vice President, Corp. Law, Apple, Inc.).
1091
See, e.g., Adam Kovacevich, Google’s Approach to Competition, G
OOGLE
P
UB
. P
OL
Y
B
LOG
(May 8, 2009), https://publicpolicy.googleblog.com/2009/05/googles-approach-to-competition
.html.
its search results page and algorithm.’’
1083
Another told the Sub-
committee, ‘‘From [our] perspective, there are no adequate sub-
stitutes for Google,’’
1084
and, ‘‘[T]hanks to its monopoly in general
internet search, Google has become the gatekeeper for vertical
search rivals.’’
1085
One specialized search provider said that 97.6
percent of its traffic comes from Google; another said that Google
accounted for such an outsized share of traffic that ‘‘we don’t even
track non-Google sources.’’
1086
At the Subcommittee’s field hearing in January 2020, David
Heinemeier Hansson, Cofounder and Chief Technology Officer of
Basecamp, testified that Google increasingly functions as ‘‘the front
door of the internet.’’
1087
He noted, ‘‘[Google is] the start page for
millions. It’s a form of navigation around the internet. People these
days rarely bother to remember the specific internet address of a
company they want to do business with, they just google
it.’’
1088
Commenting on the stark asymmetry in the general search
market, Hansson stated that Yahoo, Bing, and DuckDuckGo all
‘‘could drop [Basecamp] from their listings tomorrow and we’d bare-
ly notice,’’ but ‘‘[w]e lose our listing in Google and we may go out
of business.’’
1089
Google obtained default placement across the mobile and desktop
ecosystem through both integration and contractual arrangements.
Through owning Android, the world’s dominant mobile operating
system, Google was able to ensure that Google Search remained
dominant even as mobile replaced desktop as the critical entry
point to the internet. As discussed elsewhere in the Report, docu-
ments submitted to the Subcommittee show that, at certain key
moments, Google conditioned access to the Google Play Store on ex-
clusively pre-installing Google Search, a requirement that gave
Google a significant advantage over competing search engines.
Through revenue-sharing agreements amounting to billions of dol-
lars in annual payments, Google also established default positions
on Apple’s Safari browser (on both desktop and mobile) and on
Mozilla’s Firefox.
1090
In public statements, Google has downplayed the significance of
default placement, claiming that ‘‘competition is just a click
away.’’
1091
However, Google’s internal documents show that, at a
time when Google was still jostling for search market share, Google
executives closely tracked search defaults on Microsoft’s Internet
Explorer and expressed concern that non-Google defaults could im-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00156 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
151
1092
See, e.g., Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–01196214
(May 3, 2005) (on file with Comm.).
1093
Id. at GOOG–HJC–01680749 (2006) (identifying several recommendations, including
‘‘[f]ewest clicks required to change default, which promotes search innovation by facilitating the
user’s ability to switch’’).
1094
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 343 (statement of Megan Gray, Gen. Couns.
& Pol’y Advoc., DuckDuckGo).
1095
Id. at 5.
1096
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 73.
1097
Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n Report at 58.
1098
Case AT.39740, Google Search (Shopping), Eur. Comm’n Decision C(2017) 4444, ¶ 271
(June 27, 2017), https://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/decldocs/39740/39740l
14996l3.pdf [hereinafter Google Search (Shopping) Comm’n Decision] (‘‘The Commission con-
cludes that Google holds a dominant position in each national market for general search services
since 2008, apart from in the Czech Republic, where Google holds a dominant position since
2011.’’); Case AT.40099, Google Android, Eur. Comm’n Decision C(2018) 4761, ¶ 439 (July 18,
2018), https://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/decldocs/40099/40099l9993l3.pdf
[hereinafter Google Android Comm’n Decision] (‘‘[T]he Commission concludes that Google holds
a dominant position in the following relevant markets since 2011: . . . (3) each national market
for general search services in the EEA.’’).
pede Google Search.
1092
In an internal presentation about Internet
Explorer’s default search selection, Google recommended that users
be given an initial opportunity to select a search engine and that
browsers minimize the steps required to change the default search
provider.
1093
These discussions, as well as the steep sums Google
pays Apple and various browsers for default search placement, fur-
ther highlight the competitive significance of default positions.
Independent search engines told the Subcommittee that the lack
of defaults available to them creates significant business chal-
lenges. DuckDuckGo said this lack of options compelled it to invest
in browser technology, including the creation of its own browser for
Android and iOS and various browser extensions.
1094
It noted,
however, that ‘‘the same default placement challenges exist in the
browser market, just one level up—with the device makers requir-
ing millions or billions of dollars to become a default browser on
a device.’’
1095
Lastly, the Subcommittee’s findings are consistent with conclu-
sions reached by several enforcement bodies that recently have in-
vestigated Google’s market dominance. For example, in July 2020,
the United Kingdom’s Competition and Markets Authority found
that ‘‘Google has significant market power in the general search
sector,’’ a position maintained through ‘‘three key barriers to entry:
economies of scale in developing a web index; access to click-and-
query data at scale; and Google’s extensive default posi-
tions.’’
1096
In July 2019, the Australian Competition and Con-
sumer Commission (ACCC) found that Google has ‘‘substantial
market power in supplying general search services’’ and that it is
‘‘likely to retain its dominant share of the market at least in the
short- to medium-term.’’
1097
And in two separate enforcement ac-
tions in 2017 and 2018, the European Commission found that
Google possessed market power in the market for online general
search.
1098
While each of these enforcers focused on their respec-
tive national and regional markets, Google has failed to identify
any factors that would compel the Subcommittee to reach a dif-
ferent conclusion for the U.S. market.
(b) Conduct
(i) Google Leverages Dominance Through Data Misappropriation
and Self-Preferencing. When Google launched in 1998, the search
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00157 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
152
1099
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04137557 (Nov. 29,
2005) (on file with Comm.).
1100
Id. at GOOG–HJC–01099230 (Oct. 20, 2006).
1101
Id. at GOOG–HJC–03815865 (Apr. 23, 2010).
1102
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04276684 to –04276687 (Sept. 21, 2012).
listings it delivered were ‘‘ten blue links,’’ or a set of organic results
that guided users off Google’s webpage to locate relevant informa-
tion. In the years since, Google, as well as Bing, has evolved to dis-
playing blue links alongside a variety of Google’s own content, as
well as ‘‘information boxes’’ that list responses directly on the
search results page.
While this model may, in certain instances, provide users with
direct information more quickly, documents collected by the Sub-
committee show that Google built some of these features through
aggressive tactics that exploited its search dominance. Google’s con-
duct helped maintain its monopoly in online search and search ad-
vertising while dissuading investment in nascent competitors, un-
dermining innovation, and harming users and businesses alike.
According to internal documents, Google executives recognized as
early as 2005 that specialized—or ‘‘vertical’’—search engines could
pose a threat to Google’s long-term dominance. That year, one pro-
gram manager wrote:
[W]hat is the real threat if we don’t execute on verticals?
(a) [L]oss of traffic from google.com because folks search elsewhere for some
queries[;]
(b) related revenue loss for high spend verticals like travel[;]
(c) missing [opportunity] if someone else creates the platform to build verticals[;]
[and]
(d) if one of our big competitors builds a constellation of high quality verticals,
we are hurt badly[.]
1099
Google’s apprehension about vertical search providers persisted.
For example, a 2006 strategy memo identifying challenges asked,
‘‘How do we deal with the problem of ‘proliferating verticals?’ ’’
1100
Another message noted, ‘‘Vertical search is of tremendous strategic
importance to Google. Otherwise, the risk is that Google is the go-
to place for finding information only in the cases where there is
sufficiently low monetization potential that no niche vertical search
competitor has filled the space with a better alternative.’’
1101
In
short, Google executives feared that vertical search providers would
build direct relationships with users, thereby bypassing Google
Search and diverting traffic, valuable data, and ad revenue. While
vertical search providers were complements to Google in the short
term, Google recognized their potential for disintermediating
Google and therefore viewed them as a major competitive threat.
The fact that several of these verticals specialized in commercial
queries that were among the most valuable for Google further
raised the stakes.
1102
Documents show that Google developed a multi-pronged strategy
to thwart the threat. Two of these tactics included: (1) misappro-
priating third-party content; and (2) privileging Google’s own serv-
ices while demoting those of third parties. Through these practices,
Google exploited its dominance to weaken potential rivals and
boost its search advertising revenue.
(1) Misappropriating Third-Party Content. In the years following
2005, Google invested in building out its own vertical services. Doc-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00158 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
153
1103
Id. at GOOG–HJC–03665122 to –03665126 (Apr. 24, 2007) (internal Google discussion
noting the strength of Yelp’s local product) (‘‘[T]here is nothing else ‘yelp like’ in our current
lineup,’’ and also noting that ‘‘[Yelp’s CEO] just contacted the account manager here and asked
that their contract be revised so that they could cancel it immediately if we launch reviews, that
doesn’t mean that they would do it, but clearly this is a big deal to them.’’).
1104
Id. at GOOG–HJC–03249494 (Aug. 10, 2010) (‘‘Given that this App directly competes
with the Yelp App and offers little value to Yelp we cannot allow Google to continue leveraging
our content in this way. We’ve communicated to Patrick and Carter that your team needs to
remove our content within the next week. Since you already communicated to me that it would
be un-Googley to not remove our content when requested, I’m confident your team will do the
right thing.’’).
1105
See, e.g., id. at GOOG–HJC–03255279 (Oct. 28, 2010) (‘‘[I] want to tell you that my feel-
ings are really hurt by the ‘local is a failure’ stuff that Nikesh has been lobbing around.’’); id.
at GOOG–HJC–03790807 to –03790808 (Apr. 24, 2007) (‘‘[W]e are still waiting to be removed
from Places (while remaining in organic and local merge results), which you initially agreed to
(but more recently pulled away from).’’); id. at GOOG–HJC–01234494 (Aug. 10, 2011) (‘‘I was
surprised to find that by opting out of Google’s local product, Yelp was automatically opted out
of portions of Google’s search results. Carter Maslan and John Hanke last year said they
couldn’t/wouldn’t remove Yelp content from Google’s local product because local was powered by
the same index as web search, sounds like this was never really the case.’’); id. at GOOG–HJC–
012344946 (‘‘To be able to reference Yelp’s content in the parts of search results we discussed,
our local service needs to be at least aware of the existence of Yelp pages. Since we stopped
using any crawled Yelp pages for our local services in response to your request, this currently
isn’t possible. That said, I think that the approach we discussed, with Google making limited
use of Yelp data in the ways you described, is a constructive way to get a comprehensive view
for our users.’’).
1106
See, e.g., id. at GOOG–HJC–03664462 (Apr. 23, 2007) (‘‘78% of their uniques come from
google. [I]f they are acquired, [I] would assume that they wouldn’t turn us off.’’).
1107
See generally Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 354–60 (statement of Brian
Warner, Founder, Celebrity Net Worth).
uments reveal that Google partly did so through lifting content di-
rectly from third-party providers to bootstrap Google’s own vertical
services. In the process, Google leveraged its search dominance—
demanding that third parties permit Google to take their content,
or else be removed from Google’s search results entirely.
For example, after identifying local search as a ‘‘particularly im-
portant’’ vertical to develop, Google built Google Local, which li-
censed content from local providers, including Yelp.
1103
In 2010,
Google rolled out a service directly competing with Yelp, even as
Google continued to license Yelp’s content—prompting Yelp’s CEO
to request that Google immediately remove Yelp’s proprietary con-
tent from Google’s own service.
1104
At a time when Google Local
was failing to gain momentum, Google told Yelp that the only way
to have its content removed from Google’s competing product was
to be removed from Google’s general results entirely.
1105
Yelp re-
lied so heavily on Google for user traffic that the company could
not afford to be delisted—a fact that Google likely knew.
1106
In
short, Google weaponized its search dominance, demanding that
Yelp surrender valuable content to Google’s competing product or
else risk heavy losses in traffic and revenue.
Evidence gathered by the Subcommittee identifies additional in-
stances in which Google has intercepted traffic from third-party
websites by forcibly scraping their content and placing it directly
on Google’s own site. For example, a submission from entrepreneur
Brian Warner described how he built a database from scratch and
developed it into a sustainable and growing business—only to
watch Google lift his content and sink his traffic.
1107
Warner, the
founder of Celebrity Net Worth, told the Subcommittee that, in
2012, the content he had initially developed as a side project had
such high demand that Warner was able to quit his day job and
hire 12 staff members. In 2014, Google contacted Warner to ask if
he would provide Google with an API that would display his
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00159 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
154
1108
Id. at 357.
1109
Id. Because Warner had added several conjured celebrities to his site to gauge whether
Google was scraping his content or lifting it from elsewhere, he was able to determine that
Google was sourcing its answers directly from Celebrity Net Worth.
1110
Id. at 358.
1111
Id.
1112
Id.
1113
Id. at 306 (statement of Ben Gross, Chief Strategy Officer, Genius).
1114
Id. at 307.
1115
Id.
1116
Id.
1117
Id.
1118
CEO Hearing at 72 (question of Rep. David N. Cicilline (D–RI), Chair, Subcomm. on
Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm on the Judiciary).
webpage’s content in an ‘‘answer box’’ that would appear directly
on Google’s search results page. Warner declined, observing that
handing over his company’s ‘‘most valuable asset’’ would ‘‘cause a
catastrophic drop in traffic.’’
1108
Within two years, Google began
populating its answer boxes with Celebrity Net Worth’s content
anyway—displaying net worth results for each of the 25,000+ celeb-
rities from Warner’s database directly on Google’s search results
page.
1109
Combined with changes that pushed Warner’s webpage from the
top of organic listings to the middle of the second page, Google’s
scraping caused traffic to Celebrity Net Worth to drop by 50 per-
cent overnight.
1110
Warner wrote, ‘‘With the flip of a switch, Google
turned our original content into its own content. And with that
move, Google would keep the searcher within its walled garden in-
definitely. That is far more valuable to Google than taking a small
cut of our AdSense revenue.’’
1111
Today, Celebrity Net Worth’s
traffic is down 80 percent from 2014, and—due to the resulting
drop in revenue—Warner has had to lay off half of his staff.
1112
In a submission to the Subcommittee, lyrics site Genius de-
scribed similar misappropriation by Google. Genius noted that it
has invested ‘‘a decade and millions of dollars’’ developing a lyrics
repository that relies on user-generated content as well as partner-
ships with songwriters.
1113
For years, however, Google has copied
lyrics from Genius’s website and displayed them in information
boxes that it places at the top of its search results page.
1114
Al-
though Genius shared with Google evidence showing that the plat-
form was scraping lyrics directly from Genius, Google for two years
‘‘did nothing to address the issue.’’
1115
It was only after The Wall
Street Journal published Genius’s claims that Google responded,
taking steps to remove the evidence that Google had copied the
lyrics but leaving the lyrics in place.
1116
Google later announced
that it would attribute lyrics placed in the information box to the
underlying content provider. ‘‘This would be encouraging,’’ Genius
wrote, ‘‘except for the fact that all of the lyrics we flagged for
Google as featuring our watermark—and thus clearly copied from
Genius—are currently attributed to another company.’’
1117
At the Subcommittee’s hearing on July 29, 2020, multiple mem-
bers questioned Mr. Pichai about Google’s misappropriation of
third-party content. Subcommittee Chair David N. Cicilline (D–RI)
recounted Google’s scraping of Celebrity Net Worth, asking, ‘‘[W]hy
does Google steal content from honest businesses?’’
1118
Mr. Pichai
responded that he ‘‘disagree[d] with that categorization.’’ Rep-
resentative Ken Buck (R–CO) followed up by noting that Genius
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00160 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
155
1119
Id. at 79 (statement of Rep. Ken Buck (R–CO), Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Com-
mercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
1120
Id.
1121
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 403 (response to Questions for the Record
of Adam Cohen, Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC).
1122
Interview with Source 489 (Sept. 19, 2020).
1123
Id.
seemed to have collected clear evidence of Google’s misappropria-
tion:
When Genius suspected this corporate theft was occurring, the company incor-
porated a digital watermark in its lyrics that spelled out red-handed in Morse
code. Google’s lyric boxes contained the watermark showing that your company
stole what you couldn’t or didn’t want to produce yourself. After Google execu-
tives stated that they were investigating this problematic behavior, Genius cre-
ated another experiment to determine the scope of the misappropriation. It turns
out that, out of 271 songs where the watermark was applied, 43 percent showed
clear evidence of matching. Your company, which advertises itself as a doorway
to freedom, took advantage of this small company, all but extinguishing Genius’
freedom to compete.
1119
Mr. Pichai responded that Google ‘‘license[s] content from other
companies,’’ and that this issue was ‘‘a dispute between Genius and
other companies in terms of where the source of the content
is.’’
1120
In its response to Questions for the Record from the Sub-
committee, Google also stated that it now gives webpage owners
the ability to exclude certain content from appearing in information
boxes on Google’s search results page.
1121
However, multiple
webpage publishers stated that, in practice, this option fails to
mitigate the harm, given that Google will continue to source and
display content from others, thereby still intercepting traffic and
displacing organic listings. One publisher described Google’s claim
to give webpage owners more control as ‘‘an empty offering.’’
1122
In an interview with the Subcommittee, one webpage owner stat-
ed that he felt deceived by Google’s decision to use its crawling ad-
vantages to misappropriate third-party content. The webpage
owner said:
A major violation occurred when Google used robotic information scraped by its
crawler to create content of its own which is displayed in the search result page.
We never would have created sitemaps for Google if those were the terms.
Google wouldn’t have had sitemaps from every website on earth feeding it con-
tent if those were the terms from the beginning. They would have been forced
to create a new system in order to convince sites to comply or a new search serv-
ice would have been born that had different options.
1123
Google’s practice of misappropriating third-party content to boot-
strap its own rival search services and to keep users on Google’s
own webpage is further evidence of its monopoly power and an ex-
ample of how Google has abused that power. Google seized value
from third-party businesses without their consent. These busi-
nesses had no effective choice but to allow Google’s misappropria-
tion to continue, given Google’s search dominance. In this way,
Google leveraged its search dominance to misappropriate third-
party content, free-riding on others’ investments and innovations.
(2) Self-Preferencing. Evidence shows that once Google built out
its vertical offerings, it introduced various changes that had the ef-
fect of privileging Google’s own inferior services while demoting
competitors’ offerings. This conduct has undermined the vertical
search providers that Google viewed as a threat. It has also boosted
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00161 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
156
1124
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–01230600 (Dec. 8,
2004) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Googlers have long argued for some type of ‘universal’ search that
integrates all of Google’s indices, including those that contain different media, like Images, and
those that contain structured data, like Local and Froogle.’’); id. at GOOG–HJC–03815864 to
–03815865 (Apr. 23, 2010) (noting that Universal Search marked a shift to ‘‘increase our ability
to provide new types of media in search results’’).
1125
Id. at GOOG–HJC–02734893 (Dec. 15, 2006) (introducing Universal Search to help solve
the problem that ‘‘Google search user experience has been internally and externally perceived
as stagnant for the last 7 years’’).
1126
Id. at GOOG–HJC–03804474 (May 23, 2007) (on file with Comm.) (noting ‘‘large in-
creases in absolute coverage for all five purposes, including a 4.5% increase in News and 4%
increase in Local Search’’).
1127
Id. at GOOG–HJC–01230599 (Dec. 8, 2004) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Including some of Urs
ideas around promoting the Labs property on the Google.com results pages for some subset of
users (‘New! Try your search on the next version of Google’). Urs main concern was that Lab
gets limited traffic, and the set of users is not representative of Google’s user base. He didn’t
mind the idea of a Labs launch in principle, but he suggested we show a results page promo
for some small percentage of users to bootstrap traffic to the property with a more diverse set
of users.’’).
1128
See, e.g., id. at GOOG–HJC–01081099 (Oct. 11, 2007) (‘‘We added a ‘cooccurring sites’ sig-
nal to bias ourselves towards triggering when a local-oriented aggregator site (i.e. Citysearch)
shows up in the web results.’’).
1129
Submission from Source 564, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 9 (Nov. 13, 2020) (on file
with Comm.).
1130
Matt Southern, Over 25% of People Click the First Google Search Result, S
EARCH
E
NGINE
J. (July 14, 2020), https://www.searchenginejournal.com/google-first-page-clicks/374516/#close.
1131
Why Page 2 of Google Search Results Is the Best Place to Hide a Dead Body, D
IG
. S
YN
-
OPSIS
(Oct. 29, 2019), https://digitalsynopsis.com/tools/google-serp-design/ (stating that the
first organic result on the first search engine results page receives around 32.5 percent of overall
click-based traffic, the second result receives around 17.6 percent, and the seventh receives 3.5
percent).
Google’s ad revenue by keeping users on Google’s domains for
longer and by compelling demoted firms to pay Google more ad fees
to reach users.
In 2007, Google introduced ‘‘Universal Search,’’ which presented
users with search results that integrated Google’s various special-
ized search services, including Google Images, Google Local, and
Google News.
1124
Universal Search was designed to improve users’
search experience, as well as to increase traffic to Google’s own of-
ferings—even when those offerings weren’t the best or most rel-
evant for users.
1125
Google’s documents suggest that shortly after
launching Universal Search, traffic to Google’s own vertical serv-
ices increased.
1126
Even early in its conception, Google executives
were exploring how Universal Search could be used to show a ‘‘re-
sults page promo’’ to ‘‘bootstrap traffic’’ to Google’s other prod-
ucts.
1127
When Google launched Universal Search, it gave prominent
placement to Google’s vertical content over superior, more relevant
competitors’ products. Google’s documents show that Google ad-
justed its search algorithm to automatically elevate the ranking of
some of Google’s services above those offered by rivals.
1128
These
perks are generally not available to competing verticals, placing
them at an instant disadvantage.
1129
Given that the likelihood that
a user will click on a listing sharply declines with each drop in
placement, traffic to rivals demoted by Google has fallen signifi-
cantly.
1130
The effect is magnified on mobile search, where the
small screen means fewer results are displayed on the first page
of results.
1131
In a submission to the Subcommittee, one vertical search pro-
vider described the practical effects of Google’s discriminatory
treatment:
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00162 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
157
1132
Submission from Source 887, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 4 (Oct. 28, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1133
Submission from Source 925, to H. Comm on the Judiciary, 11 (Nov. 4, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1134
Id.
1135
Id. at 9.
1136
Submission from Source 3, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 32 (Oct. 29, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1137
Amit Singhal & Matt Cutts, Finding More High-Quality Sites in Search, G
OOGLE
: O
FF
.
B
LOG
(Feb. 24, 2011), https://googleblog.blogspot.com/2011/02/finding-more-high-quality-sites-
in.html (defining ‘‘low-quality sites’’ as those that are ‘‘low-value add for users’’ and ‘‘copy con-
tent from other websites or sites that are just not very useful’’ and defining ‘‘high-quality sites’’
as ‘‘sites with original content and information such as research, in-depth reports, thoughtful
analysis and so on’’).
1138
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–00090248 to
–00090249 (Jan 27, 2011) (on file with Comm.).
1139
Submission from Kelkoo, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Kelkoo–0032 (Nov. 4, 2019) (on
file with Comm.).
When the Local OneBox appears on the page, links to [the company’s] website
with highly relevant [results] get pushed down the page into the lower section
for organic search results. This demotion puts [the company] at a competitive
disadvantage relative to Google’s local search results and jeopardizes the health
of [our] business—and this problem is further exacerbated in the growing mobile
context where links to [our] website may be pushed off the small screen or the
first page of search results altogether. In evaluating options to reduce this harm,
[the company] has reached out to Google to explore whether [we] or [our] pro-
viders’ listings on [our] website could be included in Google’s local search results,
but Google has either refused outright or taken no steps to allow such inclu-
sion.
1132
A submission from another vertical search provider stated that
once Google began automatically placing its own competing service
at the top of its search results page, the vertical provider’s organic
search traffic fell by approximately 20 percent.
1133
The vertical pro-
vider observed that Google’s service is worse for users—showing
higher prices and fewer choices than Google’s competitors.
1134
How-
ever, Google continues to give its service top placement, occupying
close to 100 percent of the above-the-fold mobile search results
page and around 25 percent of desktop.
1135
Additional market participants echoed the view that Google’s
self-preferencing comes at the expense of users. One search pro-
vider stated that Google prohibits it from displaying live prices on
Google’s results page, even as Google’s own competing service is
permitted to do so. Stating that there was no procompetitive jus-
tification for this differential treatment, the firm also noted that
Google’s limits on rival vertical search providers likely prevent con-
sumers from seeing the cheapest or best-valued prices.
1136
In addition to placing its vertical offerings at the top of the
search results page, Google has also actively demoted certain rivals
through imposing algorithmic penalties. For example, in 2007 and
in 2011, Google launched an algorithm that demoted sites that
Google considered ‘‘low quality.’’
1137
Among the websites especially
hit were comparison shopping providers, which enable users to
compare product offers from multiple merchant websites.
1138
In a
submission to the Subcommittee, one publisher stated that Google’s
algorithmic penalty caused search leads and revenues to its website
to fall by 85 percent.
1139
Kelkoo, previously a leading comparison
shopping site, explained that Google’s demotion set off a ‘‘cyclic
trend’’ whereby a reduction in traffic leads to fewer consumers,
which leads to fewer listings and less revenue, which leads to re-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00163 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
158
1140
Id. at Kelkoo–0006, Kelkoo–0044.
1141
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–00632668 (on file
with Comm.).
1142
Id. at GOOG–HJC–02507422 (Apr. 4, 2006) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Keep in mind that,
as we discussed, most of the information that is on pages that we create is aggregated from
various sources, and those sources often have that material online already. Because of this, the
search quality team has some concerns as to if/when this Google-created content will be indexed.
And once it is indexed, it is unlikely to appear high in the search results.’’).
1143
Id.
1144
Id.
1145
Id.; see also id. at GOOG–HJC–03201904 (Mar. 22, 2006) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Gen-
erally we like to have the destination page in the index, not the aggregated pages. So if our
local pages are lists of links to other pages, its [sic] more important that we have the other
pages in the index. In addition, our pages would probably not rank well because of this.’’).
1146
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–02507420 (Apr. 5,
2006) (on file with Comm.).
1147
Id. at GOOG–HJC–01069289 (May 6, 2009) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘From a principal per-
spective it would be good if we could actually just crawl our product pages and then have the
rank organically. Problem is that today if we crawl it will never rank.’’).
1148
Interview with Source 147 (June 2019).
duced investment—which, in turn, contributes to a further decline
in traffic, a ‘‘network effect in reverse.’’
1140
In external messaging, Google justified the algorithmic penalties
it imposed on third-party sites as a response to users’ desire to see
fewer ‘‘low quality’’ sites in their search results.
1141
However,
Google did not subject its own vertical sites to the same algorithmic
demotion, even though Google’s vertical services aggregated and
copied content from around the web—just like the third-party sites
that Google had demoted.
1142
Indeed, Google’s documents reveal
that employees knew Google’s own vertical sites would likely fit the
demotion criteria that Google applied to other sites. When one em-
ployee suggested that Google index its comparison shopping site,
Froogle, another responded that it was unlikely Froogle would get
crawled ‘‘without special treatment,’’ noting, ‘‘We’d probably have
to provide a lot of special treatment to this content in order to have
it be crawled, indexed, and rank well.’’
1143
Despite the fact that Google’s own comparison shopping service
was of such low quality that Google’s product team couldn’t even
get it indexed, Google continued to give Froogle top placement on
its search results page, listing its results in the OneBox, a display
box that Google populates with information on its search results
page.
1144
Bill Brougher, a product manager, acknowledged that
Google was privileging low-quality content, writing:
Our algorithms specifically look for pages like [Froogle’s] to either demote or re-
move from our index, and there are active projects to improve the integration
into web search. The bigger problem these projects have is to improve their own
result quality. For instance with Froogle, the onebox trigger is now very good
and relevant, but the three results we show from Froogle in that onebox gen-
erally rate very low in our search quality evaluation. It is often the same with
Local.
1145
Another Google team member replied: ‘‘Yes, you’re right that the
Onebox result items often stink.’’
1146
A few years later, a Google
employee again acknowledged that, if Google ranked its own con-
tent according to the same criteria that it applied to competitors,
‘‘it will never rank.’’
1147
In an interview with the Subcommittee, one vertical site stated
that Google had not only demoted the firm, but had in at least one
instance removed it from Google’s index entirely.
1148
The search
provider stated that, after Google purchased its rival, Google de-
moted the provider in search rankings while vaulting those of its
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00164 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
159
1149
Id.
1150
Id.
1151
Sam Schechner, Kristen Grind & John West, Searching for Video? Google Pushes
YouTube over Rivals, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (July 14, 2020), https://www.wsj.com/articles/google-steers-
users-to-youtube-over-rivals-11594745232.
1152
Id.
1153
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 408 (response to Questions for the Record
of Adam Cohen, Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC).
1154
Submission from Source 3, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 32 (Oct. 29, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1155
Submission from Source 972, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 9 (Dec. 9, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1156
Id.
1157
Id.
rival.
1149
The search provider observed that Google’s demotions
sometimes followed favorable press that highlighted the search pro-
vider’s popularity with users. ‘‘There was an article that came out
in the press that painted [us] in a positive light and quoted an ex-
ecutive noting that [we are] the top result when a user searches
[for a particular search term]. The next day, Google de-indexed [us]
for [that search term].’’
1150
In July, The Wall Street Journal reported that Google also gives
preferential treatment to YouTube.
1151
Tests conducted by the
Journal found that searching Google for videos delivered YouTube
in results much more prominently than competing video providers,
even when competitor videos had more engagement. Reflecting
interviews with those familiar with the matter, the piece stated
that Google engineers:
[M]ade changes that effectively preference YouTube over other video sources.
Google executives in recent years made decisions to prioritize YouTube on the
first page of search results, in part to drive traffic to YouTube rather than to
competitors, and also to give YouTube more leverage in business deals with con-
tent providers seeking traffic for their videos.
1152
In response to Questions for the Record from Subcommittee
Chair David N. Cicilline (D–RI), the company denied that Google
Search is designed to favor YouTube. Although Google stated that
it disagreed with the methodology used by the Journal, Google did
not provide the Subcommittee with any data or internal reports
that would support its claim.
1153
Numerous market participants noted that Google’s favoring of its
own sites and demoting those of third parties have effectively in-
creased their cost of distribution. Since demoted sites can generally
only recover traffic through advertising on Google, the platform ‘‘es-
sentially requires competitors to pay for their websites to appear
above Google’s own links,’’ according to one market participant.
1154
Another business recalled that, in 2016, Google demoted one of its
vertical offerings, citing a policy of diversifying content.
1155
The
firm stated that, once it was penalized in organic rankings, it
‘‘could not get an appropriate customer service response for
months’’ and ultimately ‘‘had to increase [marketing spend on
Google] to regain lost traffic—a win-win for Google but a loss for
[our business] and its users.’’
1156
Meanwhile, Google’s own competing vertical ‘‘is always listed at
the top’’ of search results.
1157
The incident highlights how demot-
ing rivals can enrich Google in two ways: first, through diverting
greater traffic and business to its own products; and second,
through earning ad revenues from the penalized sites that are sub-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00165 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
160
1158
Submission from Source 115, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 16 (Oct. 22, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
1159
Submission from Celebrity Net Worth, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 10 (Oct. 14, 2019)
(on file with Comm.).
1160
Submission from Foundem, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 42 (Oct. 22, 2019) (on file with
Comm.). Foundem was the lead complainant in the European Commission’s antitrust investiga-
tion and case on Google Shopping.
1161
Interview with Source 507 (July 10, 2019).
1162
Id.
1163
Id.
sequently scrambling to recover their search placement. When de-
moting firms that Google views as actual or potential competitive
threats, Google is effectively raising rivals’ costs.
Another firm noted that demoted vertical providers that go on to
buy ads on Google not only feed revenue to a potential or actual
competitor in specialized search, but also risk handing Google more
commercially sensitive information. The market participant wrote:
Google thus deceptively siphons internet traffic away from its vertical competi-
tors in online travel and forces them to pay more for [search engine monetiza-
tion] and [] Ads in order to get meaningful placement on Google’s [search engine
results page]. Importantly, Google also requires its vertical competitors to pro-
vide their inventory feed to populate the ads, allowing Google to appropriate
vertical service providers’ valuable inventory data.
1158
A significant number of the website publishers that the Sub-
committee interviewed noted the outsized effect that a single algo-
rithmic change by Google can have on their business. Brian War-
ner, Celebrity Net Worth founder, stated, ‘‘All website owners live
in constant fear of Google’s algorithm updates. Without explanation
or recourse, Google can deliver a fatal blow to a website’s search
ranking visibility.’’
1159
Foundem, the UK-based comparison shop-
ping site, wrote, ‘‘An unjustified Google search penalty, whether
imposed anticompetitively or in error, has the power to cause grave
and irreparable harm to virtually any online business.’’
1160
(3) Threatening Innovation and the Open Internet. Through mis-
appropriating third-party content and giving preferential treatment
to its own vertical sites, Google abused its gatekeeper power over
online search to coerce vertical websites to surrender valuable data
and to leverage its search dominance into adjacent markets.
Google’s conduct both thwarted competition and diminished the in-
centive of vertical providers to invest in new and innovative offer-
ings.
In an interview with the Subcommittee, one market participant
observed that Google’s conduct has sapped investment, as ‘‘inves-
tors don’t want to invest in companies that are producing content
that relies on Google traffic,’’ resulting in ‘‘less capital invested in
companies reliant on traffic from Google.’’
1161
The website noted
that Google’s business practices have also skewed the website’s
own investment decisions, leading it to allocate the vast majority
of its revenue to creating ‘‘news-like temporary content’’ rather
than ‘‘evergreen content.’’
1162
It added, ‘‘If we could trust that
Google was not engaging in unfair search practices, we would be
producing different content.’’
1163
A vertical provider, meanwhile, said that Google’s conduct had
held the firm’s growth ‘‘at bay’’ and risks reducing innovation over
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00166 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
161
1164
Submission from Source 564, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 4 (Nov. 13, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
1165
Id.
1166
P
IPER
J
AFFRAY
, I
NTRODUCING
R
EVIEW
G
ROWTH FOR
Y
ELP VS
. G
OOGLE
P
LUS
(Apr. 16, 2014)
(on file with Comm.).
1167
Id.
1168
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 359 (statement from Brian Warner, Found-
er, Celebrity Net Worth).
1169
See, e.g., Submission from Source 972, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 9 (Dec. 9, 2019)
(on file with Comm.) (‘‘As opposed to cataloguing the internet and sending travelers to the most
relevant websites, Google is instead creating a walled garden, using its place at the top of the
internet funnel to ensure that the majority of users transact on Google’s own pages and prod-
ucts.’’).
1170
Google Inc., Registration Statement (Form S–1) app. B at B–6 (2004), https://www
.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1288776/000119312504139655/ds1a.htm.
1171
Rand Fishkin, Less than Half of All Google Searches Now Result in a Click, S
PARKTORO
(Aug. 13, 2019), https://sparktoro.com/blog/less-than-half-of-google-searches-now-result-in-a-
click/.
the long term, as providers whose growth is capped by Google may
be more reluctant to invest and expand.
1164
It added:
Competitors are not the only ones who have a reduced incentive to innovate as
a result of Google’s conduct. The anticompetitive effects reduce Google’s own in-
centives to improve the quality of its services, because it does not need to com-
pete on the merits with rival services.
1165
To illustrate this point, Yelp offers a contrast between its own ef-
forts to maintain high-quality user reviews and Google’s efforts. It
states that, of the approximately 150 million user reviews sub-
mitted to Yelp since 2005, Yelp has displayed only 72 percent of
them to users, while flagging 21 percent as ‘‘not recommended.’’
1166
Yelp cites investment research noting that Google, by contrast,
does not invest in curating its reviews: ‘‘25% of Google’s reviews
have zero characters and are simply Netflix-style one-click star rat-
ings from which the user can derive few, if any, insights about the
trustworthiness of the submission.’’
1167
Several market participants told the Subcommittee that Google’s
business practices in online search have already foreclosed oppor-
tunity. In a submission, Celebrity Net Worth founder Brian Warner
wrote:
It is my view that Google has removed essentially all of the oxygen from the
open internet ecosystem. There is no longer any incentive or even basic oppor-
tunity to innovate as I did back in 2008. If someone came to me with an idea
for a website or a web service today, I would tell them to run. Run as far away
from the web as possible. Launch a lawn care business or a dog grooming busi-
ness—something Google can’t take away as soon as he or she is thriving.
1168
More broadly, market participants expressed concern that Google
has evolved from a ‘‘turnstile’’ to the rest of the web to a ‘‘walled
garden’’ that increasingly keeps users within its sites.
1169
Many ob-
servers have noted that when Google filed its initial public offering,
Google cofounder Larry Page identified the company’s mission as
the following: ‘‘We want you to come to Google and quickly find
what you want. We want you to get you out of Google and to the
right place as fast as possible.’’
1170
In recent years, however, stud-
ies have shown that more than half of all queries on Google either
terminate on Google or result in a click to Google’s own prop-
erties—a share that is growing over time.
1171
In July, The Markup
published results showing that Google allocated 41 percent of the
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00167 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
162
1172
Adrianne Jeffries & Leon Yin, Google’s Top Search Result? Surprise! It’s Google, M
ARKUP
(July 28, 2020), https://themarkup.org/google-the-giant/2020/07/28/google-search-results-
prioritize-google-products-over-competitors.
1173
See, e.g., Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 433–435 (response to Questions
for the Record of Adam Cohen, Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC); CEO Hearing at 337 (response
to Questions for the Record from Sundar Pichai, CEO, Alphabet Inc.).
1174
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 433–35 (response to Questions for the
Record of Adam Cohen, Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC); id. at 437 (statement of Adam Cohen,
Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC).
1175
Letter from Kent Walker, Senior Vice President, Glob. Affs. & Chief Legal Officer, Google,
to Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the
H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 1 (July 26, 2019).
1176
Id. at 2.
1177
In a September 2020 response to Chair Cicilline on this same question, Google disputed
Fishkin’s analysis of the data. Google wrote: ‘‘The fact that a user does not click on a link on
a Google Search results page does not mean that the user has been ‘kept’ on Google properties.
Searches on Google may result in zero website clicks for many reasons, which is not discernable
without directly asking the user why they did not click a link.’’ CEO Hearing at 338 (response
to Questions for the Record of Sundar Pichai, CEO, Alphabet Inc.).
1178
Memorandum from Staff, Fed. Trade Comm’n, to the Commission iii (Aug. 8, 2012), in
The FTC Report on Google’s Business Practices, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (Mar. 24, 2015), http://graph-
ics.wsj.com/google-ftc-report/.
1179
Id. at 80.
1180
Id. at 86.
1181
Google Search (Shopping) Comm’n Decision ¶ 671.
first search results page on mobile devices to Google’s own con-
tent.
1172
On several occasions over the course of the investigation, Sub-
committee Chair David N. Cicilline (D–RI) asked Google about this
trend.
1173
At the Subcommittee’s July 16, 2019 hearing, Google’s
Director of Economic Policy, Adam Cohen, stated that Google’s goal
is ‘‘to provide users information as quickly and efficiently as pos-
sible,’’ adding that he was ‘‘not familiar’’ with studies showing that
a majority of queries now terminate on Google.
1174
In its July 26,
2019 response to a follow-up letter from Chair Cicilline, Google
wrote that it strives to ‘‘give users the most relevant, highest qual-
ity information as quickly as possible,’’ a goal that Google claims
is ‘‘[c]onsistent with Mr. Page’s comments in 2004.’’
1175
When
asked whether it was true that less than 50 percent of all searches
on Google resulted in clicks to non-Google websites, Google re-
sponded that it ‘‘has long sent large amounts of traffic to other
sites.’’
1176
In response to the Subcommittee’s request for query
metrics that would document the underlying trends, however,
Google did not produce the relevant data.
1177
Several enforcement bodies have examined these business prac-
tices. Between 2011 and 2013, the Federal Trade Commission pur-
sued an inquiry into Google’s data misappropriation and self-
preferencing, among other conduct. Staff at the Bureau of Competi-
tion concluded that ‘‘the natural and probable effect’’ of Google’s
misappropriation was ‘‘to diminish the incentives of vertical
websites to invest in, and to develop, new and innovative con-
tent.’’
1178
On Google’s self-preferencing, staff concluded that
Google’s conduct had ‘‘resulted in anticompetitive effects,’’
1179
but
that Google had offered ‘‘strong procompetitive justifica-
tions.’’
1180
In 2017, the European Commission concluded that
Google’s self-preferencing in comparison shopping services con-
stituted an illegal abuse of dominance and ordered Google to imple-
ment a remedy of ‘‘equal treatment.’’
1181
The European Commis-
sion stated that Google had not ‘‘provided verifiable evidence to
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00168 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
163
1182
Summary of Google Search (Shopping) Comm’n Decision, 2018 O.J. (C 9) 11, 13, ¶ 26
(Jan. 12, 2018), https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52018XC
0112(01)&from=EN.
1183
Press Release, Google, Google Launches Self-Service Advertising Program (Oct. 23, 2000),
http://googlepress.blogspot.com/2000/10/google-launches-self-service.html.
1184
Submission from Source 115, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 6 (Oct. 22, 2019) (on file with
Comm.) (citing Megan Graham, Amazon Is Eating into Google’s Most Important Business:
Search Advertising, CNBC (Oct. 15, 2019), https://www.cnbc.com/2019/10/15/amazon-is-
eating-into-googles-dominance-in-search-ads.html).
1185
Submission from Source 3, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 8 (Oct. 29, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1186
Alistair Barr & Garrit De Vynck, Airlines, Hotels and Other Brands Are Tired of Paying
Google for Their Own Names, B
LOOMBERG
(Mar. 9, 2019); see also Mark Irvine, Average Cost
per Click by Country: Where in the World Are the Highest CPCs?, W
ORDSTREAM
B
LOG
(Nov. 8,
2018), https://www.wordstream.com/blog/ws/2015/07/06/average-cost-per-click (showing that
the cost-per-click that Google charges search advertisers in the United States is notably higher
than the rate it charges in countries where Google faces more competition).
prove that its conduct is indispensable’’ to any procompetitive ef-
fects.
1182
(ii) Google Increased Prices for Market Access and Degraded
Search Quality. In 2000, Google launched AdWords, which allowed
advertisers to pay for keyword-based ads that would appear to the
right of Google’s search results.
1183
In the years since, Google has
changed the display of the ads on its search engine results page in
several ways, most notably by (1) increasing the number of ads
placed above organic search results, and (2) blurring the distinction
between how ads and organic listings are presented on Google’s
search results page. These changes have effectively raised the price
that businesses must pay to access users through Google. Market
participants told the Subcommittee that Google’s conduct has un-
dermined competition, misled consumers, and degraded the overall
quality of Google’s search results—all while enabling Google to fur-
ther exploit its monopoly over general online search.
Google’s clear dominance in online search also gives it significant
control over the search advertising market. Publicly available data
suggests Google captured around 73 percent of the search adver-
tising market in 2019.
1184
Submissions from market participants
show that many firms spend the vast majority of their ad budgets
on Google. For example, one major vertical provider spent signifi-
cantly more than half of its total ad spend on Google each year
from 2016 to 2019, with the second top provider receiving less than
15 percent.
1185
Public reporting suggests that, as of 2019, Google
had increased the price of search ads by about five percent per
year, exceeding the U.S. inflation rate at that time of 1.6 per-
cent.
1186
Several market participants told the Subcommittee that their ad
spend on Google has increased in large part because Google has
made it more difficult for businesses to obtain organic traffic. Part-
ly, this follows from Google’s preferencing of its own products,
which compels demoted firms to pay Google for ad placement as a
way to regain visibility. Another notable factor has been Google’s
decision to increase the number of ads posted above organic search
results.
Prior to 2016, Google’s design of its search results page placed
eight ads to the right of organic search listings and three ads above
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00169 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
164
1187
Dr. Peter J. Meyers, Four Ads on Top: The Wait Is Over, M
OZ
(Feb. 19, 2016), https://
moz.com/blog/four-ads-on-top-the-wait-is-over.
1188
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–02981172 to
–02981173 (Aug. 12, 2011) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘RHS CTR has been steadily dropping over
time to today’s level. For the best ads on the RHS, some indication that CTR is lower than qual-
ity would suggest it should be.’’); id. at GOOG–HJC–02983169 to –02983193 (Aug. 12, 2011)
(stating that RHS is 16.5 percent of search revenue, 26 percent of queries have a RHS ad,
and‘‘[o]pportunity is accelerating due to declining RHS CTR’’).
1189
Id. at GOOG–HJC–02983830 (Feb. 16, 2011).
1190
Id. at GOOG–HJC–00482674 to –00482676 (Aug. 18, 2011).
1191
Matt McGee, Confirmed: Google to Stop Showing Ads on Right Side of Desktop Search
Results Worldwide, S
EARCH
E
NGINE
L
AND
(Feb. 19, 2016), https://searchengineland.com/google-
no-ads-right-side-of-desktop-search-results-242997.
1192
Gerrit De Vynck, Google Search Upgrades Make It Harder for Websites to Win Traffic,
B
LOOMBERG
(July 13, 2020), https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2020-07-13/how-google-
search-changes-make-it-more-expensive-to-win-traffic.
1193
See, e.g., Submission from Source 972, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 14 (Dec. 9, 2019)
(on file with Comm.); Submission from Source 115, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 10 (Oct. 22,
2019) (on file with Comm.); Submission from Source 3, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 34 (Oct.
29, 2019) (on file with Comm.); Competitors Hearing at 28 (statement of David Heinemeier
Hansson, Cofounder & Chief Tech. Officer, Basecamp).
1194
Submission from Source 972, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 14 (Dec. 9, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
them.
1187
Google’s internal communications show that, as of 2011,
the rate of user engagement with right-hand side ads was declin-
ing.
1188
Since Google made money from search ads only when users
clicked on them, less user engagement meant those ads were be-
coming less valuable to Google. In February 2011, Sridhar
Ramaswamy, senior vice president of ads at Google, noted that
‘‘users are no longer looking at the [right-hand side ads],’’ and stat-
ed that Google either needed to ‘‘retrain people to look there by
putting really good stuff there,’’ or ‘‘live with the fact that users are
going to stop looking there.’’
1189
By August 2011, a team at Google
known as ‘‘Project Manhattan’’ was working on a redesign of
Google’s desktop search results page that focused on reducing or
eliminating right-hand side ads.
1190
In 2016, Google rolled out the redesigned page, which eliminated
the right-hand side ads while adding a fourth ad above organic list-
ings and three at the bottom of the page.
1191
The practical effect
of adding a fourth ad at the top of the search results page was to
push organic listings further down, requiring users to scroll down
further before reaching a non-paid result. According to Bloomberg,
when Google tested the addition of a fourth ad, some employees ob-
jected on the grounds that the fourth ad would be of lower quality
than the first organic result, but Google altered the search results
page anyway.
1192
Google’s decision to monetize a fourth ad at the expense of an or-
ganic listing fits a broader pattern of steps taken by Google to rank
search results based on what is best for Google, rather than what
is best for search users—be it preferencing its own vertical sites or
allocating more space for ads. Several market participants noted
that Google could afford to make these changes only once it had
achieved a dominant position in the market for general search and
search advertising.
1193
Now that Google is ‘‘unconstrained by com-
petitors,’’ one market participant noted, it ‘‘consistently reserves
the top of the [search engine results page] for its own vertical prod-
ucts or advertisements paid for through search engine marketing,
pushing its rivals’ organic results to the bottom, regardless of how
relevant or useful they might be.’’
1194
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00170 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
165
1195
Submission from Source 3, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 33 (Oct. 29, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1196
Id.
1197
Prepared by the Subcommittee.
Internal data shown by one market participant to the Sub-
committee demonstrates that ‘‘organic search listings have been
pushed down over time, and ‘click-throughs’ (clicking to visit a site)
on the first organic results have decreased by two-thirds over the
past 3 years.’’
1195
The market participant’s analysis also shows
that the first organic listing on mobile now appears on the bottom
of the third search results screen, which ‘‘effectively forces adver-
tising customers to bid for a paid advertisement listing if they want
their service or product to meaningfully reach consumers in a mo-
bile search.’’
1196
Google Search on Desktop Ad Placement
1197
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00171 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 11 here 11701.011
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
166
1198
Prepared by the Subcommittee.
Google Search on Mobile Phone
1198
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00172 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 12 here 11701.012
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
167
1199
Prepared by the Subcommittee.
Google Search on Desktop
1199
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00173 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 13 here 11701.013
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
168
1200
Prepared by the Subcommittee.
1201
Rand Fishkin, Less than Half of Google Searches Now Result in a Click, S
PARKTORO
(Aug.
13, 2019), https://sparktoro.com/blog/less-than-half-of-google-searches-now-result-in-a-click/.
1202
Id. (showing organic fell from 41.1 percent in January 2016 to 26.68 percent in June
2019, a period over which paid click-through rates increased from 3.29 percent to 11.38 percent).
Google Search on Mobile Phone
1200
One result of these changes is that users click less on organic
search results. As Google has reduced the share of top real estate
that it devotes to organic listings, studies show that organic click-
through as a share of all click-through plus zero-click searches has
fallen.
1201
According to an analysis by Rand Fishkin, the trend is
especially pronounced in mobile, where organic click-through rates
fell by more than 30 percent between January 2016 and June 2019,
while paid click-through rates over that same period more than tri-
pled.
1202
For businesses that depend on Google to reach users, these
trends amount to a toll hike, as traffic that firms could previously
draw through organic listings is now increasingly pay-for-play. In-
stead of competing for users by offering high-quality webpages and
services that should lead to better organic search listings, these
businesses must now compete for users based on how much money
they pay Google. Several market participants analogized Google to
a gatekeeper that is extorting users for access to its critical dis-
tribution channel.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00174 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 14 here 11701.014
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
169
1203
Competitors Hearing at 62 (statement of David Heinemeier Hansson, Cofounder & Chief
Tech. Officer, Basecamp) (‘‘Today, if a consumer goes to Google on their mobile device and
search [sic] for Basecamp, the first thing that they will find is whoever bought that trademark
term, which is usually one of our competitors. Ergo, consumers are not finding what they are
looking for .... They are being presented with an ad and that is the tollbooth that [Google is]
erecting.’’).
1204
Id. at 23.
1205
Id.
1206
Id.
1207
Jason Fried (@jasonfried), T
WITTER
(Sept. 3, 2019, 4:39 p.m.), https://twitter.com/
jasonfried/status/1168986962704982016?lang=en.
1208
Submission from Source 3, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 32 (Oct. 29, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
At the Subcommittee’s January 2020 field hearing in Colorado,
David Heinemeier Hansson, chief technology officer and cofounder
of Basecamp, testified that Google’s decision to increase the num-
ber of ads listed above organic search results has hurt search
users.
1203
Expanding on his criticism, Hansson stated that Google’s
decision to sell ad placement against a company’s brand name is
another way that Google extracts revenue from dependent busi-
nesses.
Hansson said, ‘‘Google uses this monopoly to extort businesses
like ours to pay for the privilege that consumers who search for our
trademarked brand name can find us because if we don’t they will
sell our brand name as misdirection to our competitors.’’
1204
He
noted that, while Google purports to recognize trademark law by
prohibiting the use of trademark terms in ad copy, Google ‘‘puts the
onus of enforcement on victims and does nothing to stop repeat of-
fenders, unless, of course, the trademark terms are belonging to
Google itself.’’
1205
Hansson added, ‘‘You will find no competitor ads
for any of Google’s own important properties.’’
1206
Basecamp’s Ad
1207
Other market participants generally echoed these views in sub-
missions to the Subcommittee. One wrote that Google ‘‘effectively
forces its advertising customers to pay for the ability to reach con-
sumers who are searching specifically for the customer’s
brand.’’
1208
The business added, ‘‘Facing no remotely comparable
advertising and search engine alternative, Google has the ability to
charge potentially inflated prices for its advertising services by
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00175 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 15 here 11701.015
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
170
1209
Id.
1210
Ginny Marvin, A Visual History of Google Ad Labeling in Search Results, S
EARCH
E
NGINE
L
AND
(Jan. 28, 2020), https://searchengineland.com/search-ad-labeling-history-google-bing-
254332.
1211
Google Hotel Ads, G
OOGLE
, https://ads.google.com/hotels/ (last visited Oct. 5, 2020) (of-
fering paid listings to hotels, but neglecting to designate these listings as ‘‘ads’’ on the search
results page).
forcing customers to increase their bids in order to receive a more
favorable position.’’
1209
A second factor that several third parties cited as contributing to
both higher ad prices and the degradation of search for users is
Google’s effort over the years to blur the distinction between or-
ganic listings and paid ads.
Google’s Ad Shading and Labeling: 2007–2013
1210
The diagram above depicts Google’s practice, between 2007 and
2013, of labeling its paid ads with a shaded background. As shown
below, in 2013, Google abandoned the shaded background and in-
stead inserted a small yellow square that states ‘‘Ad.’’ Since 2016,
Google has made various changes that make ads more subtle, cul-
minating in a label that renders the overall appearance of paid ads
much more similar to organic listings. Market participants have
noted that Google also neglects to label some paid ads entirely, par-
ticularly those that appear in Google’s vertical search offerings,
such as listings for hotels that appear alongside maps.
1211
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00176 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 16 here 11701.016
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
171
1212
Ginny Marvin, A Visual History of Google Ad Labeling in Search Results, S
EARCH
E
NGINE
L
AND
(Jan. 28, 2020), https://searchengineland.com/search-ad-labeling-history-google-bing-
254332.
1213
Mark Jones, Two-Thirds of People Don’t Know the Difference Between Google Paid and
Organic Search Results, M
ARKETING
T
ECH
N
EWS
(Sept. 6, 2018), https://marketingtechnews
.net/news/2018/sep/06/two-thirds-people-dont-know-difference-between-google-paid-and-organic
-search-results/.
1214
Letter from Mary K. Engle, Assoc. Dir. for Advert. Pracs., Fed. Trade Comm’n (June 24,
2013), https://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/attachments/press-releases/ftc-consumer-protec-
tion-staff-updates-agencys-guidance-search-engine-industryon-need-distinguish/130625search
enginegeneralletter.pdf.
Google’s Ad Shading and Labeling: 2013–2019
1212
The natural result of Google’s decision to blur the distinction be-
tween paid ads and organic listings is that users click on more ads
and fewer organic search results. This misleading practice has like-
ly contributed to the growth of paid click-through rates on Google.
One study found that over 59 percent of consumers were not aware
of the difference between organic results and paid ads on Google,
and about 34 percent of those who did recognize paid ads said they
would deliberately avoid clicking on them.
1213
The Federal Trade
Commission (FTC) has recognized that search engines that fail to
‘‘prominently distinguish’’ paid ads from organic listings could be
liable for deceiving consumers under Section 5 of the FTC Act.
1214
Making ads less conspicuous makes it more likely that users will
unwittingly click on them. Market participants note that, like
Google’s decision to increase the number and prominence of paid
ads, Google’s decision to blur the distinction between paid listings
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00177 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 17 here 11701.017
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
172
1215
Submission from Source 115, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 10–12 (Oct. 22, 2019) (on
file with Comm.); Submission from Source 972, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 21 (Dec. 9, 2019)
(on file with Comm.); Submission from Source 3, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Oct. 29, 2019)
(on file with Comm.).
1216
Submission from Source 3, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 32 (Oct. 29, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1217
Interview with Source 507 (July 10, 2019).
1218
Competitors Hearing at 32 (statement of David Heinemeier Hansson, Cofounder & Chief
Tech. Officer, Basecamp).
1219
CEO Hearing at 72 (question of Rep. David N. Cicilline (D–RI), Chair, Subcomm. on
Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm on the Judiciary); Submission from
Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–01099375 (Mar. 30, 2012) (on file with
Comm.); Sergey Brin & Larry Page, The Anatomy of a Large-Scale Hypertextual Search Engine,
S
TANFORD
U
NIV
. I
NFO
L
AB
, http://infolab.stanford.edu/#backrub/google.html (last visited Oct. 4,
2020) (expressing reservations about an ad-based business model, noting that ‘‘the goals of the
advertising business model do not always correspond to providing quality search to users,’’ and
given the conflicting motives that a search engine might face between serving users the most
relevant information and selling more ads, arguing that ‘‘advertising funded search engines will
be inherently biased towards the advertisers and away from the needs of the consumers’’).
1220
CEO Hearing at 72 (question of Rep. David N. Cicilline (D–RI), Chair, Subcomm. on
Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
1221
Id. (statement of Sundar Pichai, CEO, Alphabet Inc.); Submission from Google, to H.
Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–01099375 (Mar. 30, 2012) (on file with Comm.).
and organic results deceives consumers and compels businesses to
purchase ads from Google in order to be located by users.
1215
In submissions and interviews with the Subcommittee, busi-
nesses noted that higher advertising costs come at the expense of
investments in innovation and consumer benefits.
1216
One vertical
search provider stated:
If the search market were fair, the internet would have four times more content
on it, dramatically improving the web for consumers. Google’s gatekeeper power
allows it to show more advertisements for search queries with higher commercial
intent .... The harm to consumers is not necessarily a lack of content, but a lack
of quality content (requiring money to produce).
1217
At the Subcommittee’s January 2020 field hearing, Hansson tes-
tified that Google’s conduct, which harms business customers and
users alike, is enabled by its dominance:
Google’s monopoly on internet search must be broken up for the sake of a fair
marketplace. Google would never be able to get away with such a user-hostile
design as showing a full-page ad for something other than what you were search-
ing for, if it had real competition. They would never have been able to establish
their monopoly if this had been the design from the get-go. These are the monop-
oly spoils of complete domination.
1218
At the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Subcommittee Chair David
N. Cicilline (D–RI) noted that Google’s search results page now fea-
tures more ads and more of Google’s own sites and asked Google
CEO Sundar Pichai whether this trend highlights a misalignment
of Google’s incentives.
1219
He asked, ‘‘Isn’t there a fundamental
conflict of interest between serving users who want to access the
best and most relevant information and Google’s business model,
which incentivizes Google to sell ads and keep users on Google’s
own sites?’’
1220
In response, Mr. Pichai stated that Google has ‘‘al-
ways focused on providing users the most relevant information,’’
and stated that Google shows ads ‘‘only for a small subset of que-
ries where the intent from users is highly commercial.’’
1221
How-
ever, Mr. Pichai did not explain why the percentage of queries for
which Google shows ads would implicate whether or not Google’s
business model compromises the integrity of its search results.
Google also failed to produce data that would enable the Sub-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00178 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
173
1222
Alphabet Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 10 (Feb. 3, 2020), https://www.sec.gov/
Archives/edgar/data/1652044/000165204420000008/goog10-k2019.htm.
1223
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 10.
1224
Id.
1225
See generally Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n Report.
1226
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 211.
1227
Stacking the Tech: Has Google Harmed Competition in Online Advertising?: Hearing Be-
fore the S. Subcomm. on Antitrust and Consumer Rights of the S. Comm. on the Judiciary, 116th
Cong. (2019), https://www.judiciary.senate.gov/meetings/stacking-the-tech-has-google-harmed-
competition-in-online-advertising.
1228
Sara Forden & David McLaughlin, DOJ Scrutinizes Google Advertising, Search in Anti-
trust Probe, B
LOOMBERG
(Aug. 8, 2019), https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2019-08-08/
doj-scrutinizes-google-advertising-search-in-antitrust-probe.
committee to make an independent assessment of Mr. Pichai’s as-
sertion.
3. Digital Advertisements
(a) Overview and Dominance. Google makes the vast majority of
its revenue by selling advertising placement across the internet. In
2019, Google’s ad revenue accounted for approximately 83.3 percent
of Alphabet’s overall sales.
1222
Google is a prominent player in both
search advertising and digital display advertising, and it captures
over 50 percent of the market across the ad tech stack, or the set
of intermediaries that advertisers and publishers must use to buy,
sell, and place ads. Specifically, Google runs the leading ad ex-
change, while also running buy-side and sell-side intermediary
platforms’ trade on the exchange.
1223
Internationally, antitrust enforcers are currently investigating
Google’s dominance in digital advertising, including the United
Kingdom’s Competition and Markets Authority (CMA),
1224
and the
Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC).
1225
In
July 2020, the CMA concluded that Google has ‘‘significant market
power’’ in search advertising and its market power had enabled it
to charge prices 30–40 percent higher than those set by
Bing.
1226
In September 2020, the Senate Judiciary Committee held
a hearing on the effects of Google’s dominance in digital ads, where
members expressed bipartisan concern that Google’s market power
across the ad tech stack was enabling anticompetitive conduct and
harming publishers and advertisers alike.
1227
Lastly, public reports
note that both the Justice Department and several state attorneys
general are investigating Google’s market power and conduct in
digital ads, with reports that a lawsuit may be imminent.
1228
In
light of the extensive attention already given to this issue, a com-
prehensive examination of the digital advertising market is beyond
the scope of this Report.
Market participants and Google’s documents suggest that Google
is likely to maintain its lead in search and display advertising due
to high entry barriers. Most critically, as other sections of this Re-
port found, Google can mine its ecosystem—including Search,
Chrome, Android, and Maps—to combine a unique set of user data
points and build troves of online behavioral data that drive its ad
business. Furthermore, its dominance across markets increasingly
enables Google to set the terms of commerce. One third party de-
scribed:
Google is now not only a seller and broker of digital advertising across the Inter-
net, but they now also control significant portions of the web browsers, operating
systems, and platforms upon which these digital ads are delivered. This gives
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00179 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
174
1229
Submission from Source 688, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Oct. 24, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1230
Dina Srinivasan, Why Google Dominates Advertising Markets, 24 S
TAN
. T
ECH
. L. R
EV
. 55,
63–64 (2020).
1231
CEO Hearing at 169 (Rep. Pramila Jayapal (D–WA), Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust,
Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm on the Judiciary).
1232
Id. at 170.
1233
Data compiled by the Congressional Research Service (on file with Comm.).
1234
Louise Story & Miguel Helft, Google Buys DoubleClick for $3.1 Billion, N.Y. T
IMES
(Apr.
14, 2007), https://www.nytimes.com/2007/04/14/technology/14DoubleClick.html.
1235
Id. See also The DoubleClick Ad Exchange, G
OOGLE
, https://static.googleusercontent
.com/media/www.google.com/en//adexchange/AdExchangeOverview.pdf (last visited Oct. 4,
2020).
1236
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04189346 (July 26,
2006) (on file with Comm.).
1237
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04189347.
Google the ability to single-handedly shift an entire ecosystem in nearly any di-
rection they decide, based simply on their scale. Google can then use its domi-
nance to demand a higher share of ad revenues from buyers and sellers, and
there is little leverage available to counteract this position in a negotiation.
1229
One key factor that market participants and industry experts
cite when accounting for why Google is likely to maintain its domi-
nance in digital ads is its conflict of interest. With a sizable share
in the ad exchange market and the ad intermediary market, and
as a leading supplier of ad space, Google simultaneously acts on be-
half of publishers and advertisers, while also trading for itself—a
set of conflicting interests that market participants say enable
Google to favor itself and create significant information
asymmetries from which Google benefits.
1230
At the Subcommit-
tee’s sixth hearing, Representative Pramila Jayapal (D–WA) ques-
tioned Google CEO Sundar Pichai about this conflict of interest:
So, [Google is] running the marketplace, it’s acting on the buy side, and it’s act-
ing on the sell side at the same time, which is a major conflict of interest. It
allows you to set rates very low as a buyer of ad space from newspapers, depriv-
ing them of their ad revenue, and then also to sell high to small businesses who
are very dependent on advertising on your platform. It sounds a bit like a stock
market, except, unlike a stock market, there’s no regulation on your ad exchange
market.
1231
Mr. Pichai responded by citing the sums that Google has paid to
publishers, describing it as a ‘‘low-margin business’’ for Google that
it pursues ‘‘because we want to help support publishers.’’
1232
Google’s overall margins have averaged over 20 percent for nine of
the last ten years.
1233
(b) Merger Activity. Google came to control a sizable market
share across the ad tech stack through acquisitions. Google ac-
quired DoubleClick in 2007 for $3.1 billion.
1234
At the time of the
acquisition, The New York Times described DoubleClick as a
‘‘Nasdaq-like exchange for online ads,’’ and Google’s own early de-
scription of DoubleClick describes it as ‘‘a stock exchange,’’ such as
‘‘the NYSE.’’
1235
Google purchased DoubleClick to enter the display
advertising market, a segment that Google’s internal documents
calculated at around $4.3 billion in 2006—and an area where
Google at the time noted it ‘‘has no meaningful presence.’’
1236
A
presentation from July 2006 included a slide titled ‘‘Build a Self-
Reinforcing Online Ads Ecosystem,’’ which noted that acquiring
DoubleClick or Atlas could create these ‘‘self-reinforcing benefits’’
for Google’s ecosystem.
1237
The slide asked, ‘‘[I]s there some frame-
work we have to demonstrate the synergies/inter-relationships from
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00180 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
175
1238
Id.
1239
Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm’n, Federal Trade Commission Closes Google/DoubleClick
Investigation (Dec. 20, 2007), https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/press-releases/2007/12/federal-
trade-commission-closes-googledoubleclick-investigation.
1240
Id.
1241
Id.
1242
Id.
1243
Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm’n, FTC Closes Its Investigation of Google AdMob Deal
(May 21, 2010), https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/press-releases/2010/05/ftc-closes-its-investiga-
tion-google-admob-deal.
1244
Id.
1245
About the iAd App Network Shutdown, A
PPLE
: D
EV
. (Dec. 31, 2016), https://devel-
oper.apple.com/support/iad/.
1246
Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm’n, FTC Closes Its Investigation of Google AdMob Deal
(May 21, 2010), https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/press-releases/2010/05/ftc-closes-its-investiga-
tion-google-admob-deal.
1247
Press Release, U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Statement of the Department of Justice’s Antitrust
Division on Its Decision to Close Its Investigation of Google Inc.’s Acquisition of Admeld Inc.
(Dec. 2, 2011), https://www.justice.gov/opa/pr/statement-department-justices-antitrust-division-
its-decision-close-its-investigation-google.
1248
Dina Srinivasan, Why Google Dominates Advertising Markets, 24 S
TAN
. T
ECH
. L. R
EV
. 55,
92–93 (2020).
owning all these pieces?’’
1238
Nine months later, Google announced
its bid to buy DoubleClick.
When reviewing the deal, the Federal Trade Commission as-
sessed both horizontal and non-horizontal theories of harm and
noted that, prior to announcing the acquisition, Google had been
planning to enter the market and compete against DoubleClick di-
rectly.
1239
Ultimately the Commission concluded that the display
advertising market was highly competitive, and therefore the loss
of Google’s potential entry would not be competitively signifi-
cant.
1240
Examining the potential effects of the deal on privacy, the
FTC said it found no evidence that competition between Google and
DoubleClick affected their respective privacy policies.
1241
In De-
cember 2007, the FTC approved the acquisition.
1242
In 2010, Google acquired AdMob, the leading mobile ad network
at the time. In the FTC’s approval of the merger, it stated that ‘‘the
combination of the two leading mobile advertising networks raised
serious antitrust issues,’’ but that these concerns were ‘‘over-
shadowed by recent developments in the market, most notably a
move by Apple Computer Inc.—the maker of the iPhone—to launch
its own competing mobile ad network.’’
1243
The Commission’s as-
sumption that Apple would continue to build its presence in the
mobile ad market prompted it to approve the deal.
1244
In the com-
ing years, however, Apple’s product never fully took off and, in
2016, Apple abandoned the effort completely.
1245
In 2011, Google also acquired AdMeld, a leading supply-side plat-
form.
1246
The Justice Department’s Antitrust Division investigated
the acquisition and concluded that the deal was ‘‘unlikely to cause
consumer harm.’’
1247
(c) Conduct
(i) Combination of Data. When Google purchased DoubleClick, it
told Congress and the FTC that it would not combine the data col-
lected on internet users via DoubleClick with the data collected
throughout Google’s ecosystem.
1248
In 2016, however, Google re-
versed this commitment and subsequently combined DoubleClick
data with personal information collected through other Google serv-
ices—effectively combining information from a user’s personal iden-
tity with their location on Google Maps, information from Gmail,
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00181 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
176
1249
CEO Hearing at 105 (question of Rep. Val Demings (D–FL), Member, Subcomm. on Anti-
trust, Commercial and Admin Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
1250
Id. at 106.
1251
Id.
1252
Id.
1253
Id. at 368 (response to Questions for the Record of Sundar Pichai, CEO, Alphabet, Inc.).
and their search history, along with information from numerous
other Google products. At the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Rep-
resentative Val Demings (D–FL) asked Mr. Pichai about his direct
involvement in the decision to renege on Google’s commitment to
lawmakers:
When Google proposed the merger[,] alarm bells were raised about the access to
data Google would have, specifically the ability to connect to users’ personal
identity with their browsing activity. Google, however, committed to Congress
and to the antitrust enforcers that the deal would not reduce user privacy.
Google’s chief legal adviser testified before the Senate Antitrust Subcommittee
that Google wouldn’t be able to merge this data even if it wanted to, given con-
tractual restrictions. But in June of 2016, Google went ahead and merged its
data anyway, effectively destroying anonymity on the internet .... Did you sign
off on this decision to combine the sets of data with—that Google had told Con-
gress would be kept separate?
1249
Mr. Pichai confirmed that he approved the deal, claiming that,
‘‘Today [we] make it very easy for users to be in control of their
data.’’
1250
Representative Demings also noted that, at the time of
the transaction, DoubleClick executives had noted that Google’s
founders were concerned that combining the data in this way—
through a cross-site cookie—would lead to a privacy backlash. She
stated:
So, in 2007, Google’s founders feared making this change because they knew it
would upset their users, but in 2016, Google didn’t seem to care. Mr. Pichai, isn’t
it true that what changed between 2007 and 2016 is that Google gained enor-
mous market power. So. While Google had to care about user privacy in 2007.
It no longer had to in 2016? Would you agree that what changed was Google
gained enormous market power?
1251
She closed by noting she was concerned that Google’s ‘‘bait-and-
switch’’ was ‘‘part of a broader pattern where Google buys up com-
panies for the purposes of surveilling Americans, and because of
Google’s dominance users have no choice but to surrender.’’
1252
In
recent months, Google’s reversal on this commitment has become
salient for enforcers now assessing Google’s bid to purchase
FitBit.
1253
(ii) Other Areas of Concern. While a comprehensive examination
of this market is beyond the scope of this Report, the Subcommittee
heard from numerous market participants about a set of alleged
practices by Google that invite investigation. These include:
Depriving advertisers and publishers of key market and pricing information
and maintaining market opacity;
Leveraging its market power in search advertising to compel advertisers to use
Google’s products in the display market;
Leveraging control over YouTube to foreclose competition in digital video ad
serving, in part by excluding rival ad servers from having access to YouTube;
Inhibiting interoperability between Google’s ad platforms and non-Google ad
platforms; and
Using its search dominance to impose standards like AMP that, by further de-
priving publishers of user data, benefit Google’s ad business.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00182 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
177
1254
Felix Richter, The Smartphone Market: The Smartphone Duopoly, S
TATISTA
(July 27,
2020), https://www.statista.com/chart/3268/smartphone-os-market-share/ (citing Mobile Oper-
ating System Market Share Worldwide, S
TATCOUNTER
G
LOBAL
S
TATS
).
1255
S. O’Dea, Market Share of Mobile Operating Systems in the United States from January
2012 to December 2019, S
TATISTA
(Feb. 27, 2020), https://www.statista.com/statistics/272700/
market-share-held-by-mobile-operating-systems-in-the-us-since-2009/ (citing Mobile Operating
System Market Share in United States of America, S
TATCOUNTER
G
LOBAL
S
TATS
).
1256
Farhad Manjoo, A Murky Road Ahead for Android, Despite Market Dominance, N.Y.
T
IMES
(May 27, 2015), https://www.nytimes.com/2015/05/28/technology/personaltech/a-
murky-road-ahead-for-android-despite-market-dominance.html.
1257
See infra Appendix.
1258
Google Buys Motorola Mobility for $12.5B, Says ‘‘Android Will Stay Open,’’ T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Aug. 15, 2011), https://techcrunch.com/2011/08/15/breaking-google-buys-motorola-for-12-5-
billion/ (reporting that Google purchased Motorola primarily to protect the Android ecosystem
from patent litigation). In 2014, Google sold Motorola to Lenovo. Facts About Google’s Acquisi-
tion of Motorola, G
OOGLE
, https://www.google.com/press/motorola/ (last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
1259
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, A–6 (Nov. 22, 2019) (on file with
Comm.). Android is managed by the Open Handset Alliance, a group of more than eighty hard-
ware, software, and mobile network operators, including Samsung, LG, HTC, and Lenovo. See
Members, O
PEN
H
ANDSET
A
LL
., https://www.openhandsetalliance.com/ohalmembers.html (last
visited Oct. 4, 2020); Licenses, A
NDROID
O
PEN
S
OURCE
P
ROJECT
, https://source.android.com/
setup/start/licenses (last visited Oct. 4, 2020) (stating that the Android source code is freely
available for use under an open-source license).
1260
See Google Android Comm’n Decision ¶¶ 160–63.
1261
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–02393308 (Mar. 11,
2011) (on file with Comm.) (describing the Mobile Application Distribution Agreement (MADA)
as an agreement that specifies which apps Google requires hardware manufacturers to pre-in-
stall and where on the phone the apps should be placed).
1262
Id. at GOOG–HJC–02393318 (Feb. 25, 2011) (Google’s Antifragmentation Agreement).
4. Android and Google Play Store
(a) Android
(i) Overview. Android is a dominant mobile operating system,
running on approximately 75 percent of the world’s mobile de-
vices.
1254
In the United States, the only alternative to Android is
Apple’s iOS. Android captures about 47 percent of the U.S. mobile
operating system market, and Apple captures about 52 percent of
it.
1255
Google acquired Android in July 2005 for an estimated $50 mil-
lion.
1256
Since then, Google has purchased a set of technologies to
strengthen its mobile ecosystem, including both software and hard-
ware.
1257
Notably, Google purchased Motorola Mobility in 2011 for
$12.5 billion, the largest acquisition in Google’s history.
1258
Google describes Android as ‘‘a free, open-source mobile operating
system’’ that is available to anyone to download and modify on a
royalty-free basis.
1259
Indeed, Android is unique in that Google
does not generally monetize its operating system by selling propri-
etary hardware or demanding licensing fees. In practice, however,
smartphone manufacturers that seek to use Android must sign
Google’s licensing agreements, as Google limits the functionality of
non-licensed usage. Only through Google’s licensing agreements
can smartphone manufacturers access Google’s proprietary apps,
such as Gmail, YouTube, Chrome, Google Maps, and Google Play
Store.
1260
In return, Google requires that certain apps must be
pre-installed and must receive prominent placement on mobile de-
vices.
1261
Device manufacturers must also enter an agreement that
prevents them from customizing Android,
1262
and from building an
Android fork that would make the version of Android running on
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00183 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
178
1263
Id.; Google Android Comm’n Decision ¶¶ 170–71; see also Device Compatibility Overview,
A
NDROID
D
EVS
., https://developer.android.com/guide/practices/compatibility (lastvisited Oct. 4,
2020). In 2017, Google released an alternative to its Antifragmentation Agreement called the
Android Compatibility Commitment (ACC), which ‘‘would permit OEMs to manufacture incom-
patible Android devices for a third party that are marketed under a third-party brand.’’ Google
Android Comm’n Decision ¶¶ 170–71.
1264
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04216470 (May
2009) (on file with Comm.).
1265
Id. at GOOG–HJC–02393308 (Mar. 11, 2011) (on file with Comm.) (Mobile Application
Distribution Agreement).
1266
Id. at GOOG–HJC–00660371 (Apr. 11, 2011).
1267
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04216470 (May 2009).
1268
Id. at GOOG–HJC–00660364 (Apr. 11, 2011).
a device incompatible with apps built for the Android eco-
system.
1263
The Subcommittee’s investigation revealed that Google has used
Android to entrench and extend its dominance in a host of ways
that undermine competition. These include: (1) using contractual
restrictions and exclusivity provisions to extend Google’s search
monopoly from desktop to mobile and to favor its own applications;
and (2) devising Android Lockbox, a covert effort to track real-time
data on the usage and engagement of third-party apps, some of
which were Google’s competitors. Additionally, Google’s Play Store
now functions as a gatekeeper, which Google is increasingly using
to hike fees and favor its own apps. Overall, Android’s business
practices reveal how Google has maintained its search dominance
through relying on various contractual restrictions that blocked
competition and through exploiting information asymmetries, rath-
er than by competing on the merits.
(ii) Using Contracts to Extend Google’s Search Monopoly and
Self-Preference. Early communications within Google show that it
began investing in the mobile ecosystem because it recognized that
the rise of smartphone usage threatened to disintermediate Google
Search. Since losing its monopoly on search would mean losing its
valuable trove of user data, maintaining dominance over search ac-
cess points was paramount.
To maintain its search dominance, Google invested in Android,
which it recognized it could use to extend its search dominance
onto mobile devices.
1264
Google required that any smartphone man-
ufacturer seeking to license Android preinstall Google Search and
Google Play Store, alongside a host of other rotating apps selected
by Google.
1265
Google also offered mobile device manufacturers rev-
enue-share agreements, under which smartphone manufacturers
would receive a cut of the search advertising revenue that Google
made from the use of Google’s apps on their devices,
1266
as well as
a cut of Play Store revenues.
1267
In return, however, manufactur-
ers had to not only carry Google’s apps, but also ensure that Google
Search was the default and exclusive search app pre-installed on
the manufacturers’ devices. For example, one revenue share agree-
ment reviewed by the Subcommittee stated that hardware manu-
facturers shall not ‘‘pre-install, install, or incorporate on any Cov-
ered Device any application which is the same or substantially
similar to a Google Search Client or the Google Search Serv-
ices.’’
1268
Documents show that Google executives knew that conditioning
access to Android and to Google’s suite of apps on the prominent
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00184 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
179
1269
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04217467 (May 2009) (on file with Comm.).
1270
Google Android Comm’n Decision ¶ 182.
1271
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–00050146 (May 23,
2013) (on file with Comm.).
1272
Id.
1273
See Google Android Comm’n Decision ¶ 183.
1274
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–00050145 (May 23,
2013).
1275
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04300658 (Jan. 21, 2014).
placement of Google Search would disrupt existing partnerships be-
tween mobile network operators and rival search engines. For ex-
ample, a 2009 slide deck stated that ‘‘[p]artners may have deals in
place with other search providers,’’ and noted that ‘‘T-Mobile and
AT&T have closed deals with Yahoo .... Verizon has tight relation-
ship with MSFT re: search .... Expect MSFT & Yahoo to aggres-
sively pursue ‘pre-load’ deals on Android phones.’’
1269
Google’s
strategy of licensing Android for free to hardware partners and
conditioning access to Google’s must-have apps on favorable treat-
ment for Google Search enabled Google to box out rivals in mobile
search and other markets. Google’s strategy was successful. These
agreements, which were reached with the leading smartphone pro-
viders, solidified Google Search as the default search option on a
majority of the world’s smartphones.
As Android gained market share, its demands grew and hard-
ened. The European Commission found that between 2009 and
2014, Google increased the number of pre-installed Google apps
that it required from 12 to 30.
1270
Documents submitted to the
Subcommittee also show that instructions to heavily push Google
Search were coming from the company’s top management. Summa-
rizing a meeting with Sundar Pichai, then-Vice President of Prod-
uct Development, Director of Engineering for Android Patrick
Brady recalled, ‘‘His main feedback was . . . [s]earch is sacred, must
be front and center.’’
1271
He added, ‘‘Our proposal covers that
through more prescriptive search placement requirements.’’
1272
Google’s licensing agreement gave Google the right to amend the
list of apps it required device manufacturers to pre-install.
1273
Doc-
uments show that market participants expressed frustration at
Google’s ability to set the terms and also change them routinely.
Explaining the situation, Mr. Brady wrote, ‘‘Some OEMs . . . do not
like the idea of signing up to undefined requirements, but most of
our partners are somewhat used to this as the [c]ompatibility re-
quirements evolve with each release, and our [Google Mobile Serv-
ices] suite expands (incl. mandatory apps) over time.’’
1274
When
one hardware manufacturer attempted to secure additional rights,
Google pushed back. In 2014, John Lagerling, Senior Director of
Android Global Partnerships, responded to such an effort:
In your redlines on [the contract], you are suggesting [OEM] approves any new
additions to GMS. This has never been the case in our past history[,] and I think
it is the wrong message for [OEM] to send Google. We just spent some hours
explaining . . . that one of the main reasons we do Android is in order to secure
distribution of Google services.
1275
Other smartphone manufacturers also attempted to resist
Google’s terms, noting that the requirements were crowding out
placement for other apps while also taking up significant memory.
For example, in 2014, one hardware manufacturer requested that
Google ‘‘reduce the number of preloaded apps on the device . . . so
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00185 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
180
1276
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04308614 (Jan. 17, 2014).
1277
Id.
1278
Submission from Source 104, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 104–00000439 (Jan.
18, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
1279
Id. at Source 104–00000437.
1280
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04200778 (May 25,
2017) (on file with Comm.).
1281
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04204875 (Jan. 18, 2014).
1282
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04299009 (Feb. 4, 2016) (discussing how the manufacturer’s mobile
payment app would be placed inside of an apps folder while Google’s mobile payment app would
be placed more prominently outside the folder of Google apps).
1283
See, e.g., Mark Bergen & Sohee Kim, Google in Talks to Take Over More Search Tasks
on Samsung Phones, B
LOOMBERG
(July 28, 2020), https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/
2020-07-29/google-in-talks-to-take-over-more-search-tasks-on-samsung-phones; Paresh Dave &
Hyunjoo Jin, Samsung Weighs Dropping Bixby as Google Dangles New Mobile Apps Deal, R
EU
-
TERS
(July 29, 2020), https://www.reuters.com/article/us-google-samsung/samsung-weighs-
dropping-bixby-as-google-dangles-new-mobile-apps-deal-idUSKCN24U0TF.
that we don’t clutter our products with apps that may not be nec-
essary for the majority of users and we give them as much space
as possible,’’ adding that this would also ‘‘help us deal with com-
plaints from governments, NGOs and end users.’’
1276
Forwarding
the email to others at Google, Mr. Langerling noted that the manu-
facturer’s grievance was ‘‘not about clutter but about system mem-
ory,’’ adding that ‘‘[u]sers have been complaining to [the device
maker] that [it] sells them a 16Gb phone and delivers something
that only has 7–8Gb free.’’
1277
Despite complaints that Android’s pre-install conditions favored
Google’s products at the expense of user experience, Google main-
tained its requirements. Interviews with market participants sug-
gest that Google’s ability to set the terms of commerce hurt mobile
device manufacturers as well as third-party developers, both of
which had their own apps they were seeking to distribute. In a
submission to the Subcommittee, one third party recalled being in-
formed by a device manufacturer ‘‘that it could not provide home
screen placement for our preloaded app due in part to contractual
agreements to preload [Google’s competing app].’’
1278
Market participants noted that pre-installation on devices can be
critical for successful distribution. One developer explained that
‘‘integration into the initial device setup,’’ in particular, can ‘‘mean-
ingfully drive the acquisition of new users.’’
1279
Google’s documents
show that it recognized the importance of pre-installation, with one
internal presentation stating that ‘‘activation and defaults are a
known issue that we should explore, as OEM/carrier pre-installed
apps are among the most used.’’
1280
Documents also show that Google uses its leverage to push hard-
ware manufacturers to privilege Google’s products over the manu-
facturers’ products. Discussing the agenda for an upcoming meeting
with a hardware manufacturer, one Google manager noted that the
manufacturer should discourage the use of its email client for
Gmail accounts, stating, ‘‘They should use Gmail native
app.’’
1281
In a separate discussion in 2016, Google employees ex-
plained how Android Pay, a predecessor to Google Pay, would be
given preferential treatment over the manufacturer’s own mobile
payment app.
1282
Recent reporting that Google is pressuring
Samsung to promote Google apps over those offered by Samsung is
consistent with the company’s past conduct.
1283
Lastly, Google appears to use its licensing agreements to deter
mobile device manufacturers from collaborating with alternative
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00186 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
181
1284
See, e.g., Dieter Bohn, Google Explains Why It Stopped Acer’s Aliyun Smartphone Launch
(Updated), V
ERGE
(Sept. 14, 2012), https://www.theverge.com/2012/9/14/3335204/google-state-
ment-acer-smartphone-launch-aliyun-android; Roger Cheng, Alibaba: Google Forced Acer to Drop
Our New Mobile OS, CNET (Sept. 13, 2012), https://www.cnet.com/news/alibaba-google-forced-
acer-to-drop-our-new-mobile-os/; T.C. Sottek, Acer Cancels Phone Launch with Alibaba, Alleg-
edly in Response to Threats from Google, V
ERGE
(Sept. 13, 2012), https://www.theverge.com/
2012/9/13/3328690/acer-google-alibaba-phone.
1285
See id.
1286
See, e.g., Janko Roettgers, How Google Kneecapped Amazon’s Smart TV Efforts, P
RO
-
TOCOL
(Mar. 11, 2020), https://www.protocol.com/google-android-amazon-fire-tv; James
Brumley, Google Just Made Sure It’s Going to Win the Smart TV War, M
OTLEY
F
OOL
(Mar. 20,
2020), https://www.fool.com/investing/2020/03/20/google-just-made-sure-its-going-to-win-the-
smart-t.aspx.
1287
Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Fines Google Ö4.34 Billion for Illegal
Practices Regarding Android Mobile Devices to Strengthen Dominance of Google’s Search En-
gine (July 18, 2018), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/IPl18l4581.
1288
Id.
1289
Id.
mobile operating system providers. In 2012, for example, Acer, a
hardware manufacturer, and Alibaba had planned to release a vari-
ant of Android, called Aliyun OS.
1284
Reporting suggests that
Google threatened to terminate its partnership with Acer in retal-
iation, leading Acer to cancel the launch of devices running on the
Aliyun OS.
1285
Google also requires hardware partners to agree
that they will not run unsanctioned versions of Android on other
hardware products, with the understanding that any manufacturer
who violates this condition risks losing access to the Google Play
Store and other popular apps across all of the manufacturer’s de-
vices.
1286
After investigating Google’s licensing agreements, the European
Commission concluded in 2018 that Google’s conduct had illegally
benefited Google’s own services while blocking the rise of rival op-
erating systems.
1287
Although Google argued that users were free
to download other apps and that Google’s own apps were superior,
the Commission determined that ‘‘users who find search and
browser apps pre-installed on their devices are likely to stick to
these apps.’’
1288
Responding to Google’s claims that its tying agree-
ments were necessary in order for Google to be able to monetize its
investment in Android, the European Commission stated:
Google achieves billions of dollars in annual revenues with the Google Play Store
alone, it collects a lot of data that is valuable to Google’s search and advertising
business from Android devices, and it would still have benefitted from a signifi-
cant stream of revenue from search advertising without the restrictions.
1289
(iii) Accessing Real-Time Market Data. The Subcommittee’s inves-
tigation also revealed that Android gives Google unparalleled ac-
cess to data on its users and developers. This includes information
that Google can monetize through its ad business, as well as stra-
tegic intelligence that lets Google track emerging competitors and
general business trends.
Android’s dominance in the mobile operating system market en-
ables it to extensively surveil its users. This surveillance is partly
enabled through Google’s technology. In key ways, Google also uses
its dominance and its integration across markets to increase the
number of touchpoints from which it is constantly mining user
data.
Google’s documents show that it has used its leverage over hard-
ware manufacturers to demand that they structure their devices in
ways that facilitate Google’s data collection efforts. Google’s agree-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00187 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
182
1290
Google Android Comm’n Decision ¶ 187.
1291
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04204875 (Jan. 18,
2014) (on file with Comm.).
1292
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 471 (response to Questions for the Record
of Adam Cohen, Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC).
1293
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04198806 to
–04198855 (Jan. 13, 2017) (on file with Comm.).
1294
Id. at GOOG–HJC–00055102 (Nov. 2013).
1295
Id. at GOOG–HJC–02598471 (June 6, 2010).
1296
Id. at GOOG–HJC–00055102 (Nov. 2013).
1297
Id.
1298
Id.
1299
Alex Heath, Nick Bastone & Amir Efrati, Internal Google Program Taps Data on Rival
Android Apps, I
NFORMATION
(July 23, 2020), https://www.theinformation.com/articles/internal-
google-program-taps-data-on-rival-android-apps.
ments with device manufacturers, for example, require that manu-
facturers configure a ‘‘Client ID,’’ which is a unique alphanumeric
code incorporated in the smartphone that enables Google to com-
bine metrics tracked via the hardware with all the other data
Google collects on users.
1290
Additionally, Google’s own documents
also show that it has asked device manufacturers to use a Google
Account as their identifier rather than a non-Google account—a
way of ensuring that Google can capture a broader picture of its
users.
1291
On the Play Store, meanwhile, Google does not permit
users to download apps unless they have a Google Account, further
funneling users into the Google ecosystem.
1292
Combined with lo-
cation data, which Android also extensively collects, Google can
build sophisticated user profiles reflecting a person’s demographic,
where they are, and where they go, as well as which apps they use
at what time and for how long.
1293
These intimate user profiles,
spanning billions of people, are a key source of Google’s advantage
in its ad business. In this way, Android’s location data feeds into
Google’s dominance in ads.
Documents and information reviewed by the Subcommittee also
show that Google has used Android to closely monitor competing
apps—data that amounts to near-perfect market intelligence. Since
at least 2012, Google has collected installation metrics for third-
party apps,
1294
which it combined with data analyzing search que-
ries.
1295
These early documents outline the early stages of Google’s
‘‘Lockbox,’’ a project to collate data that provided Google with a
range of competitor insights and market intelligence, ranging from
an understanding of how installation of the Amazon app cor-
responded to a trend in Amazon shopping queries
1296
to a close
tracking of trends relating to Candy Crush and Angry Birds.
1297
While Lockbox began as a way to collect data on the installation
of apps, Google quickly realized it could harness it to yield other
insights as well. One document from 2013 identified a list of addi-
tional data points that the company desired, including ‘‘[m]ore sig-
nals (including uninstalls and device app mapping)’’ and ‘‘reliable
and long term app usage data,’’ for which the document noted
Google Play Services could help.
1298
In short, Google began seeking
out ways to collect specific usage data that enabled Google to track
not just which apps a user has, but also how frequently they use
the apps and for how long.
Documents obtained by the Subcommittee suggest that by 2015,
Google’s Lockbox data had succeeded in tracking more than just in-
stall rates.
1299
Google’s internal reports show that Google was
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00188 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
183
1300
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04198806 to
–04198855 (Jan. 13, 2017) (on file with Comm.).
1301
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04198814 (Jan. 13, 2017).
1302
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04198812 (Jan. 13, 2017).
1303
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04199726 (Jan. 13, 2017).
1304
Alex Heath, Nick Bastone & Amir Efrati, Internal Google Program Taps Data on Rival
Android Apps, I
NFORMATION
(July 23, 2020), https://www.theinformation.com/articles/internal-
google-program-taps-data-on-rival-android-apps.
1305
Jon Porter, Google Reportedly Keeps Tabs on Usage of Rival Android Apps to Develop
Competitors, V
ERGE
(July 24, 2020), https://www.theverge.com/2020/7/24/21336946/google-
android-lockbox-data-rival-apps-antitrust-scrutiny.
1306
CEO Hearing at 164 (statement of Sundar Pichai, CEO, Alphabet, Inc.).
1307
Id. at 346 (response to Questions for the Record of Sundar Pichai, CEO, Alphabet, Inc.).
1308
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04218465 (Nov. 26,
2009) (on file with Comm.).
1309
See infra Section V.D.2(c)(i).
tracking in real-time the average number of days users were active
on any particular app,
1300
as well as their ‘‘total time spent’’ in
first- and third-party apps.
1301
Google subsequently used this data
to benchmark the company’s first-party apps against third-party
apps, suggesting that Google was using Lockbox data to assess the
relative strengths and weaknesses of its own offerings.
1302
Google’s
documents show how Lockbox furnishes Google with near-perfect
market intelligence, which Google has used to inform strategic
moves and potential business transactions.
1303
Recent reporting by
The Information documented how YouTube employees used
Lockbox data to track TikTok usage in India as Google was devel-
oping and planning its own rival to TikTok.
1304
During the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Subcommittee Vice
Chair Joe Neguse (D–CO) asked Mr. Pichai about allegations that
Google had used Android to surveil rival apps and develop com-
peting products.
1305
Mr. Pichai responded, ‘‘Congressman, because
we try to understand what’s going on in [the] market and we are
aware of, you know, popularity of apps,’’ adding, ‘‘But, in general,
the primary use for that data is to improve the health of An-
droid.’’
1306
In follow-up questions to Mr. Pichai, Google was asked to identify
all acquisitions or product decisions that had been informed by
data from Android Lockbox. Google’s answer was not responsive to
the question.
1307
(b) Play Store. The Play Store is the dominant app store on An-
droid devices. Early documents reviewed by the Subcommittee
show that Google chose for a single app store to control software
distribution on the Android ecosystem, with one executive noting
that ‘‘we would strongly prefer to have one Market that everyone
focuses on.’’
1308
Because Google’s Play Store is the primary way that users install
applications on Android devices, the Play Store effectively functions
as a gatekeeper for software distribution on a majority of the
world’s mobile devices. The Subcommittee’s investigation reveals
that Google uses this gatekeeper power in several key ways.
First, Google uses its Play Store gatekeeper power to charge high
fees to mobile developers. Amazon, Spotify, Netflix, Epic Games,
and Tinder have all expressed public concerns about Google’s app
store fees, along with Apple’s.
1309
As a lawsuit recently filed by
Epic Games stated, ‘‘Google has thus installed itself as an unavoid-
able middleman for app developers who wish to reach Android
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00189 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
184
1310
Complaint for Injunctive Relief at 2, Epic Games, Inc. v. Google LLC, No. 3:20–cv–05671
(N.D. Cal. Aug. 13, 2020).
1311
Play Console Help: Service Fees, G
OOGLE
, https://support.google.com/googleplay/
android-developer/answer/112622?hl=en (last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
1312
Transaction Fees for Merchants, G
OOGLE
P
AYMENTS
H
ELP
C
TR
., https://support
.google.com/paymentscenter/answer/7159343?hl=en#:#:text=The%20transaction%20fee%20for%
20all,distribution%20partner%20and%20operating%20fees (last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
1313
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04217474 (on file
with Comm.).
1314
Complaint for Injunctive Relief at 7, Epic Games, Inc. v. Google LLC, No. 3:20–cv–05671
(N.D. Cal. Aug. 13, 2020).
1315
Id. at 28.
1316
Id. at 7.
users and vice versa. Google uses this monopoly power to impose
a tax that siphons monopoly profits for itself every time an app de-
veloper transacts with a consumer for the sale of an app or in-app
digital content.’’
1310
Although Google doesn’t block off all alternative channels for ac-
cessing apps—allowing, for example, both some app stores and
sideloading—in practice, these options do not provide meaningful
alternatives to the Google Play Store. In contrast, the dual domi-
nance of the Play Store and the Android ecosystem enables Google
to exert control and engage in conduct that harms competition by
exploiting, excluding, and discriminating against rivals.
Google charges developers of paid apps a 30 percent commission
for downloads from the Play Store.
1311
Google also charges devel-
opers a 30 percent fee for in-app purchases.
1312
According to docu-
ments obtained by the Subcommittee, from 2011 to 2015, revenue
from the Play Store accounted for 85 percent of Google’s total rev-
enue from the Android operating system, hardware sales, and the
Play Store.
1313
Third-party apps can also avoid the Play Store’s commissions
and fees by directing consumers to sideload the app—that is, to in-
stall the app using a browser, outside of an app store. Rival app
stores that are not pre-installed on the device, such as the Amazon
Appstore, must be sideloaded. Although sideloading is technically
an option for rival app stores and app developers, market partici-
pants explained that Google goes out of its way to make
sideloading difficult. Epic’s recent lawsuit against Google alleges:
Google ensures that the Android process is technically complex, confusing and
threatening, filled with dire warnings that scare most consumers into aban-
doning the lengthy process. For example, depending on the version of Android
running on a mobile device, downloading and installing Fortnite on an Android
device could take as many as 16 steps or more, including requiring the user to
make changes to the device’s default settings and manually granting various per-
missions while being warned that doing so is dangerous.
1314
Additionally, Epic’s complaint notes that when it attempted to
work with LG, another Android device manufacturer, LG told Epic
that it had a contract with Google ‘‘to block side downloading off
Google Play Store this year.’’
1315
If a user is able to install the
competing app store, Google blocks them ‘‘from offering basic func-
tions, such as automatic updating of apps in the background, which
is available for apps downloaded from the Google Play Store.’’
1316
The Play Store’s dominance over app distribution on Android de-
vices has enabled Google to begin to require the use of its in-app
payment system (IAP). As a result, Google has become the middle-
man between app developers and their customers. This was not al-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00190 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
185
1317
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 480 (response to Questions for the Record
of Adam Cohen, Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC).
1318
Submission from Source 736, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Sept. 25, 2020) (on file with
Comm.).
1319
Submission from Source 62, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 1 (July 31, 2020) (on file with
Comm.).
1320
Submission from Source 685, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 12 (Oct. 15, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
1321
Submission from Callsome, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Apr. 28, 2020) (on file with
Comm.).
1322
Id. at 7.
1323
Google AdMob, G
OOGLE
, https://admob.google.com/home/ (last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
1324
Submission from Source 685, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (on file with Comm.).
ways the case. Market participants explain that Google has
changed its stance and re-interpreted policies over time to require
more app developers to use Google Pay. Beginning in 2014, for ex-
ample, Google designated specific categories of applications—in-
cluding mobile games—that would be required to use Google Play
In-App Billing.
1317
Recently, however, several market participants
have informed the Subcommittee that Google has begun insisting
that a broader category of apps will be required to use Google IAP
exclusively, no longer allowing the option of a third-party payment
processor.
1318
In interviews with the Subcommittee, developers state that one
way Google exercises its gatekeeper power over third-party app de-
velopers is through its arbitrary and unaccountable enforcement of
Play Store policies. One developer that spoke with the Sub-
committee described Google’s Play Store policies as an ‘‘opaque sys-
tem [that] threatens the ability of app developers to develop and
compete in the market for consumers, who should ultimately deter-
mine which apps they use.’’
1319
Another developer explained,
‘‘When apps allegedly violate Google Play Store standards, Google
does not ever explain how, other than to quote the policy above and
attach pictures of the allegedly violating image. When the imagery
does not fit the above definitions, app publishers such as [third
party] are put in a position of having to guess how to apply these
standards.’’
1320
Developers also alleged that Google uses control over the Play
Store to protect the dominance of its own services and stifle rivals.
For example, Callsome, a mobile app that provided productive fol-
low-up to phone calls or text messages, such as prompting a cal-
endar entry or a reminder to text back, has sued Google and
claimed it was banned from the Google Play store for ‘‘Ad Policy’’
violations only to later learn that a ‘‘fundamentally identical prod-
uct’’ was able to stay and thrive in the Play Store.
1321
Callsome be-
lieves it was banned because of its partnership with StartApp,
which—at the time—was widely considered a nascent but rising
rival to Google in the Russian search market.
1322
The Subcommittee also spoke with several market participants
that said Google has abused its control of the Play Store by using
rule violations as a pretext for retaliatory conduct. For example,
one third party described how, soon after it ceased using Google’s
AdMob, an in-app ads monetization tool,
1323
Google began sending
the third party notifications of policy violations related to content
the third party had included in its app for years.
1324
In response to questions from the Subcommittee, Google stated
that it ‘‘only suspends apps from the Google Play Store if it finds
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00191 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
186
1325
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 478 (response to Questions for the Record
of Adam Cohen, Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC).
1326
Id. at 479.
1327
Submission from Callsome, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Apr. 28, 2020) (on file with
Comm.).
1328
Submission from Source 685, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 12 (Oct. 15, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
1329
Google Chrome: A New Take on the Browser, G
OOGLE
P
RESS
(Sept. 2, 2008), http://
googlepress.blogspot.com/2008/09/google-chrome-new-take-on-browserl02.html.
1330
Chromium, T
HE
C
HROMIUM
P
ROJECTS
, https://www.chromium.org/Home (last visited
Oct. 4, 2020).
1331
Catalin Cimpanu, All the Chromium-Based Browsers, ZDN
ET
(Jan. 29, 2019), https://
www.zdnet.com/pictures/all-the-chromium-based-browsers/4/.
1332
An Update on Chrome, the Web Store and Chrome OS, C
HROME
B
LOG
(Dec. 7, 2010),
https://chrome.googleblog.com/2010/12/update-on-chrome-web-store-and-chrome.html.
the app in violation of Google Play Program Policies . . . or in viola-
tion of the Developer Distribution Agreement.’’
1325
Google also
stated that it gives developers opportunities to address what they
may view as incorrect enforcement decisions of Play Store policies,
adding that a ‘‘developer can easily contact the Policy Support
Team (Appeals) in order to challenge the enforcement decision or
receive additional clarification on the infraction.’’
1326
App developers, in contrast, said that challenging a Play Store
decision was like navigating a black box. One third party explained
that it ‘‘tried for over a month through several channels to get a
full explanation from Google of the problem and resolve it ami-
cably. Google responded with silence, then roadblocks and run-
arounds.’’
1327
However, one third party told the Subcommittee:
When apps allegedly violate Google Play Store standards, Google does not ever
explain how, other than to quote the policy above and attach pictures of the al-
legedly violating image. When the imagery does not fit the above definitions, app
publishers such as [third party] are put in a position of having to guess how to
apply these standards.
1328
In theory, one way that app developers could avoid Google’s com-
missions and fees would be to negotiate with a mobile device manu-
facturer to have the app pre-installed on the device. In practice,
however, Google’s restrictive contracts with smartphone manufac-
turers have strictly limited—if not excluded—third-party apps from
being pre-installed. In this way, Google’s licensing agreements not
only preclude the vast majority of third-party apps from being pre-
installed, but they also funnel those apps into the Google Play
Store, subject to Google’s commissions and arbitrarily enforced poli-
cies.
5. Chrome
(a) Overview. Google launched its web browser, Google Chrome,
in 2008.
1329
Chrome makes a significant portion of its underlying
code base available through the open-source Chromium Project,
1330
which has been used to build a series of ‘‘chromium-based’’ brows-
ers such as Microsoft Edge and Opera.
1331
In 2010, Google intro-
duced the Chrome web store, which enables users to access and in-
stall browser extensions, such as Easy Ad Blocker, Grammarly, and
Netflix Party.
1332
Prior to Chrome’s launch, Internet Explorer, Firefox, and Safari
were the most popular browsers. Firefox leaned heavily on a part-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00192 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
187
1333
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–00125917 to
–00125929, GOOG–HJC–00125937 (Apr. 25, 2005) (on file with Comm.).
1334
Trefis Team, Great Speculations, Rising Chrome Use Means Search Advertising Growth
for Google, F
ORBES
(Aug. 23, 2012), https://www.forbes.com/sites/greatspeculations/2012/08/
23/rising-chrome-use-means-search-advertising-growth-for-google/#579c604f2d66; MG Siegler,
Here It Is: Google’s Kick-Ass Chrome Speed Test Video, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(May 5, 2010), https://
techcrunch.com/2010/05/05/google-chrome-video-test/.
1335
Turn Sync On and Off in Chrome, G
OOGLE
C
HROME
H
ELP
, https://support.google.com/
chrome/answer/185277?co=GENIE.Platform%3DDesktop&hl=en (last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
1336
Google Privacy Policy, G
OOGLE
P
RIV
.
&
T
ERMS
, https://policies.google.com/privacy (last
visited Oct. 4, 2020) (‘‘When you’re signed in, we also collect information that we store with your
Google Account.’’).
1337
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04214204 (Sept. 17,
2019) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Alternatives to IE (Firefox, Opera, Safari) proved unattractive[:]
Google initially partnered with Mozilla, but Firefox had technical limitations and faced uncer-
tain prospects[.] Apple launched Safari for Windows in 2007. If Firefox was displaced by Safari,
Apple could further constrain user access to Google[.]’’ (bullets and emphasis removed)).
1338
Id. at GOOG–HJC–00005661.
1339
Id. at GOOG–HJC–00086891 (Jan. 24, 2011).
1340
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 18–19.
1341
Submission from Source 534, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1342
Google Privacy Policy, G
OOGLE
P
RIV
.
&
T
ERMS
, https://policies.google.com/privacy (last
visited Sept. 29, 2020) (‘‘We collect information to provide better services to all our users . . .
which ads you’ll find most useful . . . which YouTube videos you might like.’’). At the Subcommit-
tee’s sixth hearing, Committee Chair Jerrold Nadler (D–NY) asked Google CEO Sundar Pichai
to explain how Google uses data on browsing activity, asking, ‘‘Does Google use that data for
its own purposes, either in advertising or to develop and refine its algorithms?’’ Mr. Pichai re-
sponded that Google uses data ‘‘to improve our products and services for our users.’’ CEO Hear-
ing at 73.
nership with Google Search, which documents show enabled Google
to closely track Firefox’s growth.
1333
Chrome initially set itself apart by offering an address bar that
also functioned as a Google search bar, and by enabling users to
sign in to the browser, offering a faster browsing experience com-
pared to other browsers.
1334
Chrome was also integrated with
other Google products. By signing in to the browser, Chrome auto-
matically signed users into Gmail, YouTube, and additional Google
services when users visited those sites, while also allowing users
to sync their bookmarks, passwords, and other browser set-
tings.
1335
While automatic sign-in provided a more streamlined
user experience, it also helped Google build more detailed user pro-
files by connecting activity data to the user’s Google Account.
1336
In a 2019 presentation to the Justice Department’s Antitrust Di-
vision, Google explained that it had launched Chrome as a defen-
sive move to protect users’ access to Google’s prod-
ucts.
1337
Internally, however, Google frequently referred to Chrome
as part of Google’s growth strategy. For example, in 2010, one of
Google’s strategy documents listed Chrome as a driver of ‘‘signifi-
cant value,’’
1338
and Eric Schmidt gave a company-wide speech
stating that the rise of cloud computing meant that the browser—
the primary way users access the cloud—would be increasingly crit-
ical to Google’s success.
1339
Perhaps most critically, Chrome serves as a way for Google to
control the entry points for its core markets: online search and on-
line advertising.
1340
Chrome uses Google Search as its default
search engine—a default setting that market participants say
Google makes difficult to change.
1341
Chrome also provides Google
with another source of user data that the company can feed into
its ad business to offer behavioral ads.
1342
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00193 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
188
1343
Id.; Trefis Team, Great Speculations, Rising Chrome Use Means Search Advertising
Growth for Google, F
ORBES
(Aug. 23, 2012), https://www.forbes.com/sites/greatspeculations/
2012/08/23/rising-chrome-use-means-search-advertising-growth-for-google/#579c604f2d66 (ob-
serving that Google captured 67 percent of desktop searches across all browsers and 95 percent
of searches conducted on Chrome, and noting that ‘‘[t]his large discrepancy in search market
share, depending on which browser is used, is one of the reasons why we think that the Chrome
browser has helped increase Google’s revenues’’).
1344
Desktop Browser Market Share in the United States, S
TAT
C
OUNTER
, https://gs
.statcounter.com/browser-market-share/desktop/united-states-of-america (last visited Sept. 27,
2020); Mobile Browser Market Share in the United States, S
TAT
C
OUNTER
, https://gs
.statcounter.com/browser-market-share/mobile/united-states-of-america (last visited Sept. 27,
2020).
1345
Browser Market Share, S
TAT
C
OUNTER
, https://gs.statcounter.com/browser-market-share/
all/united-states-of-america (last visited Sept. 27, 2020).
1346
Mobile Operating Systems’ Market Share Worldwide from January 2012 to July 2020,
S
TATISTA
(July 2020), https://www.statista.com/statistics/272698/global-market-share-held-by-
mobile-operating-systems-since-2009/.
1347
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 149.
(b) Market Power. Chrome became a leading web browser as
early as 2012.
1343
In the U.S. market, Chrome captures an esti-
mated 59 percent of desktop browser usage and 37 percent of mo-
bile browser usage,
1344
while capturing an estimated 66 percent of
overall browser usage worldwide.
1345
Several factors suggest that Google is likely to maintain its lead
in the browser market. First, Google has established Chrome as the
default browser on the majority of Android devices, which make up
around 75 percent of smartphones globally.
1346
While Google does
allow users to change default browsers on Android, in practice
users rarely do. As the United Kingdom’s Competition and Markets
Authority recently found, even platforms that do provide users with
options often end up using ‘‘defaults and choice architecture that
make it difficult for consumers to exercise this choice.’’
1347
Second, Chrome is likely to remain dominant because it benefits
from network effects. Web developers design and build for the
Chrome browser because it has the most users, and users, in turn,
are drawn to Chrome because webpages work well on it. And third,
Chrome is likely to maintain its lead because Google can leverage
the popularity of its apps to favor Chrome. Specifically, Google’s
documents show that the company has focused on designing
Chrome features to provide a better experience of apps like
YouTube and Search, advantages that other browsers lack.
(c) Conduct. Google used its search engine dominance and control
over the Android operating system to grow its share of the web
browser market and favor its other lines of business. Reciprocally,
Chrome’s dominance in the browser market gives it significant
gatekeeper power over managing and monitoring users’ browsing
activity—power Google can wield to shape outcomes across markets
for search, mobile operating systems, and digital advertising. These
advantages across markets feed back into and reinforce one an-
other—advantages that standalone browsers lack.
(i) Exploiting Information Asymmetries. Even before it developed
Chrome, Google’s search business and popular web-based applica-
tions gave it unique insights into the browser market. Because
Google.com is accessible through all browsers, Google Search usage
data includes data on the browser where the search query began.
Documents show that Google used search origination trends as
early as 2004 to track Firefox’s growth—and Internet Explorer’s de-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00194 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
189
1348
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–00126978 to
–00126985 (Nov. 2004) (on file with Comm.).
1349
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04214714 (Jan. 4, 2009) (on file with Comm.).
1350
Danny Sullivan, Search Market Share 2008: Google Grew, Yahoo & Microsoft Dropped &
Stabilized, S
EARCH
E
NGINE
L
AND
(Jan. 26, 2009), https://searchengineland.com/search-market-
share-2008-google-grew-yahoo-microsoft-dropped-stabilized-16310.
1351
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–01465906 (Apr. 22,
2009) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘We’ve been experimenting with some novel homepage promos for
Chrome in preparation for the IE8 autoupgrade [sic]. Using 0.1% experiments, we found a few
that performed very well. The promo on the homepage right now should be running for IE users
only.’’); id. at GOOG–HJC–01164689 (Apr. 23, 2009).
1352
Christopher Williams, Google Chrome Takes Second Place from Firefox, T
ELEGRAPH
(Dec.
2, 2011), https://www.telegraph.co.uk/technology/news/8930759/Google-Chrome-takes-second-
place-from-Firefox.html.
cline—in the browser market.
1348
Google’s collection of Google Apps
has also enabled it to monitor browser growth and performance.
For example, in 2009, a Chrome team member explained:
I’ve looked at the Gmail numbers a little—enough to know that we have per-
browser breakdowns of performance already. In the Gmail case, it’s quite clear
which browsers are faster. There are a zillion numbers we collect, including
Gmail startup times. I am confident that the other Google Apps teams also have
numbers. We could pull together a collection of 2–3 stats from each app, nor-
malize the scores somehow, and produce a number.
1349
This data from Google’s adjacent lines of business helped the
Chrome team track their performance against competitors. Most of
Chrome’s competitors then and now lack access to this type of data
at Google’s scale.
(ii) Favoring Google’s Products in Adjacent Markets. Through de-
sign choices and default settings, Google can use its dominance in
any one market to favor its other lines of business. For example,
when Chrome launched in 2008, Google Search was already the
most popular search engine in the world.
1350
Shortly after releas-
ing Chrome, Google began promoting the browser in the top corner
of the Google.com homepage. The display was referred to internally
as the ‘‘Google Chrome Promotion,’’ and it was frequently discussed
by Google’s Chrome team within the company.
1351
Internet Ex-
plorer users that visited Google’s home page would see the Google
Chrome installation button in the top-right corner, as shown below:
Google Chrome Promotion on Google.com Homepage
1352
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00195 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 18 here 11701.018
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
190
1353
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–01465903 (Apr. 22,
2009) (on file with Comm.).
1354
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04214743 (Apr. 3, 2009).
1355
Id. at GOOG–HJC–01465906 (Apr. 22, 2009).
1356
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04195391 (Mar. 4, 2011) (‘‘[O]rganic growth slowed a bit because our
homepage promo was down for a couple of weeks due to a change in the HPP system. It’s back
up now.’’).
1357
Submission from Source 534, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1358
CEO Hearing at 348 (response to Questions for the Record by Sundar Pichai, CEO, Al-
phabet, Inc.).
1359
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–02393308 (Mar. 1,
2011) (on file with Comm.).
1360
See generally Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Fines Google Ö14.34
Billion for Illegal Practices Regarding Android Mobile Devices to Strengthen Dominance of
Google’s Search Engine (July 17, 2018), https://europa.eu/rapid/press-releaselIP-18-
4581len.htm.
At the time, several Google employees expressed concerns inter-
nally that this promotion strategy was unfairly harnessing Google’s
search dominance to boost Chrome. In an email among Chrome em-
ployees in 2009, one employee wrote, ‘‘I find the very, very high-
profile promotion of Google Chrome on Google.com quite frankly,
startling.’’
1353
Senior executives at the company pushed to con-
tinue this strategy. For example, in 2009, Sundar Pichai, then-Vice
President of Product Development, encouraged the Chrome team to
‘‘promote through Google.com’’ and to push users to set Chrome as
their default browser.
1354
This strategy drove significant growth to Chrome. In 2009, Direc-
tor of Product Management Brian Rakowski informed his team
that the promotion was ‘‘performing exceptionally well’’ and was
‘‘driving tremendous number[s] of downloads.’’
1355
When Google
halted the promotion, Chrome’s growth rate dropped. In 2011,
Chrome employees noted that ‘‘organic growth slowed a bit because
our homepage promo was down for a couple of weeks.’’
1356
Market participants view this behavior as an example of how
Chrome does not compete on the merits. One firm stated, ‘‘Google
has abused its dominant position in the search space to build up
another dominant position in the browser space.’’
1357
In response
to questions about this use of Google’s search page, Google told the
Subcommittee that these ‘‘promotional campaigns on Google.com on
Internet Explorer have been run for over a decade.’’
1358
Google has reinforced its market power in the browser market
through its dominance in the mobile operating system market.
Chrome is preinstalled on every mobile device that runs Google’s
Android operating system, and Android powers approximately 75
percent of the world’s mobile devices. Beginning in 2014, Google
mandated that Chrome be pre-installed and prominently placed on
all certified Android devices that had entered a Mobile Application
Distribution Agreement (MADA), which grants smartphone manu-
facturers access to Google’s Play Store and other proprietary
Google applications.
1359
During negotiations with Android manu-
facturers for revenue share agreements, meanwhile, Google re-
quired that Chrome be set as the default browser.
1360
For the remaining portion of the global mobile phone market—
Apple iOS—Google uses the popularity of its mobile applications to
promote Chrome installations. Although Apple does not permit
Chrome to be set as the default browser on an iPhone, Google pro-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00196 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
191
1361
Submission from Source 269, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (July 23, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
1362
Id.
1363
Id.
1364
Set Your Default Search Engine, G
OOGLE
C
HROME
H
ELP
, https://support.google.com/
chrome/answer/95426?co=GENIE.Platform%3DDesktop&hl=en (last visited Oct. 2, 2020).
1365
Submission from Source 534, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1366
Submission from Source 269, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Jan. 2020) (on file with
Comm.).
1367
Martin Brinkmann, The New Skype for Web Does Not Work in Firefox or Opera,
GHACKS
.
NET
(Mar. 8, 2019), https://www.ghacks.net/2019/03/08/the-new-skype-for-web-does-
not-work-in-firefox-or-opera/.
vides users the option to use Chrome whenever a user selects a
link within a Google application, such as Gmail or YouTube.
1361
While Apple requires that Safari also be included as a choice,
1362
Google does not allow any other browser to be listed. If the user
has not previously installed the Chrome browser, then the menu
displays a ‘‘Get’’ button that prompts the user to install Google’s
browser.
1363
Similarly, Google privileges its own line of business by setting
Google Search as the default in Chrome. Although users can
change this setting, the process is not intuitive and involves mul-
tiple steps, including:
1. At the top right, click More :> Settings.
2. Under ‘‘Search engine,’’ click Manage search engines.
3. Find ‘‘Other search engines.’’
Add: To the right of ‘‘Other search engines,’’ click Add. Fill out the text
fields and click Add.
Set as default: To the right of the search engine, click More :> Make default.
Edit: To the right of the search engine, click More :> Edit.
Delete: To the right of the search engine, click More :> Remove from list.
1364
One third party told the Subcommittee that, in some cases, Google
prompts users to change their default search engine back to Google
Search even after they have switched:
After a user installs the extension, Chrome is showing continuous warning
prompts which ask users to restore their search settings back to Google. In user
tests, we observe that most people are very confused about this prompt and often
click ‘‘restore settings’’ even though they actually want to keep using [our search
engine]. In many Chrome versions the button ‘‘restore settings’’ is even high-
lighted which makes it highly likely that users will click this button and thereby
completely remove [our search engine] from their computers. We believe that we
have already lost millions of users because of this prompt.
1365
(iii) Unilaterally Setting Standards. By virtue of its dominance in
the browser market, Google can effectively set standards for the in-
dustry in two ways.
First, changes to Chrome’s functionality create de facto stand-
ards. Market participants must adhere to these standards or risk
their technology no longer being compatible with most websites.
Market participants explain that Google will often build features
quickly, without using the standard-setting process or giving small-
er browsers time to implement the new features. Once web devel-
opers start building to these specifications, however, smaller brows-
ers are under pressure to quickly implement these changes, often
with little notice.
1366
If smaller browsers cannot keep up, users are
flooded with ‘‘[b]rowser not supported’’ messages on webpages that
have already been built to Chrome’s specifications.
1367
Several
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00197 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
192
1368
Interview with Source 482 (July 2, 2020).
1369
W3C Mission, W3C, https://www.w3.org/Consortium/mission (last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
1370
Submission from Source 269, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 4 (July 23, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
1371
Id.
1372
Sarah Sluis, Google Chrome Will Drop Third-Party Cookies in 2 Years, A
D
E
XCHANGER
(Jan. 14, 2020), https://www.adexchanger.com/online-advertising/google-chrome-will-drop-
third-party-cookies-in-2-years/.
1373
Dieter Bohn, Google to ‘‘Phase Out’’ Third-Party Cookies in Chrome, but Not for Two
Years, V
ERGE
(Jan. 14, 2020), https://www.theverge.com/2020/1/14/21064698/google-third-
party-cookies-chrome-two-years-privacy-safari-firefox.
1374
Nick Bastone, In Ironic Twist, Google’s Pro-Privacy Move Boosted U.S. Antitrust Probe,
I
NFORMATION
(Sept. 18, 2020), https://www.theinformation.com/articles/in-ironic-twist-googles-
pro-privacy-move-boosted-u-s-antitrust-probe.
1375
CEO Hearing at 133 (question of Rep. Kelly Armstrong (R–ND), Member, Subcomm. on
Antitrust, Commercial & Admin. Law of the H. Comm on the Judiciary).
1376
Id. (statement of Sundar Pichai, CEO, Alphabet, Inc.).
market participants told the Subcommittee that they felt ‘‘bullied’’
by this process.
1368
Second, Google has an outsized role in the formal stakeholder
standards-making processes. As explained earlier in this Report,
the World Wide Web Consortium (W3C) is one of the leading stand-
ards organizations in the browser market. Its stated mission is to
be ‘‘open and collectively empowering.’’
1369
Other market partici-
pants believe that Google is significantly overrepresented in the
W3C web platform incubator community group (WICG). They note
that Google’s employees comprise 106 members—more than eight
times the number of employees from Microsoft, the next largest
stakeholder represented. Most companies, meanwhile, have only
one representative.
1370
One market participant explained that, al-
though standards bodies like the W3C give the impression of being
a place where browser vendors collaborate to improve the web plat-
form; in reality, Google’s monopoly position and aggressive rate of
shipping non-standard features frequently reduce standards bodies
to codifying web features and decisions Google has already
made.
1371
Recent events underscore how Google’s ad-based business model
can prompt questions about whether the standards Google chooses
to introduce are ultimately designed primarily to serve Google’s in-
terests. In January 2020, Google announced that it plans to phase
out third-party cookies in Chrome within two years.
1372
Unlike
other browsers that have limited cross-site tracking, Google’s deci-
sion appears to be motivated by ‘‘trying to cut down on tracking
without kneecapping revenue for websites.’’
1373
Several observers have noted that this change would have the
likely effect of reinforcing Google’s power and harming rivals, shift-
ing more advertisers toward Google.
1374
In particular, market par-
ticipants are concerned that, while Google phases out third-party
cookies needed by other digital advertising companies, Google can
still rely on data collected throughout its ecosystem.
During the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Representative Kelly
Armstrong (R–ND) asked Mr. Pichai, ‘‘[D]o you have other ways of
collecting it [data] through Gmail or consumer facing plat-
forms?’’
1375
Mr. Pichai responded, ‘‘[T]o the extent on the services
where we provide ads and if users have consented to ads personal-
ization, yes, we do have data.’’
1376
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00198 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
193
1377
Ethan Russell, 9 Things to Know About Google’s Maps Data: Beyond the Map, G
OOGLE
C
LOUD
(Sept. 30, 2019), https://cloud.google.com/blog/products/maps-platform/9-things-know-
about-googles-maps-data-beyond-map.
1378
Royal Bank of Canada Report at 5.
1379
Id.
1380
R
OSS
S
ANDLER
, B
ARCLAYS
, A
LPHABET
I
NC
.: S
TEADY
C
OMPOUNDER
, W
ITH
P
LENTY OF
I
NNO
-
VATION
A
HEAD
20 (Mar. 28, 2017) (on file with Comm.).
1381
Scarlett Pruitt, Google Test Drives New Search Tool, PC W
ORLD
(Sept. 23, 2003), https://
www.pcworld.com/article/112604/article.html.
1382
Google Maps, A
CQUIRED
(Aug. 26, 2019), https://www.acquired.fm/episodes/google-
maps.
1383
Id.
1384
Google Acquires Keyhole, W
ALL
S
T
. J.: N
EWS
R
OUNDUP
(Oct. 27, 2004), https://
www.wsj.com/articles/SB109888284313557107; Michael Bazeley, Google Acquires Traffic Info
Start-up ZipDash, V
ENTURE
B
EAT
(Mar. 30, 2005), https://venturebeat.com/2005/03/30/google-
acquires-traffic-info-start-up-zipdash/.
1385
Elizabeth Reid, A Look Back at 15 Years of Mapping the World, G
OOGLE
: T
HE
K
EYWORD
(Feb. 6, 2020), https://blog.google/products/maps/look-back-15-years-mapping-world/.
1386
Id.
1387
Frederic Lardinois, Google’s Ground Truth Initiative for Building More Accurate Maps
Now Covers 50 Countries, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Sept. 3, 2014), https://techcrunch.com/2014/09/03/
googles-ground-truth-initiative-for-building-more-accurate-maps-now-covers-50-countries/.
1388
Greg Miller, The Huge, Unseen Operation Behind the Accuracy of Google Maps, W
IRED
(Dec. 8, 2014), https://www.wired.com/2014/12/google-maps-ground-truth/ (‘‘As of December
2014, Google’s ‘Street View cars ha[d] driven over 7 million miles, including 99 percent of the
public roads in the U.S.’ ’’).
1389
Id.
6. Maps
(a) Overview. Google dominates the market for digital maps with
over a billion users.
1377
Between Google Maps and Waze—which
Google also owns—the corporation captures an estimated 80 per-
cent of the navigation app market.
1378
Financial analysts have de-
scribed navigation maps as a ‘‘utility’’ that people cannot do with-
out,
1379
and one bank estimated that if Google Maps were a stand-
alone product, its market capitalization would hit $61.5 billion.
1380
Google Maps can be traced to a series of acquisitions. In Sep-
tember 2003, Google Labs launched ‘‘Search by Location,’’ a feature
that sought to filter search results based on a user’s geographic lo-
cation.
1381
Because Google lacked mapping data, however, the fea-
ture stalled.
1382
In October 2004, a few months after Google’s IPO,
Google acquired Where 2 Technologies, an Australian startup that
created web-based dynamic maps.
1383
Google soon followed this ac-
quisition with two additional purchases: Keyhole, a firm that used
satellite images and aerial photos to create digital-mapping soft-
ware; and ZipDash, a provider of real-time traffic information cap-
tured through GPS.
1384
In February 2005, Google launched Google
Maps.
1385
The following year, Google introduced Google Maps API, which
enabled developers to use and build on top of its digital
maps.
1386
In 2008, it launched ‘‘Ground Truth,’’ a project devoted
to assembling and refining underlying mapping data and im-
ages.
1387
This effort included Google Street View Cars, which drove
around the country—and, eventually, the world—taking pictures of
the surrounding buildings and landscapes, and delivering Google
structured data that it could use to create digital maps.
1388
As part
of Project Ground Truth, Google also obtained mapping information
from satellite and aerial imagery, as well as from public data-
bases.
1389
A 2008 budget request for Ground Truth stated that the goal of
the project was ‘‘long term independence from Tele Atlas and
Navteq,’’ two sources of mapping data that Google had been using
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00199 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
194
1390
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–03386002 (Dec. 6,
2007) (on file with Comm.).
1391
Id.
1392
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04211018 (Oct. 17, 2010).
1393
Chris Gaither, Overtaking MapQuest a Challenge for Yahoo, L.A. T
IMES
(Jan. 10, 2005),
https://www.latimes.com/archives/la-xpm-2005-jan-10-fi-maps10-story.html.
1394
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–03610422 (Oct. 28,
2008) (on file with Comm.).
1395
Announcing Google Maps Navigation for Android 2.0, G
OOGLE
: O
FF
. B
LOG
(Oct. 28, 2009),
https://googleblog.blogspot.com/2009/10/announcing-google-maps-navigation-for.html.
1396
Jenna Wortham & Miguel Helft, Hurting Rivals, Google Unveils Free Phone GPS, N.Y.
T
IMES
(Oct. 28, 2009), https://www.nytimes.com/2009/10/29/technology/companies/29gps
.html.
1397
Arik Hesseldahl, Garmin, TomTom Slash Prices Amid Google Threat, B
LOOMBERG
(Dec.
8, 2009), https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2009-12-08/garmin-tomtom-slash-prices-
amid-google-threat (stating that upon Google’s announcement, Garmin stock dropped around 16
percent and TomTom stock fell by around 29 percent).
1398
Jenna Wortham & Miguel Helft, Hurting Rivals, Google Unveils Free Phone GPS, N.Y.
T
IMES
(Oct. 28, 2009), https://www.nytimes.com/2009/10/29/technology/companies/29gps
.html (internal quotation marks omitted).
1399
Kevin J. O’Brien, Smartphone Sales Taking Toll on G.P.S. Devices, N.Y. T
IMES
(Nov. 14,
2010), https://www.nytimes.com/2010/11/15/technology/15iht-navigate.html.
1400
Charles Arthur, Navigating Decline: What Happened to TomTom?, G
UARDIAN
(July 21,
2015), https://www.theguardian.com/business/2015/jul/21/navigating-decline-what-happened-
to-tomtom-satnav.
1401
Experian Mktg. Servs., Google Maps Edges Closer to Mapquest, E
XPERIAN
B
LOG
(Feb. 11,
2009), http://www.experian.com/blogs/marketing-forward/2009/02/11/google-maps-edges-
closer-to-mapquest/.
1402
Id.
at the time and that were owned by TomTom and Nokia, respec-
tively.
1390
The presentation stated that achieving independence
would take several years and requested a five-to-seven-year re-
newal of the Tele Atlas contract to help Google bridge ‘‘between
now and completion of Google Truth initiatives.’’
1391
Although
Google Maps was not generating revenues, Google was investing in
it heavily. Google’s documents show that, from 2008 to 2009, the
company spent $32 million on the Street View program and $88.7
million on Ground Truth overall.
1392
When Google launched Google
Maps in 2005, MapQuest had been the ‘‘king of Internet-based
maps and driving directions,’’ with Yahoo gearing up to heavily
compete.
1393
By 2008, Google’s internal documents show that
Google was ‘‘#1 in Maps usage’’ as well as at the top in capturing
online local search.
1394
In 2009, Google introduced Google Maps for Mobile, a navigation
service featuring turn-by-turn directions, live traffic updates, and
automatic rerouting.
1395
Whereas market leaders TomTom and
Garmin sold navigation services through subscriptions, Google was
offering its service for free
1396
—a fact widely seen as disfavoring
the incumbents, whose stock prices fell upon Google’s announce-
ment.
1397
As one analyst noted at the time, ‘‘If it’s free and a good
service, why would you pay for something you can get for free?’’
1398
As smartphones overtook personal navigation devices, Google
Maps further eclipsed TomTom and Garmin.
1399
When asked in
2015 what had accounted for TomTom’s decline, its CEO cited two
factors: the 2008 economic crisis and the fact that ‘‘Google began
offering navigation for free.’’
1400
Some market participants at the time questioned whether Google
was using its search dominance to give Google Maps a boost. In
2009, one publisher noted that ‘‘61% of visits to Google Maps came
directly from Google,’’ giving it an advantage over MapQuest.
1401
The publisher wrote, ‘‘As long as Google dominates search,
MapQuest will face a tough battle for visits.’’
1402
A few years later,
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00200 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
195
1403
Letter from John M. Simpson, Priv. Project Dir., Consumer Watchdog, to William J. Baer,
U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Assistant Att’y Gen., Antitrust Div. (June 12, 2013), https://www
.consumerwatchdog.org/resources/cltrdojwaze061213.pdf.
1404
Brian McClendon, Google Maps and Waze, Outsmarting Traffic Together, G
OOGLE
B
LOG
(June 11, 2013), https://googleblog.blogspot.com/2013/06/google-maps-and-waze-outsmarting
.html; Vindu Goel, Google Expands Its Boundaries, Buying Waze for $1 Billion, N.Y. T
IMES
(June 11, 2013), https://bits.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/06/11/google-expands-its-boundaries-
buying-waze-for-1-billion/.
1405
Royal Bank of Canada Report at 10–11.
1406
How Mobile Search Connects Users to Stores, T
HINK
W
ITH
G
OOGLE
(May 2016), https://
www.thinkwithgoogle.com/marketing-strategies/app-and-mobile/mobile-search-trends-consumers
-to-stores/.
1407
See, e.g., Royal Bank of Canada Report at 20.
1408
R
OSS
S
ANDLER
, B
ARCLAYS
, A
LPHABET
, I
NC
.: S
TEADY
C
OMPOUNDER
, W
ITH
P
LENTY OF
I
NNO
-
VATION
A
HEAD
20 (Mar. 28, 2017) (on file with Comm.).
1409
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, A–4 (Nov. 22, 2019) (on file with
Comm.) (‘‘Google Maps has a number of features, including maps, turn-by-turn navigation and
directions, Street View, and information on local businesses (such as restaurants and services)
and travel destinations (such as hotels and tourist spots) that are also offered by competitors.
These competitors include Apple Maps, Bing Maps, TomTom, Yelp, TripAdvisor, Angie’s List,
and Facebook .... All of these competitors are widely used, with some having a strong presence
on key platforms: for example, one report from 2015 estimated that iPhone users use Apple
Maps three times more than Google Maps. However, we are not aware of any public market
share estimates that reflect the frequency of multi-homing among users or that account for com-
petitors like TripAdvisor, OpenTable, Yelp, or directory apps such as Yellow Pages that overlap
with many of the features of Google Maps, which would reflect the full range of robust competi-
tion in maps that drives Google to continually invest and innovate in the Google Maps prod-
uct.’’).
Consumer Watchdog wrote a letter to the Antitrust Division noting
that Google ‘‘was able to muscle its way to dominance by unfairly
favoring its own service ahead of such competitors as Mapquest in
its online search results.’’
1403
In 2013, Google purchased Waze, an Israeli crowd-sourced map-
ping provider, for $1.3 billion.
1404
The acquisition solidified
Google’s dominance in turn-by-turn navigation, eliminating its only
meaningful competitive threat.
While Google captured the navigation market by offering Google
Maps for free, even as it generated no revenue, Google now mone-
tizes both Waze and Google Maps through selling ads. In 2013,
Google introduced a limited form of maps advertising, and in recent
years, it has expanded the program, allowing local businesses to
purchase advertising on maps to maximize foot traffic.
1405
Re-
search by Google shows that 76 percent of users who search for lo-
cations nearby end up visiting a related business within a day and
that 28 percent of those searches ultimately lead to a purchase.
1406
This high conversion rate leads analysts to believe that Google
Maps alone could help drive between $1.9 billion and $3.7 billion
of incremental revenue by 2021.
1407
Commenting on the value of
Google Maps to the Google ecosystem, one analyst noted:
[Google Maps’] user base has been impressive for years, crossing 1B a few years
ago, but monetization is just getting started .... Maps is the closest thing to a
platform that Google has at the application layer, with three stakeholders in the
ecosystem: (1) users; (2) publishers; and (3) advertisers. The importance of Maps
to mobile, including both the advertising and transportation-on-demand spaces,
is one of the biggest potential markets Google is servicing in the future.
1408
(b) Market Power. Google Maps is the dominant provider of map-
ping data and turn-by-turn navigation services. The company de-
clined to provide the Committee with information about the market
share captured by Google Maps.
1409
According to a third-party esti-
mate, however, Google Maps combined with Waze captures 81 per-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00201 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
196
1410
Royal Bank of Canada Report at 4.
1411
Submission from Source 564, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Nov. 13, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
1412
Interview with Source 703 (June 22, 2020).
1413
Id.
1414
Id.
1415
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 589 (response to Questions for the Record
from Kyle Andeer, Vice President, Corp. Law, Apple, Inc.).
1416
Royal Bank of Canada Report at 10–11.
1417
Id. at 1.
1418
Uber Techs., Inc., Registration Statement (Form S–1) 46 (Apr. 11, 2019), https://
www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1543151/000119312519103850/d647752ds1.htm.
1419
Id. It is unclear whether Uber pays Google for the underlying maps data or for the place
search function, both of which are part of ‘‘Google Maps Core Services.’’
1420
Id. at 254.
cent of the market for turn-by-turn navigation services.
1410
One
market participant, meanwhile, estimated that Google Maps’ API
captures over 90 percent of the business-to-business market.
1411
Several developers stated that Google Maps introduced greater
licensing restrictions as it gained a stronger market position. One
noted that Google’s control over what now serves as a key mapping
technology has allowed Google to call all the shots.
1412
‘‘We license
Google Maps and it’s essentially a contract of adhesion. It’s full of
restrictions and we aren’t able to negotiate any changes,’’ the devel-
oper said.
1413
The developer added that they have explored switch-
ing to alternative mapping providers, but that no other provider
has the same geographic depth and coverage as Google Maps.
‘‘Other providers still value us and want to know how they can ac-
commodate us,’’ they said. ‘‘With Google, we just have to comply
with all their restrictions.’’
1414
Several factors suggest that Google Maps is well-positioned to
maintain its dominance. The high fixed costs of creating mapping
data pose a significant barrier to entry. Apple, which recently built
its mapping database from the ground up, told the Subcommittee
that the effort required billions of dollars.
1415
Google, moreover,
also benefits from an enormous lead in the tracking and processing
of location data, as well as from the prevalence of tracking-enabled
Android devices.
1416
Commenting on its monetization potential, an
analyst recently wrote that Google Maps has ‘‘reasonably sustain-
able moats.’’
1417
Certain businesses have made public disclosures about their reli-
ance on Google Maps. For example, in 2019, Uber disclosed that it
relies on Google Maps for ‘‘the mapping function that is critical to
the functionality’’ of its platform.
1418
It added, ‘‘We do not believe
that an alternative mapping solution exists that can provide the
global functionality that we require to offer our platform in all of
the markets in which we operate.’’
1419
Uber disclosed that between
January 1, 2016 and December 31, 2018, the company paid Google
$58 million for use of Google Maps.
1420
In a submission to the Subcommittee, one market participant
who uses Google Maps to power its reservation system, website,
and mobile app, stated that there are no alternatives to using
Google Maps. It wrote, ‘‘Local businesses are most likely to use
Google’s tools to index their websites because Google controls the
search engine space, which has the ability to deliver—or restrict—
whether these websites appear in corresponding links in consumer
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00202 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
197
1421
Submission from Source 333, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Oct. 21, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1422
Id.
1423
Id.
1424
Mark Bergen & Ben Brody, Google’s Waze Deal Is a Likely Target in FTC Antitrust
Sweep, B
LOOMBERG
(Feb. 14, 2020), https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2020-02-14/
google-s-waze-deal-is-a-likely-target-in-new-ftc-antitrust-sweep.
1425
Id.
1426
Id.
1427
Id.
1428
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04208423 (June
2013) (on file with Comm.).
1429
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04211080 (July 24, 2013) (citing the U.S. Census Bureau’s TIGER
mapping data as one source).
search results.’’
1421
The market participant added that this de-
pendence reinforces Google’s market power, as it ‘‘provides Google
with another opportunity to monetize companies’ supply chains and
leverage its pricing power over companies that need to promote
their businesses and/or purchase ad space to grow.’’
1422
This busi-
ness predicted that ‘‘the data advantages that Google incorporates
into its tools will only grow with time, making it impossible for a
new player to ever achieve the scale, user base, or database nec-
essary to compete.’’
1423
(c) Merger Activity. Google has made several acquisitions related
to digital mapping: Where2Technologies (2004); Keyhole (2004);
Skybox (2011); and Waze (2013). Of these acquisitions, only Waze—
for which Google paid $1.1 billion—was subject to an antitrust in-
vestigation. Although Google did not originally report the Waze
transaction, both the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) and the
United Kingdom’s Office of Fair Trading (OFT) reviewed the
deal.
1424
Both enforcers initially approved the transaction but have
since revisited the decision. In 2019, the OFT commissioned a
study reviewing its past merger cases, including Google/Waze, and
the FTC is reportedly examining the Waze deal as part of its
broader review of previous tech mergers.
1425
Materials that the FTC produced to the Subcommittee suggest
that the Commission’s analysis of the Google/Waze deal was lim-
ited. A document from the FTC shows that the agency focused on
assessing the quality of Waze’s data and concluded that its maps
were ‘‘not a Google maps replacement.’’
1426
It is unclear if or how
closely the agency considered that Google was acquiring Waze not
for its mapping features (which Google’s own documents had sug-
gested were inferior to Google’s), but in order to eliminate an inde-
pendent source of mapping data.
1427
In acquiring Waze, Google bought out one of the few companies
in the world making navigable maps while also providing turn-by-
turn navigation service.
1428
Founded in Israel, Waze had entered
the U.S. market by initially relying on public domain data, which
it refined through input from drivers.
1429
Waze’s model has relied
on user-generated maps, whereby drivers using Waze’s app feed
real-time data back into the app, and volunteer ‘‘editors’’
proactively fine-tune the maps by fixing street names, adding busi-
nesses, and making other updates. Waze’s documents reveal that,
through 2012, the firm had prioritized achieving growth and at-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00203 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
198
1430
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04208066 (June 2013) (Waze was ‘‘earning $250k in revenue in Janu-
ary 2013 and less than $1 million in revenue in 2012’’).
1431
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04208423.
1432
Id.
1433
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04208281 (May 2012).
1434
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04208072 (Nov. 2012).
1435
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04209632.
1436
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04208127 (May 2013).
1437
Id.
1438
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04208140.
1439
Id.
1440
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04213996 (June 2013).
1441
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04208047.
1442
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04211046 (July 24, 2013).
tracting users over earning revenue, although it had begun to mon-
etize its navigation app through location-based advertising.
1430
Internal Waze presentations stated that its crowd-sourced data
was one of the company’s defining features. One presentation stat-
ed, ‘‘The DNA of the company is of a social network, and user gen-
erated, we are merely the stage, and not the performers.’’
1431
In
a 2013 document, Waze identified its two main competitive advan-
tages: first, the fact that Waze was a real-time map with fresh
data, accounting for updates such as car accidents and road clo-
sures; and, second, that its business involved ‘‘zero cost.’’
1432
Google’s documents reveal that, by 2012, Google Maps was the
top provider of digital maps in desktop, mobile, and API,
1433
and
it was closely tracking Waze’s fast growth. One Google presentation
in 2012 noted that Waze was the most-downloaded app in the navi-
gation category, and that it was seeing a 30 percent increase in
daily downloads and averaging around 100,000 downloads a
day.
1434
Google also honed in on the fact that Waze was the only
other mapping provider that was vertically integrated across the
full stack, spanning the provider, application, map, traffic, and
search layers.
1435
In an internal presentation, Google identified several strategic
rationales for acquiring Waze.
1436
These included obtaining a
‘‘highly-engaged community of map contributors and expertise’’ in
order to ‘‘nurture/grow communities,’’ which Google said it strug-
gled with; achieving a ‘‘scalable solution’’ for maintaining a fresh
map with ‘‘real-time incident data’’; using Waze as a ‘‘sandbox’’ to
‘‘test map/navigation features’’; and acquiring a ‘‘highly-talented
team’’ with ‘‘deep experience in maps.’’
1437
Google also ranked
Waze poorly on several metrics, including the accuracy of its re-
sults in smaller cities and its limited map search capabili-
ties.
1438
Commenting on Waze’s mapping tiles, Google wrote,
‘‘[D]ata is missing and rendering is overly simple and missing de-
tail.’’
1439
Meanwhile, Google described Waze’s future financial pro-
jections as ‘‘highly speculative,’’
1440
and noted that its purchase
price of just under $1 billion was ‘‘expensive for a company with
<$1 million in 2012 revenue.’’
1441
In its correspondence with the FTC, Google stated that ‘‘there is
no shortage of full-featured navigation alternatives for users,’’
which it said reflected the ‘‘low (and continually decreasing) bar-
riers to entry.’’
1442
Google emphasized Waze’s entry, in particular,
focusing on how Waze ‘‘spent far less than $20 million for all pur-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00204 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
199
1443
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04211080.
1444
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04208696.
1445
Submission from Source 26, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 26–000622 (Sept. 21,
2013) (on file with Comm.).
1446
Id. See also Interview with Source 572 (Sept. 24, 2020).
1447
Interview with Source 572 (Sept. 24, 2020).
1448
Id.
1449
Id.
1450
Id.
poses in the two years preceding its US launch’’ and noting that it
was able to enter the market using only public domain data.
1443
In contrast, market participants viewed Google and Waze as
close competitors in a ‘‘highly concentrated’’ market for navigable
digital map databases and turn-by-turn navigation applications.
Prior to the transaction, Waze had observed that it and Google
were ‘‘the only vertically integrated stacks.’’
1444
One market partic-
ipant told antitrust enforcers that it viewed Waze as ‘‘Google’s clos-
est competitor for real-time, updated [turn-by-turn] navigation
services’’ and that Waze ‘‘was the digital-map competitor with the
best opportunity to overcome Google’s significant data and funding
advantage.’’
1445
Market participants cited a few reasons the transaction would
undermine competition. First, they noted that barriers to entry in
the market for turn-by-turn navigation providers were high and
that it would be difficult for new firms to enter. One market partic-
ipant stated, ‘‘Navigable digital map databases contain far more in-
formation than maps and addresses. For example, Google’s data-
base includes a range of other information, including traffic, condi-
tions and rerouting information, interior and exterior photographs,
reviews, commentary from Google+ friends.’’
1446
And Waze, in par-
ticular, had a unique crowd-sourced model that would be difficult
for other firms to replicate. Although Waze had secured a ‘‘first-
mover advantage’’ and acquired a ‘‘critical mass of users,’’ the
group of self-selected volunteers who edited Waze’s maps were ‘‘un-
likely to fill such a role (without payment) for more than one set
of mapping data.’’
1447
The market participant added, ‘‘Once those
editors provide the benefit of their input into Waze they create a
powerful map that passive Waze users will turn to as well given
the lack of other real-time-updated maps of comparable quality. As
a result, passive Waze users likely will have no incentive to multi-
home.’’
1448
Second, market participants pointed to the fact that Waze was
the only firm meaningfully positioned to dislodge Google Maps be-
cause it—like Google—lacked financial pressures. One entre-
preneur noted, ‘‘Google and Waze do not care how much it costs to
keep the maps up-to-date. Google because it has a lot of money,
and Waze because it relies on the community.’’
1449
One market
participant stated:
The acquisition would effectively lead to the elimination of Waze as a market
disrupting force that would otherwise be capable of challenging the model adopt-
ed by Google’s dominant Google Maps. In essence, Google’s acquisition of Waze
is defensive—seeking to remove a disruptive force from the market.
1450
Several market participants and advocates who opposed the deal
noted that Waze’s own CEO, Noam Bardin, had recently stated
that Waze was ‘‘the only reasonable competition’’ to Google Maps,
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00205 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
200
1451
Letter from John M. Simpson, Priv. Project Dir., Consumer Watchdog, to William J. Baer,
Assistant Att’y Gen., U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Antitrust Div. (June 12, 2013), https://www.
consumerwatchdog.org/resources/cltrdojwaze061213.pdf.
1452
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04211030 (July 24,
2013) (on file with Comm.).
1453
Royal Bank of Canada Report at 14.
1454
Interview with Source 572 (Sept. 24, 2020).
1455
Id.
1456
Royal Bank of Canada Report at 5.
1457
Jagmeet Singh, Google Maps API Price Hike Is Threatening the Future of Some Compa-
nies, G
ADGETS
360 (Aug. 28, 2018), https://gadgets.ndtv.com/apps/features/google-maps-apis-
new-pricing-impact-1907242.
1458
Id.
1459
Ishveena Singh, Insane, Shocking, Outrageous: Developers React to Changes in Google
Maps API, G
EO
A
WESOMENESS
(May 3, 2018), https://geoawesomeness.com/developers-up-in-
arms-over-google-maps-api-insane-price-hike/ (‘‘The Standard (no access to customer support)
and Premium plans are being merged into one pay-as-you-go pricing plan. And the new fee
structure is not pretty. Google is raising its prices by more than 1,400%. Obviously, no direct
comparison figures of old and new prices have been provided by Google, but that’s the average
surge that is being reported by developers.’’).
which would suggest that Google may have been pursuing the ac-
quisition in efforts to quash its most significant competitor.
1451
And third, market participants argued that the acquisition would
give Google both the incentive and ability to foreclose rivals, in-
cluding those apps that offer mobile navigation and social net-
working services. Seeking to mitigate this concern, Google’s letter
to the FTC emphasized the ‘‘numerous providers who license map-
ping, traffic, and incident’’ data for use in mobile apps.
1452
Today, the Google Maps and Waze teams remain separate. Ana-
lysts have reported that Google has used Waze as a tool to ‘‘test
and iterate on monetizing Navigation without disrupting its much
larger Google Maps asset.’’
1453
One market participant stated,
‘‘Google has used Waze as an ads guinea pig,’’
1454
noting that
Waze has released efficacy reports of location-tailored ads, informa-
tion that seems to have informed Google Maps’ recent expansion of
advertising.
1455
Since completing the Waze acquisition, Google has reportedly
come to capture 81 percent of the market for navigation mapping
services.
1456
Despite Google’s claims that entry barriers were low
and alternate offerings abundant, no meaningful competitor has
emerged since Google acquired Waze. Based on the materials the
FTC provided to the Subcommittee, it is unclear whether the Com-
mission fully assessed the barriers to entry. It instead appears the
FTC primarily took a static view—focusing on the existing quality
of Waze’s maps—rather than assessing the dynamic effects of the
acquisition.
(d) Conduct
(i) Raising Prices. For years, Google offered a free tier of the
Maps API, incentivizing developers to build their apps with Google
Maps. In 2018, however, Google Maps introduced a single ‘‘pay-as-
you-go’’ pricing plan for the core mapping APIs.
1457
This shift dra-
matically reduced the number of free Maps API calls a firm could
make—from 25,000 per day to around 930 per day.
1458
Developers
stated that the change amounted to a price increase of 1,400 per-
cent.
1459
In a submission to the Subcommittee, one market participant
said that Google instituted this price hike after ‘‘gaining domi-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00206 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
201
1460
Submission from Source 564, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Nov. 13, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
1461
Id. at 4.
1462
Submission from Source 685, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 4 (Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1463
Id.
1464
Jagmeet Singh, Google Maps API Price Hike Is Threatening the Future of Some Compa-
nies, G
ADGETS
360 (Aug. 28, 2018), https://gadgets.ndtv.com/apps/features/google-maps-apis-
new-pricing-impact-1907242.
1465
Google Maps Platform Terms of Service, G
OOGLE
§ 21, https://cloud.google.com/maps-
platform/terms (last visited Oct. 3, 2020) (‘‘ ‘Google Maps Content’ means any content provided
through the Service (whether created by Google or its third-party licensors), including map and
terrain data, imagery, traffic data, and places data (including business listings).’’).
1466
Id. § 3.2.2(e).
nance.’’
1460
Since becoming a Google Maps customer, the market
participant’s costs ‘‘have increased over 20×’’ and ‘‘there are no via-
ble alternatives.’’
1461
Another developer stated that the 2018 pric-
ing change ‘‘took our bill from $90/month in October to $20,000/
month in December.’’
1462
The developer stated that it was able to
subsequently reduce its bill through making a change that enabled
the location-retrieval function to occur directly on a user’s device—
a change that gave Google a ‘‘greater ability to identify and track’’
the device user.
1463
Several developers expressed their frustrations publicly, noting
that Google’s decision to hike prices so sharply, and without giving
developers significant notice, underscored its power to set the
terms of commerce. One developer stated:
I understand that Google wants to make this into a line of business. But it feels
like they’re taking advantage of us. They know that they’re the best, and that
no one else is even close. Instead of just giving us Maps for free or very cheap,
in exchange for collecting all our usage data, they now feel they need to charge
really high prices.
1464
In effect, Google makes market participants pay twice to access
Google Maps—first by giving Google their valuable usage data and
then again by paying Google’s volume-based fees for API calls.
(ii) Tying. Business-facing mapping products usually consist of a
core set of features to provide greater mapping functionality. For
example, the ‘‘Google Maps Platform’’ offers developers traffic data
and places data (also known as place search), as well as map
data.
1465
Some developers choose to mix and match, using map
data from one firm but placing data from another. Google, however,
prohibits developers from using any part of its mapping tools
alongside any non-Google mapping features. Until April 2020,
Google’s Maps Platform Terms of Service included the following
provision:
(e) No Use With Non-Google Maps. Customer will not use the Google Maps Core
Services in a Customer Application that contains a non-Google map. For exam-
ple, Customer will not (i) display Places listings on a non-Google map, or (ii) dis-
play Street View imagery and non-Google maps in the same Customer Applica-
tion.
1466
In April 2020, Google amended the language slightly:
(e) No Use With Non-Google Maps. To avoid quality issues and/or brand confu-
sion, Customer will not use the Google Maps Core Services with or near a non-
Google Map in a Customer Application. For example, Customer will not (i) dis-
play or use Places content on a non-Google map, (ii) display Street View imagery
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00207 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
202
1467
Id.
1468
Interview with Source 572 (Sept. 24, 2020).
1469
Interview with Source 157 (Sept. 25, 2020).
1470
Interview with Source 572 (Sept. 24, 2020).
1471
Id.
1472
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 424 (response to Questions for the Record
of Adam Cohen, Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC).
1473
Id.
1474
Interview with Source 572 (Sept. 24, 2020).
and non-Google maps on the same screen, or (iii) link a Google Map to non-
Google Maps content or a non-Google map.
1467
Both versions of this provision prohibit developers from using
any component of the Google Maps Core Service with mapping
services provided by non-Google firms. The April 2020 change to
the terms of service is even more restrictive: It prohibits developers
from even displaying any component of Google Maps ‘‘near’’ any
other map. In practice, Google’s contractual provision has led sev-
eral major companies to switch entirely to Google’s ecosystem, even
in cases where they preferred mapping services from a non-Google
provider, such as Mapbox.
Through interviews with market participants, the Subcommittee
learned that Google now enforces this provision aggressively. Ac-
cording to one firm, Google closely tracks and pressures developers
who use Google’s place data in conjunction with mapping data from
a non-Google firm, effectively forcing them to choose whether they
will use all of Google’s mapping services or none of them.
1468
One
firm described Google’s coercive tactics, stating, ‘‘It’s a bigger play-
er putting a gun to our head saying ‘switch or else.’ ’’
1469
Because Google’s monopoly in online search has furnished it with
a trove of data, as well as a robust index, its place search feature
is also seen by many market participants effectively as a must-
have. One market participant that has lost business partnerships
due to Google’s coercive restrictions stated that Google is ‘‘using ac-
cess to its dominant search products as leverage to intimidate busi-
nesses out of working with other map providers.’’
1470
He noted that
Google’s conduct now threatens his firm’s survival, saying, ‘‘This is
existential for us.’’
1471
Google was asked to identify and justify any limits it places on
the ability of app developers who use the Google Maps Platform to
use non-Google mapping services.
1472
Google responded that it does
‘‘restrict developers from incorporating Google Maps Core Services
into an application that uses a non-Google map’’ in order to ‘‘pre-
vent brand confusion and other negative user experiences.’’
1473
As
described above, Google subsequently changed its terms of service
to mirror its response to the Subcommittee’s question. However, de-
velopers and mapping providers questioned Google’s rationale, not-
ing that developers were the ones best positioned to determine
whether combining mapping services from multiple providers cre-
ated a ‘‘negative user experience.’’ One provider added, ‘‘The devel-
opers we partner with are extremely sophisticated. They’re not con-
fused.’’
1474
Google has also used its dominance in mapping to acquire cloud
computing customers for its Google Cloud Platform (GCP). Specifi-
cally, in 2018, Google implemented a change requiring all API calls
to use a valid API key, which must be linked to a Google Cloud
Platform account. All keyless calls to the Maps JavaScript API and
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00208 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
203
1475
Guide for Existing Users, G
OOGLE
C
LOUD
, https://cloud.google.com/maps-platform/user-
guide (last visited Oct. 3, 2020).
1476
Daria Bulatovych, Mapbox as a Worthy Alternative to Google Maps Price Hike, Y
ALANTIS
,
https://yalantis.com/blog/mapbox-maps-ready-mobile-apps/ (last visited Oct. 5, 2020).
1477
Larry Dignan, Top Cloud Providers in 2020: AWS, Microsoft Azure, and Google Cloud,
Hybrid, SaaS Players, ZDN
ET
(Oct. 1, 2020), https://www.zdnet.com/article/the-top-cloud-
providers-of-2020-aws-microsoft-azure-google-cloud-hybrid-saas/.
1478
What Is Map Caching?, A
RC
GIS E
NTER
., https://enterprise.arcgis.com/en/server/latest/
publish-services/linux/what-is-map-caching-.htm (last visited Oct. 3, 2020).
1479
Places API Policies, Google Maps Platform, G
OOGLE
, https://developers.google.com/
places/web-service/policies (last visited Oct. 3, 2020) (stating ‘‘that you must not pre-fetch,
index, store, or cache any Content except under the limited conditions stated in the terms’’).
1480
Interview with Source 521 (June 22, 2020).
1481
Id.
Street View API trigger low-resolution maps that are watermarked
with ‘‘for development purposes only.’’
1475
Developers who do not
have a Google Cloud account, and therefore do not have an API
key, are effectively locked out of Google Maps. Even if an applica-
tion is built on a non-Google cloud platform, developers are forced
to use GCP for the Maps API portion of their app.
1476
By one esti-
mate, revenue from Google Cloud Platform has more than tripled
since 2017, the year before Google began tying access to Google
Maps to Google Cloud Platform.
1477
(iii) Self-Preferencing Through Contractual Restrictions. Some de-
velopers told the Subcommittee that Google uses its control over
digital mapping to favor its own products in other lines of business.
Since Google provides mapping services but also offers non-map-
ping products that use mapping as an input, Google can selectively
degrade access for third parties that rely on its mapping product
to disfavor them as competitors to its non-mapping products. For
example, market participants noted that Google has added various
restrictions to the license agreement for Google Maps API—restric-
tions that apply to third-party developers but not to Google’s own
competing products.
One example is unequal rights to map caching. Map caching oc-
curs when a server stores copies of map images that it can speedily
distribute when next recalled. Without caching, a map is drawn
each time it is requested, a much slower process.
1478
Although pre-
vious versions of the Google Maps API agreement permitted
caching by developers, the recent versions prohibit caching of maps
with limited exceptions.
1479
Third-party apps built on Google Maps
API can no longer store a map cache. Market participants note,
however, that Google’s own products built on Google Maps—rang-
ing from its local search service to its hotel finder—face no similar
restrictions, enabling them to load faster than those run by third
parties.
Commenting on the asymmetry, one market participant stated
that Google’s decision to deny third parties caching ‘‘denigrates the
service that our maps can provide compared to Google’s.’’
1480
They
added, ‘‘[T]hat’s why we can’t create an app that provides direc-
tions as well as Google or we can’t update a user’s location as
quickly as Google.’’
1481
(iv) Strategic Platform Mismanagement. Although Google’s re-
sponses to the Subcommittees’ questions about its conduct regard-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00209 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
204
1482
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 403 (response to Questions for the Record
of Adam Cohen, Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC).
1483
Rob Copeland & Katherine Bindley, Millions of Business Listings on Google Maps Are
Fake—and Google Profits, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (June 20, 2019), https://www.wsj.com/articles/google-
maps-littered-with-fake-business-listings-harming-consumers-and-competitors-11561042283.
1484
Id.
1485
Id.
1486
Id. (Reporting that a 67-year-old woman contacted a local home repair service she found
through Google, only to be serviced by a man who was pretending to be from the company she
had hired. The man charged almost twice the cost of previous repairs and demanded a personal
check or cash. The woman told The Wall Street Journal, ‘‘I’m at my house by myself with this
guy. He could have knocked me over dead.’’).
1487
Id.
1488
Id.
1489
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 69 (question of Rep. Lucy McBath (D–GA),
Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judici-
ary).
1490
Id.
1491
Id. (statement of Adam Cohen, Dir. of Econ. Pol’y, Google LLC).
ing Google Maps emphasized ‘‘quality’’ and ‘‘user experience,’’
1482
public reporting has documented that Google Maps’ listings are
‘‘overrun with millions of false business addresses and fake
names.’’
1483
A fake listing can occur when a business creates a
fake listing or when a fraudulent business hijacks the name of a
legitimate business on Google Maps, diverting user calls or visits
from the legitimate business to a fraudulent one. A survey of ex-
perts conducted by The Wall Street Journal estimated that Google
Maps hosts around 11 million falsely listed businesses on any given
day.
1484
The same experts stated that ‘‘a majority’’ of the listings
on Google Maps for businesses such as ‘‘contractors, electricians,
towing and car repair services, movers and lawyers,’’ as well as
others, are not actually located at the location given by Google
Maps.
1485
These fake listings endanger consumer safety, giving rise to situ-
ations where users of Google Maps have unknowingly requested
home repairs and other services from fraudulent providers, ulti-
mately, paying inflated prices for shoddy work.
1486
The fraudulent
listings also disadvantage legitimate businesses, both those whose
listings have been hijacked as well as those whose own listings ap-
pear below those of sham businesses. Marketers have weaponized
this problem to demand ransom payments from businesses under
the threat of wiping out their listings through a flood of fake busi-
nesses. When the listing of one auto junkyard fell from the first to
the second page of Google Maps results, the owner’s income fell by
half and pushed him to the edge of closing shop entirely.
1487
Legitimate businesses hurt by fake listings say that contacting
Google to report the situation generally fails to resolve the prob-
lem. In practice, the only way legitimate businesses can shield
themselves from fake listings is to buy ads from Google. Ad prices
for categories that are most susceptible to ad fraud have increased
more than 50 percent over the last two years.
1488
The Subcommittee asked Google about this practice on several
occasions. At the Subcommittee’s July 16, 2019 hearing, Represent-
ative Lucy McBath (D–GA) asked Adam Cohen, Google’s director of
economic policy, what steps Google was taking to identify and re-
move fraudulent listings on Google Maps.
1489
She added, ‘‘Is it a
lack of competition in online search that allows Google to be so
complacent by addressing this problem head on?’’
1490
Mr. Cohen
responded that he was ‘‘not familiar’’ with the relevant facts.
1491
In
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00210 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
205
1492
Letter from Kent Walker, Senior Vice President, Glob. Affs. & Legal Officer, Google, to
Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.
Comm. on the Judiciary (July 26, 2019), https://judiciary.house.gov/sites/democrats.
judiciary.house.gov/files/documents/07.26.19%20-%20google%20response.pdf.
1493
Id.
1494
Rob Copeland & Katherine Bindley, Millions of Business Listings on Google Maps Are
Fake—and Google Profits, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (June 20, 2019), https://www.wsj.com/articles/google-
maps-littered-with-fake-business-listings-harming-consumers-and-competitors-11561042283 (in-
ternal quotation marks omitted).
1495
Id. (internal quotation marks omitted).
1496
Michael Arrington, Google Jumps Head First into Web Services with Google App Engine,
T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Apr. 8, 2008), https://techcrunch.com/2008/04/07/google-jumps-head-first-into-
web-services-with-google-app-engine/ (reporting that GCP’s first public cloud offering, App En-
gine, launched as a private preview for developers in April 2008).
1497
Benjamin Pimentel, Google Just Reported Cloud Revenue for the First Time Ever, Show-
ing that It’s Growing Fast but Nowhere Close to Amazon Web Services, B
US
. I
NSIDER
(Feb. 3,
2020), https://www.businessinsider.com/google-cloud-revenue-first-time-thomas-kurian-2020-2.
1498
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04266215 (on file
with Comm.).
1499
GCP’s position in the cloud market is explained in the cloud computing market overview
section. See supra Section IV.
1500
Snap Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 11 (Feb. 4, 2020) (indicating that Snap had com-
mitted to spend $2.0 billion with Google Cloud over five years beginning January 2017); Kevin
McLaughlin and Amir Efrati, TikTok Agreed to Buy More than $800 Million in Cloud Services
from Google, I
NFORMATION
(July 14, 2020), https://www.theinformation.com/articles/tiktok-
agreed-to-buy-more-than-800-million-in-cloud-services-from-google (reporting that TikTok signed
a three-year agreement with GCP in 2019, with a minimum commitment of $800 million over
the time period).
1501
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04266215 (on file
with Comm.).
1502
Nan Boden, Orbitera Joins the Google Cloud Platform Team, G
OOGLE
(Aug. 8, 2016),
https://cloud.google.com/blog/products/gcp/orbitera-joins-the-google-cloud-platform-team (not-
Continued
response to a follow-up letter sent by Chair Cicilline, Google wrote
that it has ‘‘no evidence’’ that the number of fake listings on Google
Maps is around 10 million.
1492
Google stated that, as of July 2019,
it had taken down more than 3 million fake business profiles and
that it has ‘‘implemented strict policies and created tools that en-
able people to flag false content.’’
1493
Both digital advertisement experts and individuals engaging in
fraudulent activity believe that Google has turned a blind eye to
the problem. According to The Wall Street Journal, one ad spe-
cialist who was invited by Google to help root out the problem left
after concluding that Google ‘‘has obviously chosen not to solve the
problem.’’
1494
A business owner who helps facilitate the fake list-
ings says his activity leaves a ‘‘huge footprint’’ and yet Google is
‘‘just letting it happen.’’ He added, ‘‘I know Google knows.’’
1495
7. Cloud
Google Cloud Platform (GCP) is Google’s suite of public cloud
computing services that first launched in 2008.
1496
Today, Google
Cloud is Alphabet’s fastest-growing line of business, with revenues
in Q1 2020 hitting $2.78 billion, up 52 percent from $1.83 billion
in Q1 2019.
1497
Documents provided to the Subcommittee make
clear that the cloud market is a priority for the company.
1498
GCP
is the third largest provider of IaaS services in the United States
and has a year-over-year growth rate twice that of Amazon Web
Services—the current market leader.
1499
Today, GCP boasts long
term contracts with data-intensive companies such as Snap,
Spotify, and TikTok.
1500
The Subcommittee reviewed internal documents that outline
Google’s plans to invest significantly in acquisitions.
1501
To date,
these acquisitions include Orbitera,
1502
Cask Data, Velostrata, and
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00211 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
206
ing that GCP leveraged Orbitera technology to offer automated test drives and lead manage-
ment, custom pricing and billing, cloud cost visibility and control, and self-serve onboarding to
be fully integrated into the GCP console).
1503
Ingrid Lunden, Google Acquires Cask Data to Beef Up Its Tools for Building and Running
Big Data Analytics, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(May 16, 2018), https://techcrunch.com/2018/05/16/google-
acquires-cask-data-to-beef-up-its-tools-for-building-and-running-big-data-analytics/.
1504
Lauren Feiner & Jordan Novet, Google Cloud Boss Thomas Kurian Makes His First Big
Move—Buys Looker for $2.6 Billion, CNBC (June 6, 2019), https://www.cnbc.com/2019/06/06/
google-buys-cloud-company-looker-for-2point6-billion.html.
1505
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04167298 to
–04167381 (July 2, 2019) (on file with Comm.). See also Donna Goodison, Google Cloud’s New
Alooma Migration Service Won’t Accept New AWS, Microsoft Azure Customers, CRN (Feb 20,
2019), https://www.crn.com/news/cloud/google-cloud-s-new-alooma-migration-service-won-t-ac-
cept-new-aws-microsoft-azure-customers.
1506
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–02456801 (on file
with Comm.). See also id. at GOOG–HJC–04214427 (Aug 4, 2016).
1507
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04266213 (May 23, 2018).
1508
Id. at GOOG–HJC–04215099 (Dec. 31, 2018).
1509
Id.
1510
See supra Section IV.
Elastifile, among others.
1503
Most recently, Google purchased Look-
er for $2.6 billion to ‘‘add a new analytics tool for Google Cloud’s
customers.’’
1504
In some instances, Google acquired firms that
were multi-cloud solutions but, after acquisition, Google made them
compatible only with Google’s cloud infrastructure, at times inte-
grating them into first-party PaaS and SaaS offerings only avail-
able through the Google Cloud Portal.
1505
According to interviews with market participants and Google’s
internal documents, Google employs two strategies that raise con-
cerns about potential anticompetitive conduct. First, Google ap-
pears to leverage its dominant business lines, including popular
APIs such as Google Search and Maps, along with machine learn-
ing services, to attract customers to its platform through discounts
and free tier services.
1506
For example, according to internal strat-
egy documents, in 2018, Google ‘‘launched a program with the Play
team to provide GCP credits to game developers based on their
Play Store spend, to increase focus on Play and incentivize migra-
tion to GCP.’’
1507
By harnessing Google’s advantages in existing
markets, GCP is undermining competition on the merits.
Second, Google’s documents suggest the company is considering
bundling its popular machine learning service with other services
that Google is seeking to promote. One recent Google cloud pricing
strategy document explains, ‘‘the question that we need to think
about is whether we use our entry point with Big Query to get a
customer to use all the services such as Data Proc, Data Flow, as
a suite and give them a price break on the Analytics Suite because
it will be much harder for them to migrate away from us if they
use all the other services.’’
1508
The document goes on to describe
potential discounts and ultimately a plan to have ‘‘a pricing model
that makes it advantageous for customers to put 80 percent of their
workload on GCP.’’
1509
As described elsewhere in this Report, ab-
sent interventions, the barriers to entry and network effects in this
market mean there is a high potential for single-homing and an
overall concentrated market.
1510
As Google grows in this space,
regulators and enforcers should be watchful for potential anti-
competitive conduct.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00212 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
207
1511
Amazon.com, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 3 (Jan. 31, 2020), http://d18rn0p25
nwr6d.cloudfront.net/CIK-0001018724/4d39f579-19d8-4119-b087-ee618abf82d6.pdf.
1512
Press Release, Amazon, Amazon.com Announces Second Quarter Results 2 (July 30,
2020), https://s2.q4cdn.com/299287126/files/doclfinancials/2020/q2/Q2-2020-Amazon-Earn-
ings-Release.pdf; Charles Duhigg, Is Amazon Unstoppable?, N
EW
Y
ORKER
(Oct. 21, 2019),
https://www.newyorker.com/magazine/2019/10/21/is-amazon-unstoppable.
1513
Amazon.com, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 83–84 (Mar. 9, 2005), https://
www.annualreports.com/HostedData/AnnualReportArchive/a/NASDAQlAMZNl2004.pdf;
Saul Hansell, Amazon Reports First Full-Year Profit, N.Y. T
IMES
(Jan. 28, 2004), https://www
.nytimes.com/2004/01/28/business/technology-amazon-reports-first-full-year-profit.html.
1514
See, e.g., CEO Hearing at 15 (statement of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.) (‘‘As I
have said since my first shareholder letter in 1997, we make decisions based on the long-term
value we create . . . .’’); Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–
00035545 (July 14, 2010) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Membership programs are created with a long-
term, company-wide perspective with the goal of increasing loyalty and cross-category shopping
behavior. The programs do not optimize for short-term gain or profitability in a single cat-
egory.’’).
1515
See, e.g., Annie Palmer, Jeff Bezos Is Now Worth More than $200 Billion, CNBC (Aug.
26, 2020), https://www.cnbc.com/2020/08/26/amazon-ceo-jeff-bezos-worth-more-than-200-
billion.html.
1516
Prepared by the Subcommittee based on Amazon.com, Inc., Annual Reports (Form 10–
K) (1997–2019).
C. Amazon
1. Overview
Amazon.com, Inc. was founded in 1994 as an online book-
seller.
1511
Today, it is one of the largest companies in the world.
Based in Seattle, Amazon is estimated to be the second-largest pri-
vate employer in the United States, with over 500,000 employ-
ees.
1512
The company operates across a wide range of direct-to-con-
sumer and business-to-business markets, including e-commerce,
consumer electronics, television and film production, groceries,
cloud services, book publishing, and logistics. Amazon went public
in 1997 but did not post its first full-year profit until 2003.
1513
This
is partly because Amazon’s business strategy has generally focused
on long-term growth over short-term profits.
1514
Amazon is cur-
rently one of the most valuable companies in the world, and its
CEO, Jeff Bezos, is reported to be the wealthiest person in the
world.
1515
Amazon’s Annual Revenue, Operating Expenses,
and Profits
1516
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00213 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 19 here 11701.019
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
208
1517
Amazon.com, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 3 (Jan. 31, 2020), http://d18rn0p25
nwr6d.cloudfront.net/CIK-0001018724/4d39f579-19d8-4119-b087-ee618abf82d6.pdf.
1518
Id. at 18.
1519
Id. at 24.
1520
Id. at 3; see also Nathan Reiff, How Amazon Makes Money, I
NVESTOPEDIA
(Aug. 12,
2020), https://www.investopedia.com/how-amazon-makes-money-4587523 (‘‘Retail remains Ama-
zon’s primary source of revenue, with online and physical stores accounting for the biggest
share.’’).
1521
Amazon.com, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 24–25 (Jan. 31, 2020), http://d18rn0p25
nwr6d.cloudfront.net/CIK-0001018724/4d39f579-19d8-4119-b087-ee618abf82d6.pdf.
1522
J.P. M
ORGAN
, R
ETAIL VS
. A
MAZON
: L
IFE IN A
P
OST
COVID–19 W
ORLD
(2020), https://
markets.jpmorgan.com/research/email/-lbk68f4/Alp1kP9tQUPS29jlzWl3bOg/GPS-3397412-0.
1523
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 499 (response to Questions for the Record
of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1524
Number of Sellers on Amazon Marketplace, M
ARKETPLACE
P
ULSE
, https://www
.marketplacepulse.com/amazon/number-of-sellers (last visited Sept. 25, 2020); see also CEO
Hearing at 17 (statement of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.) (‘‘There are now 1.7 million
small and medium-sized businesses around the world selling in Amazon’s stores.’’).
1525
Number of Sellers on Amazon Marketplace, M
ARKETPLACE
P
ULSE
, https://www
.marketplacepulse.com/amazon/number-of-sellers (last visited Oct. 5, 2020).
1526
J
UNGLESCOUT
, T
HE
S
TATE OF THE
A
MAZON
S
ELLER
2020, at 4 (2020), https://www
.junglescout.com/wp-content/uploads/2020/02/State-of-the-Seller-Survey.pdf.
Amazon reports financial information for three business seg-
ments: North America, International, and Amazon Web Services
(AWS), Amazon’s cloud services business.
1517
Despite the fact that
Amazon is already so large that it dominates several important in-
dustries, it continues to report strong and steady growth—as well
as increasing profits. For 2019, Amazon reported total revenue of
about $280 billion, up 20 percent from the previous year, and a net
income of over $11 billion.
1518
AWS’s revenue increased by 37 per-
cent in 2019 to $35 billion.
1519
Retail operations continue to be the
platform’s largest source of revenue, but AWS is a key source of its
overall profits.
1520
In 2019, Amazon’s cloud business contributed
over 60 percent of Amazon’s total operating income, despite ac-
counting for only 12.5 percent of its total revenue.
1521
Sales on Amazon.com fall into one of two categories. First-party
sales are those where Amazon retails its own private-label products
or sources products wholesale from a vendor or manufacturer.
Third-party sales, in contrast, refer to sales by independent mer-
chants who sell through the Amazon Marketplace. When a con-
sumer visits Amazon.com, Amazon’s private-label products, such as
AmazonBasics or its Kindle E-Readers, are listed for sale alongside
independent merchants’ offers.
One of the unique features of Amazon’s e-commerce site is its
fast and free shipping on an extremely broad selection of products.
Amazon Prime Members can choose from over 100 million items
that are available for free two-day delivery in the continental
United States. Walmart, by contrast, has only single-digit millions
of products eligible for free two-day shipping.
1522
In response to
questions from the Subcommittee, Amazon represented that it of-
fers approximately 158,000 private-label products across 45 in-
house brands, not including some additional private-label products
sold through Amazon Fresh.
1523
Amazon also hosts 2.3 million ac-
tive third-party sellers from around the world,
1524
about 45 times
more than the 52,000 third-party sellers that Walmart hosts on its
marketplace.
1525
A recent survey estimated that about 37 percent
of Amazon’s third-party sellers, representing over 850,000 sellers,
rely on Amazon as their sole source of income.
1526
Amazon does not limit the number of sellers that can offer the
same product for sale on its platform. Because of this, the same
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00214 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
209
1527
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 498 (response to Questions for the Record
of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1528
Id.
1529
F
EEDVISOR
, T
HE
A
MAZON
B
UY
B
OX
P
LAYBOOK FOR
S
ELLERS AND
R
ETAILERS
4 (2020).
1530
Id. at 5.
1531
CEO Hearing at 282 (response to Questions for the Record of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Ama-
zon.com, Inc.).
1532
FBA Usage Among Amazon Marketplace Sellers, M
ARKETPLACE
P
ULSE
, https://
www.marketplacepulse.com/amazon/fulfillment-by-amazon-fba (last visited Oct. 5, 2020).
1533
Fulfillment by Amazon, A
MAZON
, https://sell.amazon.com/fulfillment-by-amazon.html
(last visited Sept. 28, 2020).
1534
Id.
product may be sold by multiple sellers, as well as by Amazon.
Each time a consumer clicks on a product, Amazon chooses a single
seller from all the vendors offering that product to display as the
featured offer in the ‘‘Buy Box.’’
1527
In its response to questions
from the Subcommittee, Amazon stated that the featured merchant
algorithm, also commonly referred to as the Buy Box algorithm, is
designed to predict the offer that consumers would choose after
comparing all the available offers in detail.
1528
The Amazon Buy Box Playbook, a well-known guide for sellers,
explains this in lay terms:
When a shopper lands on a product detail page, Amazon chooses one seller
whose details appear in the Buy Box—the white box on the right-hand side of
the page. When a customer clicks on the ‘‘Add to Cart’’ button, the sale goes to
the seller in this box.
1529
Industry experts estimate that about 80 percent of Amazon sales
go through the Buy Box, and the percentage is even higher for mo-
bile purchases.
1530
In response to a question from the Sub-
committee, Amazon provided only high-level information about how
it chooses which offer will win the Buy Box, stating that the algo-
rithm considers criteria such as price, delivery speed and cost,
Prime eligibility, and seller performance.
1531
Despite the impor-
tance of winning the Buy Box to sellers on its platform, only Ama-
zon knows exactly how its featured merchant algorithm works.
As Amazon’s e-commerce business has grown, it has also devel-
oped a significant logistics business providing fulfillment and deliv-
ery services to third-party sellers through its Fulfillment by Ama-
zon (FBA) program. Nearly 85 percent of the top 10,000 Amazon
Marketplace sellers reportedly rely on this program to fulfill and
deliver their orders.
1532
Third-party sellers that use FBA keep
their inventory in Amazon’s fulfillment centers.
1533
After a con-
sumer places an order online, Amazon does the picking, packing,
and shipping, and provides customer service to complete the
order.
1534
The figure below explains the different types of sellers on
Amazon.com and the various modes of delivery and fulfillment they
use.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00215 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
210
1535
Prepared by the Subcommittee based on Amazon 1P vs. 3P: What Are the Differences?,
F
EEDVISOR
, https://feedvisor.com/university/amazon-1p-vs-3p/ (last visited Sept. 24, 2020).
1536
Amazon.com, Inc., Quarterly Report (Form 10–Q) 18 (July 31, 2020), http://d18rn0p25
nwr6d.cloudfront.net/CIK-0001018724/a77b5839-99b8-4851-8f37-0b012f9292b9.pdf.
1537
Selling on Amazon Fee Schedule, A
MAZON
S
ELLER
C
ENT
., https://sellercentral
.amazon.com/gp/help/external/200336920 (last visited Sept. 25, 2020).
1538
Pricing Overview, A
MAZON
S
ELLER
C
ENT
. (2020), https://sell.amazon.com/pricing.html
(last visited Sept. 25, 2020); see also Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
12 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with Comm.) (noting that advertising revenue is not included in seller
services).
1539
Press Release, Gartner, Gartner Says Worldwide IaaS Public Cloud Services Market
Grew 31.3% in 2018 (July 29, 2019), https://www.gartner.com/en/newsroom/press-releases/
2019-07-29-gartner-says-worldwide-iaas-public-cloud-services-market-grew-31point3-percent-in-
2018; see also Letter from David Zapolsky, Gen. Couns., Amazon.com, Inc., to Hon. David N.
Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the
Judiciary, 6 (July 26, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
Types of Sellers on Amazon and Shipping Options
1535
Amazon generates a significant amount of revenue from the fees
that it charges third-party sellers. According to a recent SEC filing,
net sales for services provided to third-party sellers increased from
$23 billion in the first six months of 2019 to $32 billion over the
same period in 2020—an increase of 39 percent.
1536
For the ability
to sell a product on the platform, a seller might pay the company
a monthly subscription fee, a high-volume listing fee, a referral fee
on each item sold, and a closing fee on each item sold.
1537
Amazon
charges additional fees for fulfillment and delivery services, as well
as for advertising.
1538
AWS, the company’s cloud services business, offers digital infra-
structure services to businesses that require increased computing
infrastructure, such as increased capacity for servers to host or
store data. Amazon is the dominant provider of infrastructure as
a service. AWS accounts for close to half of all global spending on
cloud infrastructure services, and the business has three times the
market share of Microsoft, its closest competitor.
1539
Cloud serv-
ices are an essential and increasingly expensive line item for many
companies. Given AWS’s role as a dominant cloud provider, some
of Amazon’s competitors in other business lines often end up de-
pendent on the platform. For example, Netflix, a competitor of
Amazon Prime Video, paid AWS $500 million in 2018 to store its
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00216 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 20 here 11701.020
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
211
1540
Kevin McLaughlin, Amazon’s Cloud King: Inside the World of Andy Jassy, I
NFORMATION
(Jan. 23, 2019), https://www.theinformation.com/articles/amazons-cloud-king-inside-the-world-
of-andy-jassy.
1541
See, e.g., Alana Semeuls, Many Companies Won’t Survive the Pandemic. Amazon Will
Emerge Stronger Than Ever, T
IME
(July 28, 2020), https://time.com/5870826/amazon-
coronavirus-jeff-bezos-congress/ (‘‘Consumer spending on Amazon between May and July was up
60% from the same time frame last year.’’).
1542
M
ORNINGSTAR
E
QUITY
A
NALYST
R
EPORT
: Amazon.com, Inc 6 (Aug. 27, 2020) (on file with
Comm.); Press Release, Amazon, Amazon.com Announces First Quarter Results (Apr. 30, 2020),
https://s2.q4cdn.com/299287126/files/doclfinancials/2020/Q1/AMZN-Q1-2020-Earnings-
Release.pdf.
1543
M
ORNINGSTAR
E
QUITY
A
NALYST
R
EPORT
: Amazon.com, Inc 6 (Aug. 27, 2020) (on file with
Comm.).
1544
Amazon.com, Inc. Common Stock (AMZN), N
ASDAQ
, https://www.nasdaq.com/market-
activity/stocks/amzn (last visited Oct. 3, 2020).
1545
See Walmart, Inc. Common Stock (WMT), N
ASDAQ
, https://www.nasdaq.com/market-ac-
tivity/stocks/wmt (last visited Oct. 5, 2020) ($398 billion); Target Corp. Common Stock (TGT),
N
ASDAQ
, https://www.nasdaq.com/market-activity/stocks/tgt (last visited Oct. 5, 2020) ($79.6
billion); Salesforce.com, Inc. Common Stock (CRM), N
ASDAQ
, https://www.nasdaq.com/market-
activity/stocks/crm (last visited Oct. 5, 2020) ($225.5 billion); Int’l Bus. Machines Corp. Common
Stock (IBM), N
ASDAQ
, https://www.nasdaq.com/market-activity/stocks/ibm (last visited Oct. 5,
2020) ($107 billion); eBay, Inc. Common Stock (EBAY), N
ASDAQ
, https://www.nasdaq.com/
market-activity/stocks/ebay (last visited Oct. 5, 2020) ($36.2 billion); Etsy, Inc. Common Stock
(ETSY), N
ASDAQ
, https://www.nasdaq.com/market-activity/stocks/etsy (last visited Oct. 3,
2020) ($16.7 billion).
1546
See, e.g., Gabe Alpert, Top 5 Highest Priced Stocks in America, I
NVESTOPEDIA
(May 19,
2020), https://www.investopedia.com/financial-edge/0711/the-highest-priced-stocks-in-america
.aspx.
1547
See, e.g., Data and Privacy Hearing at 170 (statement of Margrethe Vestager, Eur.
Comm’r for Competition) (‘‘[I]n 2017 we accepted commitments from Amazon not to introduce
or enforce what are sometimes called ‘most-favoured nation’ clauses in the e-books market.’’);
Press Release, Bundeskartellamt, Bundeskartellamt Obtains Far-Reaching Improvements in the
Terms of Business for Sellers on Amazon’s Online Marketplaces (July 17, 2019), https://
www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Meldung/EN/Pressemitteilungen/2019/17l07l2019l
Amazon.html (‘‘In response to the competition concerns expressed by the Bundeskartellamt,
Amazon is amending its terms of business for sellers on Amazon’s online marketplaces.’’); Ama-
zon Online Retailer: Investigation into Anticompetitive Practices, U.K. C
OMPETITION &
M
KTS
.
A
UTH
. (Oct. 1, 2013), https://www.gov.uk/cma-cases/amazon-online-retailer-investigation-into-
anticompetitive-practices (‘‘In light of [Amazon’s] decision to remove the price parity policy and
subsequent steps to implement that decision . . . the [Office of Fair Trading] has decided to close
its investigation on administrative priority grounds.’’).
Amazon Prime Video, paid AWS $500 million in 2018 to store its
streaming video library.
1540
While the pandemic has harmed many businesses, Amazon has
experienced a surge in sales.
1541
The company’s operating profit of
$5.8 billion during the second quarter of 2020 significantly out-
performed the –$1.5 billion to +$1.5 billion projection that Amazon
had issued to investors.
1542
One analyst described the magnitude
of Amazon’s recent sales growth outperformance as a ‘‘paradigm-
shifting update.’’
1543
In October 2020, Amazon’s stock price was
about $3,000, giving it a market valuation of about $1.5 tril-
lion
1544
—greater than that of Walmart, Target, Salesforce, IBM,
eBay, and Etsy, combined.
1545
The company is consistently one of
the highest-priced stocks on Wall Street,
1546
which is a clear indi-
cation investors expect Amazon to maintain and expand its market
power.
The Subcommittee initiated its investigation of Amazon’s market
power and its role as a gatekeeper for digital markets in June
2019. Before and concurrent with the Subcommittee’s investigation,
many international and U.S. enforcement authorities also opened
antitrust investigations into Amazon’s business practices. Some of
these investigations have led to Amazon making policy changes.
1547
The European Commission began its in-depth antitrust investiga-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00217 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
212
1548
Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Opens Investigation into Possible
Anti-competitive Conduct of Amazon (July 17, 2019), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/
presscorner/detail/en/IPl19l4291.
1549
Submission from Margrethe Vestager, Exec. Vice President, Eur. Comm’n, to H. Comm.
on the Judiciary, 4 (July 24, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
1550
Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm’n, FTC to Examine Past Acquisitions by Large Tech-
nology Companies (Feb. 11, 2020), https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/press-releases/2020/02/ftc-
examine-past-acquisitions-large-technology-companies.
1551
Jason Del Rey, Amazon May Soon Face an Antitrust Probe. Here Are 3 Questions the FTC
Is Asking About It, V
OX
: R
ECODE
(June 4, 2019), https://www.vox.com/recode/2019/6/4/
18651694/amazon-ftc-antitrust-investigation-prime; Dina Bass, David McLaughlin & Naomi Nix,
Amazon Faces Widening U.S. Antitrust Scrutiny in Cloud Business, B
LOOMBERG
(Dec. 4, 2019),
https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2019-12-04/amazon-faces-widening-u-s-antitrust-
scrutiny-in-cloud-business.
1552
Tyler Sonnemaker, Amazon Is Reportedly Facing a New Antitrust Investigation into Its
Online Marketplace Led by the FTC and Attorneys General in New York and California, B
US
.
I
NSIDER
(Aug. 3, 2020), https://www.businessinsider.com/amazon-antitrust-probe-ftc-new-york-
california-online-marketplace-2020-8; Karen Weise & David McCabe, Amazon Said to Be Under
Scrutiny in 2 States for Abuse of Power, N.Y. T
IMES
(June 12, 2020), https://www.nytimes.com/
2020/06/12/technology/state-inquiry-antitrust-amazon.html.
1553
Bipartisan Letter from the Chair, Ranking Member, and Members of H. Comm. on the
Judiciary, to Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc. (May 1, 2020), https://judiciary.house.gov/
uploadedfiles/2020-05-01lletterltolamazonlceolbezos.pdf.
1554
See generally Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 30 (finding that recent financial
indicators suggest Amazon’s ‘‘dominan[ce] in a meaningfully distinct sector of online retail’’ will
endure and that ‘‘investors are expecting it to retain its dominant position, and to earn signifi-
cantly higher profits in future’’); Stigler Report at 78 (‘‘[T]he evidence thus far does suggest that
current digital platforms face very little threat of entry .... [T]he key players in this industry
remained the same over the last two technology waves, staying dominant through the shift to
mobile and the rise of AI. In the past, dominant business found it difficult to navigate innova-
tion or disruption waves. By contrast, Facebook, Google, Amazon, Apple, and even Microsoft
were able to ride these waves without significant impact on market share or profit margins.’’).
tion of Amazon on July 17, 2019.
1548
According to Executive Vice
President Margrethe Vestager, the European Commission’s inves-
tigation ‘‘focuses on the use by Amazon of accumulated, competi-
tively sensitive information about marketplace sellers, their prod-
ucts and transactions on the Amazon marketplace, which may in-
form Amazon’s retail business decisions.’’
1549
In the United States,
the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) is investigating Amazon’s
past acquisition activity.
1550
The FTC is also reportedly inves-
tigating Amazon’s treatment of third-party sellers and its cloud
services business.
1551
Additionally, Amazon reportedly faces anti-
trust scrutiny by state attorneys general offices in California,
Washington, and New York.
1552
During the course of the investigation, Amazon displayed a lack
of candor to the Subcommittee in response to questions about its
business practices. As Chair Nadler, Subcommittee Chair Cicilline,
and Ranking Member Sensenbrenner, along with other members of
the Committee, wrote to Mr. Bezos in a bipartisan letter in May
of this year, the Subcommittee was troubled that some of the
‘‘statements Amazon made to the Committee about the company’s
business practices appear to be misleading, and possibly criminally
false or perjurious.’’
1553
In light of this concern, the Subcommittee
views Amazon’s other claims and representations with a degree of
skepticism in instances where they conflict with credible sources,
such as investigative reporting, interviews with market partici-
pants, or other evidence uncovered by the Subcommittee during the
investigation.
2. Amazon.com
(a) Market Power. Amazon has significant and durable market
power in the U.S. online retail market.
1554
The company’s actual
share of U.S. e-commerce is unknown outside of Amazon because
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00218 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
213
1555
Andrew Lipsman, Top 10 US Ecommerce Companies 2020, E
MARKETER
(Mar. 10, 2020),
https://www.emarketer.com/content/top-10-us-ecommerce-companies-2020.
1556
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00206583
(2019) (on file with Comm.) (eMarketer Inc.—Global Ecommerce 2019 Report).
1557
See Kimberly Collins, Google + Amazon: Data on Market Share, Trends, Searches from
Jumpshot, S
EARCH
E
NGINE
W
ATCH
(Aug. 1, 2019), https://www.searchenginewatch.com/2019/
08/01/amazon-google-market-share/.
1558
See id.
1559
See Submission from Source 11, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file
with Comm.) (‘‘Amazon has amassed at least a 50% share of the ecommerce market and con-
tinues to expand, both its market share and the breadth of its offerings.’’); P
YMNTS
.
COM
,
W
ALMART VS
. A
MAZON
, W
HOLE
P
AYCHECK
T
RACKER
: B
ATTLE FOR THE
D
IGITAL
F
IRST
C
ONSUMER
6 (2020), https://securecdn.pymnts.com/wp-content/uploads/2020/09/Amazon-Walmart-Whole-
Paycheck-092020.pdf (estimating Amazon’s market share at 51.2 percent in Q1 2020 and 44.4
percent in Q2 2020, but noting U.S. e-commerce increased by 44 percent over the same period,
and that ‘‘[f]or Amazon to drop only 7 percent in total eCommerce share with that kind of over-
all increase is actually quite an achievement’’).
1560
See, e.g., Kimberly Collins, Google + Amazon: Data on Market Share, Trends, Searches
from Jumpshot, S
EARCH
E
NGINE
W
ATCH
(Aug. 1, 2019), https://www.searchenginewatch.com/
2019/08/01/amazon-google-market-share/; see also J.P. M
ORGAN
, R
ETAIL VS
. A
MAZON
: L
IFE IN
A
P
OST
COVID–19 W
ORLD
13 (2020) (Amazon’s market share of online sales of ‘‘Books & Maga-
zines’’ is 75 percent).
1561
See, e.g., Ben Evans, What’s Amazon’s Market Share?, B
ENEDICT
E
VANS
, https://
www.ben-evans.com/benedictevans/2019/12/amazons-market-share19#:#:text=Amazon%20has%
2050%25%20or%20more,it%20has%20over%2050%25 (‘‘Amazon has 50% or more of the US print
book market.’’); Submission from Source 17, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 33 (Nov. 14, 2019)
(on file with Comm.) (‘‘Amazon accounts for roughly 83 percent of all e-book sales, about 90 per-
cent of online print sales, and about 90 percent of digital audiobook sales.’’); Dig. Competition
Expert Panel Report at 30 (‘‘In the e-book market, Amazon was reported in February 2017 to
account for around 88% of total annual unit sales.’’).
1562
Submission from Top Shelf Brands, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 26 (Oct. 26, 2019) (on
file with Comm.) (citing D
IG
. C
OMMERCE
360, 2019 O
NLINE
M
ARKETPLACES
R
EPORT
).
it does not report the gross merchandise volume of third-party
sales made on its marketplace. A frequently cited analysis by mar-
ket research company eMarketer estimates that Amazon’s share in
this market is 38.7 percent.
1555
eMarketer’s estimate, however, is
likely understated because its definition of e-commerce is overly
broad. For example, under eMarketer’s approach to e-commerce,
the Auto and Parts category includes online sales of cars.
1556
In
contrast, marketing analytics company Jumpshot estimates that
Amazon captures an average of 74 percent of digital transactions
across a wide range of product categories.
1557
The Jumpshot anal-
ysis may overstate Amazon’s share because it calculates market
share as a percentage of transactions made on well-known market
participants’ websites, like Amazon, Walmart, and Target, but ex-
cludes small, online retailers.
1558
Based on the information the
Subcommittee gathered during its investigation, estimates that
place Amazon’s share of U.S. e-commerce at about 50 percent or
higher are more credible than lower estimates of 30–40 percent.
1559
In a number of key product categories, ranging from household
essentials to sports, fitness and outdoors, Amazon is reported to ac-
count for well over 50 percent of online sales.
1560
The platform also
has significant market power over the entire book industry, includ-
ing sales, distribution, and publishing. In the U.S. market, Amazon
accounts for over half of all print book sales and over 80 percent
of e-book sales.
1561
Amazon is the dominant online marketplace. It reportedly con-
trols about 65–70 percent of all U.S. online marketplace sales.
1562
The platform’s market power is at its height in its dealings with
third-party sellers, as well as many of its suppliers, which Amazon
refers to as vendors. Increasingly, Amazon is also gaining market
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00219 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
214
1563
See M
ARKETPLACE
P
ULSE
, M
ARKETPLACES
Y
EAR IN
R
EVIEW
48 (2019), https://cdn
.marketplacepulse.com/misc/marketplaces-year-in-review-2019.pdf (‘‘Amazon’s ‘business-to-busi-
ness,’ or B2B, marketplace is gaining market share faster than its retail operation.’’); Phone
Interview with Nat’l Ass’n of Wholesaler-Distributors (Sept. 3, 2020); S
TACY
M
ITCHELL &
O
LIVIA
L
AVECCHIA
, R
EPORT
: A
MAZON
S
N
EXT
F
RONTIER
: Y
OUR
C
ITY
S
P
URCHASING
4 (2018), https://
ilsr.org/amazon-and-local-government-purchasing/ (‘‘Amazon is leveraging its growing relation-
ship with local governments to induce more businesses to join its Marketplace.’’).
1564
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Oct. 14, 2019).
1565
See Complaint at 4, In re Edgewell Personal Care Co., No. 9390 (Fed. Trade Comm’n Feb.
2, 2020), https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/cases/publiclp3lcomplaintl-ledge
well-harrys.pdf.
1566
See Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 17 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
1567
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–0059575 (Nov.
22, 2010) (on file with Comm.).
1568
S
IMILARWEB
, W
ORLDWIDE
E-C
OMMERCE AND
S
HOPPING
C
ATEGORY
P
ERFORMANCE
(July
2020), https://pro.similarweb.com/#/industry/overview/E-commercelandlShopping/999/
1m/?webSource=Total (Amazon had 2.6 billion visits in July 2020 compared to 940.8 million vis-
its for eBay).
1569
Submission from Source 11, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1570
Lucy Koch, Looking for a New Product? You Probably Searched Amazon, E
MARKETER
(Mar. 31, 2019), https://www.emarketer.com/content/looking-for-a-new-product-you-probably-
searched-amazon (citing F
EEDVISOR
, T
HE
2019 A
MAZON
C
ONSUMER
B
EHAVIOR
R
EPORT
14 (2019));
see also W
UNDERMAN
T
HOMPSON
, T
HE
F
UTURE
S
HOPPER
R
EPORT
2020, at 11 (2020), https://
insights.wundermanthompsoncommerce.com/hubfs/@UK/Landing%20Pages/2020/The%20
Future%20Shopper%202020/WTC%20-%20The%20Future%20Shopper%20Report%202020.pdf.
power in certain business-to-business (B2B) online markets
through Amazon Business, its B2B marketplace.
1563
In response to the Committee’s requests for information, Amazon
claims that ‘‘estimates of total retail share are the most appro-
priate and relevant method of estimating’’ Amazon’s market
share.
1564
This approach is inconsistent with evidence gathered by
the Subcommittee, conventional antitrust analysis of relevant prod-
uct markets, and common sense. In a recent investigation, for ex-
ample, the FTC concluded that a ‘‘relevant market may be divided
by channel of sale, resulting in separate markets for brick-and-mor-
tar sales and online sales.’’
1565
Illustrating the extent of Amazon’s
overly broad approach to identifying the relevant market and its
top competitors, in response to the Committee’s request for ‘‘[a] list
of the Company’s top ten competitors,’’ Amazon identified 1,700
companies, including Eero (a company Amazon owns), a discount
surgical supply distributor, and a beef jerky company.
1566
Amazon also included single-category companies in response to
the Committee’s request for a list of Amazon’s top ten competitors.
Yet documents produced by Amazon suggest that even in its early
days it did not view such retailers as direct competitors. For in-
stance, a recap of an Amazon marketing presentation identified one
of its key points as: ‘‘No direct competitors, closest competitors
would be what you refer to as category driven, i.e. Best Buy,
Barnes and Noble . . . etc.’’
1567
Regardless of the precise boundaries of e-commerce or online
marketplaces, the sum of evidence that the Subcommittee exam-
ined demonstrates that Amazon functions as a gatekeeper for e-
commerce. Amazon is the most-visited website in the world for e-
commerce and shopping.
1568
In a submission to the Committee, an
e-commerce market participant said that ‘‘many of the 64% of
American households that have Prime memberships are effectively
locked into Amazon for their online shopping.’’
1569
Meanwhile, re-
cent market analysis suggests that over 60 percent of all online
product searches in the U.S. begin on Amazon.com.
1570
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00220 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
215
1571
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 190–191 (statement of Stacy F. Mitchell,
Co-Dir., Inst. for Local Self-Reliance).
1572
See, e.g., Submission from Top Shelf Brands, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 49 (Oct. 26,
2019) (‘‘98% of all of Top Shelf’s transaction[s] has taken place on Amazon’s platform.’’); see also
Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 30 (‘‘Regardless of the view on dominance over a par-
ticular defined market, it is clear that for thousands of smaller independent online sellers in
particular, Amazon’s marketplace is a strategically important gateway to consumers.’’).
1573
Competitors Hearing at 20 (statement of David Barnett, CEO & Founder, PopSockets
LLC).
1574
Submission from Source 11, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
At the Subcommittee’s hearing on innovation and entrepreneur-
ship, Stacy Mitchell, the Co-Director of the Institute for Local Self-
Reliance, described one independent retailer’s attempt to survive in
e-commerce independent of Amazon:
As its customers moved online, so too did the company. Gazelle Sports built a
robust e-commerce site. With scores of enthusiastic reviews on Google and Yelp,
the site came right up in online searches, yielding a brisk stream of customers
and sales.
But, in 2014, sales began to decline. The problem was that many people in
Michigan and across the country were no longer starting their online shopping
on a search engine, where they might find Gazelle Sports. Instead, they were
going straight to Amazon. By 2016, the share of online shoppers bypassing
search engines and beginning their product search on Amazon had grown to 55
percent. With sales flagging and staff reductions underway, the owner of Gazelle
Sports . . . made what seemed like a necessary decision: Gazelle Sports would join
Amazon Marketplace, becoming a third-party seller on the digital giant’s plat-
form. ‘‘If the customer is on Amazon, as a small business you have to say, ‘That
is where I have to go,’ ’’ he explained. ‘‘Otherwise, we are going to close our
doors.’’
1571
Interviews with sellers, as well as documents that the Sub-
committee reviewed, make clear that Amazon has monopoly power
over most third-party sellers and many of its suppliers.
1572
Numer-
ous sellers told the Subcommittee in interviews that they cannot
turn to alternative marketplaces, regardless of how much Amazon
may increase their costs of doing business or how badly they are
treated. David Barnett, the CEO and Founder of PopSockets, a
former third-party seller and current Amazon supplier, testified
about Amazon’s coercive tactics at one of the Subcommittee’s hear-
ings:
I suspect that Amazon is accustomed to behaving this way because most brands
cannot afford to leave Amazon. They evidently have no choice but to endure tac-
tics that would be rejected out of hand in any ordinary relationship whereby the
two parties enter into the relationship by preference rather than necessity.
1573
Sellers feel forced to be on Amazon because that is where the
buyers are.
1574
At the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Representa-
tive Lucy McBath (D–GA) noted that the evidence the Sub-
committee collected is at odds with how Amazon describes its rela-
tionship with third-party sellers. She asked Mr. Bezos:
[Y]ou referred to third party sellers today as ‘‘Amazon’s partners’’ and that your
success depends on their success. But, over the past year, we’ve heard a com-
pletely different story. As part of this investigation, we’ve interviewed many
small businesses, and they use the words like ‘‘bullying,’’ ‘‘fear,’’ and ‘‘panic’’ to
describe their relationship with Amazon .... You said that sellers have many
other attractive options to reach customers, but that’s not at all what we found
in our investigation .... If Amazon didn’t have monopoly power over these sell-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00221 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
216
1575
CEO Hearing at 114–15 (question of Rep. Lucy McBath (D–GA), Member, Subcomm. on
Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
1576
Id. at 115 (statement of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1577
Submission from Online Merchants Guild, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 4 (Oct. 23,
2019) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Members who sell across multiple platforms often report the
amount of revenue generated outside of Amazon including their own eCommerce site, is insig-
nificant, with over 90% of their sales being generated on the platform.’’); see also Submission
from Top Shelf Brands, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 60–61 (Oct. 26, 2019) (explaining that
it has ‘‘no viable alternatives’’ to Amazon, where 98 percent of its transactions have taken place
on Amazon’s platform, eBay accounts for one percent of its income, and Walmart accounts for
less than one percent).
1578
Selling Polices and Seller Code of Conduct, A
MAZON
S
ELLER
C
ENT
., https://
sellercentral.amazon.com/gp/help/external/G1801?language=enlUS&ref=efphlG1801lcont
l200386250 (last visited Sept. 28, 2020); see also Submission from Source 100, to H. Comm.
on the Judiciary (Sept. 26, 2020) (raising concerns that Amazon permits itself to contact cus-
tomers about negative reviews for Amazon-branded products, while third-party sellers are large-
ly barred from customer engagement).
1579
Submission from Online Merchants Guild, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 4 (Oct. 23,
2019) (on file with Comm.); see also Submission from Source 11, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
3 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with Comm.) (explaining that, ‘‘[w]henever an order is shipped through
[Fulfillment by Amazon], even if the purchase is made through another marketplace, it is likely
to arrive in an Amazon-branded box, creating confusion’’ for customers).
1580
Submission from Online Merchants Guild, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Oct. 23,
2019) (on file with Comm.).
1581
See, e.g., Phone Interview with Source 84 (Mar. 4, 2020).
ers, do you think they would choose to stay in a relationship that is character-
ized by bullying, fear, and panic?
1575
Mr. Bezos responded that ‘‘there are a lot of options’’ for sellers,
and that ‘‘[t]here are more and more every day.’’
1576
This claim is
inconsistent with the Subcommittee’s investigative record. In a
submission to the Committee, the Online Merchants Guild, a trade
association for small- and medium-sized online sellers, said that its
members who try to diversify sales across multiple platforms often
report that they are unable to generate many sales outside of Ama-
zon.
1577
An important limit on a seller’s ability to switch from selling on
Amazon to selling on its own site or a competing platform is that
Amazon generally forbids sellers from contacting their cus-
tomers.
1578
The packaging and even the order confirmation email
for third-party sales feature the Amazon brand prominently and do
not reference the seller. A typical Amazon customer is unaware of
the source of the sale.
1579
According to the Online Merchants
Guild, ‘‘Many Amazon sellers use websites such as Shopify to try
and establish their own eCommerce presence, but without the abil-
ity to market to their supposed core customer base, their Amazon
customers, it’s pretty futile.’’
1580
The Subcommittee heard from several market participants that
Amazon also has significant market power over suppliers. For ex-
ample, third-party sellers told the Subcommittee that Amazon fre-
quently ignores manufacturer policies that bind sellers.
1581
For ex-
ample, brand manufacturers may establish minimum advertised
pricing guidelines (MAP) to prevent online retailers from freeriding
off brick-and-mortar stores’ investments in product display or ex-
pertise—such as how to fit a running shoe. Amazon’s leverage over
suppliers gives it the ability to ‘‘break’’ minimum advertised pricing
rules and undercut competing sellers on price. In contrast, third-
party sellers must abide by the rules. As a former third-party seller
explained, ‘‘Given Amazon’s immense clout, we believe that sup-
pliers have no realistic threat to stop selling on Amazon in re-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00222 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
217
1582
Submission from Source 48, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 8 (Nov. 8, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1583
See, e.g., Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–
00151722 (Feb. 9, 2009) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘[P]lease audit that we are price matching . . .
any diapers.com pricing. If this puts us in the soup with P&G on their pampers map price, so
be it.’’); id. at AMAZON–HJC–00206714 (Mar. 8, 2018) (‘‘Why did Walmart break MAP and we
didn’t?’’).
1584
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00190108 (June 6, 2016) (on file with Comm.).
1585
Competitors Hearing at 20 (statement of David Barnett, CEO & Founder, PopSockets
LLC).
1586
Submission from Source 91, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Sept. 22, 2020) (on file with
Comm.).
1587
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00199845 (Oct.
23, 2013) (on file with Comm.).
1588
Id.
1589
See Submission from Source 11, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file
with Comm.) (‘‘Amazon has been quite frank about the reality that once consumers invest in
Prime, they do most of their online shopping on Amazon in order to gain value from the invest-
ment in shipping, whereas they might otherwise multisource.’’).
1590
Tonya Garcia, Amazon Prime Membership Exceeds 100 Million, M
ARKETWATCH
(Jan. 17,
2019), https://www.marketwatch.com/story/amazon-prime-membership-exceeds-100-million-
2019-01-17; see also Brian Olsavsky, Senior Vice President & Chief Fin. Officer, Amazon.com,
Continued
sponse to Amazon ‘breaking’ MAP.’’
1582
Amazon’s internal docu-
ments suggest that it does not fear any consequences for failing to
comply with most vendor policies.
1583
Another way that Amazon leverages its market power is to force
certain brand manufacturers that would prefer to be third-party
sellers into being wholesalers. A discussion among Amazon execu-
tives suggests that certain brands may only be allowed to have a
wholesale relationship with Amazon even if the brand would prefer
to be a third-party seller. In 2016, Sebastian Gunningham, then
senior vice president of Amazon Marketplace, commented on a list
of proposed seller tenets, ‘‘I would add that there are x,000 sup-
pliers around the world that do not get this choice . . . I am talking
about the apple, nikes and p&g, etc .... We don’t want to open that
door, relationship has to be reseller.’’
1584
Consistent with this
stance, Popsockets CEO and Founder David Barnett testified that
Amazon attempted to force him into maintaining a wholesale rela-
tionship with Amazon Retail despite his preference to be a third-
party seller or make sales on the marketplace through an author-
ized distributor.
1585
A former Amazon employee confirmed that it
was not uncommon for Amazon to use its brand standards policy
to shut down a brand’s third-party seller account and force brands
into an exclusive wholesaler relationship.
1586
Amazon also enjoys significant market power over online con-
sumers. Amazon uses Prime and its other membership programs to
lock consumers into the Amazon ecosystem. According to an inter-
nal analysis, Amazon was willing to pay a credit card company a
significant sum in 2013 for signing up new Prime members under
the assumption that each new member would contribute $527 to
Amazon’s gross merchandise sales and $46 of gross profit.
1587
Ama-
zon estimated that the deal had a five-year net present value of
$17 million, assuming that it delivered 100,000 paid Prime mem-
bers.
1588
Once Prime members pay the upfront annual membership fee,
they are likely to concentrate their online purchases with Ama-
zon.
1589
According to a recent survey, Prime members spend an av-
erage of $1,400 annually on Amazon, versus $600 for non-mem-
bers.
1590
As one market participant observed, ‘‘Prime members will
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00223 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
218
Inc., Q1 2020 Earnings Call (Apr. 30, 2020, 5:30 p.m.) (‘‘We see our Prime customers are shop-
ping more often and they have larger basket sizes.’’).
1591
Submission from Source 11, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1592
See J.P. M
ORGAN
, R
ETAIL VS
. A
MAZON
: L
IFE IN A
P
OST
COVID–19 W
ORLD
(2020), https://
markets.jpmorgan.com/research/email/-lbk68f4/Alp1kP9tQUPS29jlzWlbOg/GPS-3397412-0
(‘‘We believe there are no comparable unlimited free shipping offerings available at scale, with
Amazon’s large and growing infrastructure investments serving as a significant barrier to
entry.’’).
1593
Prime, A
MAZON
, https://www.amazon.com/b?ie=UTF8&node=15247183011 (last visited
Sept. 28, 2020) (‘‘Free One-Day Delivery .... Available coast-to-coast on more than 10 million
items with no minimum purchase.’’).
1594
Press Release, Marc Lore, President & CEO, Walmart eCommerce US, Free NextDay De-
livery Without a Membership Fee (May 14, 2019), https://corporate.walmart.com/newsroom/
2019/05/14/free-nextday-delivery-without-a-membership-fee; Walmart Help Center: NextDay De-
livery, W
ALMART
, https://www.walmart.com/help/article/nextday-delivery/fd3f1c5cf0ec4682
abca8c83f5f0e977 (last visited Sept. 28, 2020) (‘‘Currently, NextDay Delivery is only available
in select markets.’’).
1595
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00154659 (Nov.
23, 2010) (on file with Comm.).
continue to use Amazon and not switch to competing platforms, de-
spite higher prices and lower-quality items on Amazon compared to
other marketplaces, and despite recent increases in the price of a
Prime membership.’’
1591
Other retailers are unable to match Amazon on its ability to pro-
vide free and fast delivery for such a large volume and inventory
of products. Even Walmart, with its extensive national distribution
network, does not come close to matching Amazon on this meas-
ure.
1592
Amazon currently offers Prime members free, next-day de-
livery on over 10 million items anywhere in the continental United
States.
1593
Walmart, by contrast, has only about 200,000 products
eligible for two-day shipping in select markets.
1594
Amazon’s market power is durable and unlikely to erode in the
foreseeable future. There are several factors that make successful
entry or expansion by a challenger to Amazon unlikely. Barriers to
entry include: (1) network effects, which make it difficult for an-
other marketplace to achieve a comparable number of buyers and
sellers; (2) switching costs associated with consumers shopping out-
side of the Amazon ecosystem; and (3) the steep costs of building
a logistics network comparable in size and scope to Amazon’s mas-
sive international footprint in fulfillment and delivery. Amazon’s
internal documents recognize that entry into online commerce
‘‘require[s] significant incremental investments in brand develop-
ment, inventory, and marketing/customer acquisition.’’
1595
Further,
Amazon expanded its market power by avoiding taxes, extracting
state subsidies, and engaging in anticompetitive conduct—tactics
that have given the company an unfair advantage over actual and
potential competitors.
As the COVID–19 pandemic pushes more American shoppers on-
line, Amazon’s market power has grown. Evidence shows that
Amazon is willing to use its increased market power in e-commerce
during this crisis to exert pressure on suppliers and favor its own
first-party products over those sold by third-party sellers. Amazon
initially responded to the sudden surge in sales by refusing to ac-
cept or deliver non-essential supplies from its third-party sellers—
a stance that would seem reasonable except that Amazon continued
to ship its own non-essential products while restricting third-party
sellers’ ability to use alternative distribution channels to continue
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00224 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
219
1596
Ron Knox & Shaoul Sussman, How Amazon Used the Pandemic to Amass More Monopoly
Power, N
ATION
(June 26, 2020), https://www.thenation.com/article/politics/amazon-bezos-pan-
demic-monopoly/.
1597
Phone Interview with Nat’l Grocers Ass’n (May 28, 2020) (raising concerns that Amazon
and some Big Box retailers may have used their buyer power over suppliers during the pan-
demic to secure inventory at the expense of smaller businesses); Letter from Int’l Bhd. of Team-
sters, Commc’n Workers of Am., United Food & Commercial Workers Int’l Union & Change to
Win, to Comm’rs of the Fed. Trade Comm’n, 6 (July 23, 2020) (stating that, if seller reports are
true, ‘‘Amazon’s hold over sellers effectively took food from the shelves of neighborhood grocery
stores . . . and moved it to Amazon’s own warehouses, where it earned fees for Amazon’’); see
also Renee Dudley, The Amazon Lockdown: How an Unforgiving Algorithm Drives Suppliers to
Favor the E-Commerce Giant over Other Retailers, P
RO
P
UBLICA
(Apr. 26, 2020), https://
www.propublica.org/article/the-amazon-lockdown-how-an-unforgiving-algorithm-drives-sup-
pliers-to-favor-the-e-commerce-giant-over-other-retailers.
1598
Esther Fung & Sebastian Herrera, Amazon and Mall Operator Look at Turning Sears,
J.C. Penney Stores into Fulfillment Centers, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (Aug. 9, 2017), https://www.wsj.com/
articles/amazon-and-giant-mall-operator-look-at-turning-sears-j-c-penney-stores-into-fulfillment-
centers-11596992863.
1599
See infra Appendix.
1600
Infographic: Amazon’s Biggest Acquisitions, CB I
NSIGHTS
(June 19, 2019), https://
www.cbinsights.com/research/amazon-biggest-acquisitions-infographic/.
1601
Id.
1602
Id.
1603
Amazon Acquisitions, M
ICROACQUIRE
, https://acquiredby.co/amazon-acquisitions/ (last
visited Oct. 3, 2020).
selling through Prime.
1596
As for suppliers, the Subcommittee
heard concerns that the platform used its power as a large buyer
to pressure suppliers into prioritizing Amazon over other retail cus-
tomers such as independent grocers.
1597
Meanwhile, numerous re-
ports suggest that Amazon is in talks to convert real estate in va-
cated malls into additional Amazon distribution centers, further
highlighting how it will continue to amass further scale even as its
brick-and-mortar counterparts crater.
1598
(b) Merger Activity. Amazon’s acquisition strategy has primarily
focused on purchasing its competitors and companies that operate
in adjacent markets, providing access to additional valuable cus-
tomer data. This strategy has effectively protected and expanded
Amazon’s market power in e-commerce and helped Amazon extend
that power to other markets.
Over the past two decades, Amazon has acquired at least 100
companies.
1599
It has been particularly aggressive over the past
few years, making deals that are bigger and more ambitious rel-
ative to its historical approach.
1600
In 2017, the company made its
largest acquisition to date by purchasing Whole Foods for $13.7 bil-
lion.
1601
Amazon’s other large purchases include Ring, which it
bought for $1.2 billion in 2018; PillPack, which it bought for $1 bil-
lion in 2018; and Zappos, which it bought for $1.2 billion in
2009.
1602
Over the years, Amazon has acquired an assortment of
highly recognizable companies, including IMDB.com, which it
bought in 1998; Audible, which it bought in 2008; Goodreads,
which it bought in 2013; and Twitch, which it bought in 2014.
1603
Amazon’s acquisition strategy has led to fewer choices for con-
sumers in terms of differentiated online retail channels, as well as
reduced competitive pressure in terms of price and quality. Addi-
tionally, Amazon’s expansion into a diverse array of business
lines—from brick-and-mortar supermarkets to home security—has
reinforced its significant stockpile of consumer data. With more
data about online and offline consumer behavior, Amazon’s acquisi-
tions set in motion a self-reinforcing cycle, creating an ever-wid-
ening gap between the platform and its competitors. As one former
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00225 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
220
1604
Interview with Source 91 (May 8, 2020); see also Submission from Artist Rights Alliance,
to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (July 31, 2019) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘With respect to the music
world, at the heart of this problem lies a simple, economic truth—companies like . . . Amazon
are not music businesses. They are advertising platforms and data machines. As our then-Presi-
dent, Melvin Gibbs, told the New York Times back in 2017, ‘None of these companies that are
supposedly in the music business are actually in the music business. They are in the data-aggre-
gation business. They’re in the ad-selling business. The value of music means nothing to
them.’ ’’).
1605
See Stigler Report at 75 n.152 (‘‘The number of potential competitors purchased by the
tech giants is large. For example, Amazon has purchased Zappos, Fabric, CDNow, Quorus, Audi-
ble, Goodreads, and Quidsi.’’); T
IM
W
U
, T
HE
C
URSE OF
B
IGNESS
: A
NTITRUST IN THE
N
EW
G
ILDED
A
GE
124 (2018) (‘‘Amazon acquired would-be competitors like Zappos, Diapers.com, and
Soap.com.’’).
1606
Amazon Closes Zappos Deal, Ends Up Paying $1.2 Billion, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Nov. 2, 2009),
https://techcrunch.com/2009/11/02/amazon-closes-zappos-deal-ends-up-paying-1-2-billion/;
Confirmed: Amazon Spends $545 Million on Diapers.com Parent Quidsi, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Nov. 8,
2010), https://techcrunch.com/2010/11/08/confirmed-amazon-spends-545-million-on-diapers-
com-parent-quidsi/.
1607
Eric Engleman, Amazon and Zappos, Six Months Later: How They’re Fitting Together,
P
UGET
S
OUND
B
US
. J. (May 21, 2010), https://www.bizjournals.com/seattle/blog/techflash/
2010/05/amazonlandlzapposlhow ltheyrelfittingltogether.html.
1608
Bill Taylor, Amazon and Zappos: A Savvy Deal, H
ARV
. B
US
. R
EV
. (July 23, 2009), https://
hbr.org/2009/07/a-savvy-deal-from-amazon-to-za.
1609
Alistair Barr, Amazon to Close Fashion Website Endless.com, R
EUTERS
: I
NDUS
., M
ATE
-
RIALS &
U
TILS
. (Sept. 18, 2012), https://www.reuters.com/article/amazon-endless/amazon-to-
close-fashion-website-endless-com-idUSL1E8KINKD20120918 (quoting an Amazon spokesman
who stated that Amazon shut down Endless.com as an independent site in 2012 and incor-
porated it into Amazon’s main website, Amazon.com, ‘‘in order to focus on the Amazon Fashion
experience’’).
1610
Bill Taylor, Amazon and Zappos: A Savvy Deal, H
ARV
. B
US
. R
EV
. (July 23, 2009), https://
hbr.org/2009/07/a-savvy-deal-from-amazon-to-za.
1611
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00170649
(Sept. 23, 2008) (on file with Comm.).
1612
Claire Cain Miller, Amazon Has a Reported Deal to Buy Parent of Diapers.com, N.Y.
T
IMES
(Nov. 7, 2010), https://www.nytimes.com/2010/11/08/technology/08amazon.html.
Amazon employee told the Subcommittee, ‘‘Amazon is first and
foremost a data company[;] they just happen to use it to sell
stuff.’’
1604
Over its history, Amazon has acquired a number of its rivals.
1605
A decade ago, Amazon acquired two of its direct competitors:
Zappos and Quidsi.
1606
Documents reviewed by the Subcommittee
show that Amazon viewed both online retailers as competitive
threats prior to acquiring them.
Amazon’s 2009 acquisition of Zappos, an online shoe retailer,
marked the company’s first $1 billion-plus purchase.
1607
Acquiring
Zappos provided Amazon with two important advantages. First, it
enabled Amazon to add significant selection to its category of shoes
and other fashion-related items at a time when expanding its selec-
tion was critical to the company’s success.
1608
The added selection
included access to ‘‘hold-out’’ brands, which had previously refused
to sell on Amazon.com or Amazon’s other online retail store End-
less.com.
1609
Second, Zappos’s unique approach to customer serv-
ice, marked by ‘‘a deeply felt connection with customers,’’ added an
emotional and psychological element to Amazon’s relationship with
consumers.
1610
An Amazon internal planning document from 2008
referred to Zappos as one of Endless’s ‘‘primary competitors,’’ and
noted that ‘‘Zappos offers the largest selection of brands and styles
and carries all of our top holdouts including Nike, Merrell, Keen,
Cole Haan and Michael Kors.’’
1611
About a year later, Amazon acquired Quidsi, the parent company
of Diapers.com and Soap.com, for about $540 million.
1612
Prior to
buying it, Amazon identified Diapers.com as its ‘‘largest and fastest
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00226 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
221
1613
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00142833 (May
12, 2009) (on file with Comm.).
1614
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00151722 (Feb. 9, 2009).
1615
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00151722 to –00151724.
1616
CEO Hearing at 109 (question of Rep. Mary Gay Scanlon (D–PA), Vice Chair, H. Comm.
on the Judiciary).
1617
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00057007 (Apr.
5. 2010) (on file with Comm.).
1618
CEO Hearing at 110 (question of Rep. Mary Gay Scanlon (D–PA), Vice Chair, H. Comm.
on the Judiciary).
1619
See, e.g., Jason Del Rey, Why Amazon’s Explanation for Shutting Down Diapers.com and
Quidsi Stunned Employees, V
OX
: R
ECODE
(Apr. 2, 2017), https://www.vox.com/2017/4/2/
15153844/amazon-quidsi-shutdown-explanation-profits.
1620
See, e.g., Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–
00034097 (Nov. 8, 2010) (on file with Comm.) (email from Diapers.com founder Vinit Bharara
forwarding a customer testimonial in the form of a poem titled ‘‘An Ode to Diapers.com,’’ begin-
ning, ‘‘Oh how do I love thee, my Diapers.com?’’ and ending with ‘‘Don’t ever leave me, my Dia-
pers.com’’).
1621
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00154656 (noting that, ‘‘[a]lthough Quidsi is still primarily an on-
line baby care specialty retailer, it has recently begun selling new items such as household goods
and personal-care products with the launch of Soap.com .... In the future, management intends
to launch additional vertical shopping categories such as beauty, toys and pets.’’); id. at AMA-
ZON–HJC–00132026 (June 8, 2010) (email from Doug Herrington, Vice President of
Consumables, to Jeff Bezos stating, ‘‘While we find no evidence that alice.com has gotten trac-
tion with vendors or customers, and can’t see an economic model for them that pencils out,
soap.com feels like a more credible threat’’).
1622
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00172932 (June 22, 2017) (showing analysis that, for Amazon
Fresh customers who don’t do 100 percent shopping on Amazon Fresh, Whole Foods is consist-
ently among the top 5 stand-alone national chains where Amazon Fresh customers do their gro-
cery shopping).
1623
Lauren Hirsch, A Year After Amazon Announced Its Acquisition of Whole Foods, Here’s
Where We Stand, CNBC (June 15, 2018), https://www.cnbc.com/2018/06/15/a-year-after-
amazon-announced-whole-foods-deal-heres-where-we-stand.html.
growing competitor in the on-line diaper and baby care space,’’
1613
and its ‘‘#1 short term competitor.’’
1614
Amazon’s internal docu-
ments said that Diapers.com ‘‘keep[s] the pressure on pricing on
us’’ and provided extremely high customer service levels, which—
prior to the merger—had forced Amazon to up its game.
1615
Ama-
zon executives took swift and predatory action in response to this
competitive threat. As Representative Mary Gay Scanlon (D–PA)
summarized at the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Amazon’s inter-
nal documents ‘‘show that Amazon employees began strategizing
about ways to weaken this company, and, in 2010, Amazon hatched
a plot to go after Diapers.com and take it out.’’
1616
Specifically,
Amazon’s documents show that the firm entered into an aggressive
price war, in which Amazon was willing to bleed over $200 million
in losses on diapers in one month.
1617
Addressing Mr. Bezos, Rep-
resentative Scanlon added, ‘‘Your own documents make clear that
the price war against Diapers.com worked, and within a few
months it was struggling, and so then Amazon bought it.’’
1618
In 2017, Amazon shut down Diapers.com, citing profitability
issues, though some industry experts questioned the legitimacy of
this rationale.
1619
In shutting down the company, Amazon elimi-
nated a differentiated online retailer that consumers loved
1620
—re-
ducing the number of online options for consumers in the diaper
and baby care markets. Further, it eliminated a potential compet-
itor in other verticals such as household goods, toys, and pets.
1621
More recently, Amazon acquired Whole Foods, a strategic move
to acquire both a competitor
1622
and a new source of customer
data.
1623
Amazon purchased Whole Foods at around $13.7 billion,
more than 10 times the cost of its second-most expensive acquisi-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00227 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
222
1624
Infographic: Amazon’s Biggest Acquisition, CB I
NSIGHTS
(June 19, 2019), https://
www.cbinsights.com/research/amazon-biggest-acquisitions-infographic/.
1625
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00172090
(June 22, 2017) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘[A] survey said about 45% of [Whole Foods Market] cus-
tomers are Prime; and about 20% of Prime members shop at [Whole Foods Market].’’); id. at
AMAZON–HJC–00173652 (June 23, 2017) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Based on our survey results,
we estimate that approximately 46% of Prime members have shopped at a [Whole Foods] store
in the last four weeks.’’).
1626
Lauren Hirsch, A Year After Amazon Announced Its Acquisition of Whole Foods, Here’s
Where We Stand, CNBC (June 15, 2018), https://www.cnbc.com/2018/06/15/a-year-after-
amazon-announced-whole-foods-deal-heres-where-we-stand.html.
1627
Letter from Hon. David N. Cicilline, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Regulatory Reform,
Commercial and Antitrust Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, to Hon. Bob Goodlatte, Chair,
H. Comm. on the Judiciary, & Hon. Tom Marino, Chair, Subcomm. on Regulatory Reform, Com-
mercial and Antitrust Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (July 13, 2017), https://
cicilline.house.gov/sites/cicilline.house.gov/files/images/
AmazonlWholel FoodslAcquistion.pdf.
1628
See, e.g., Interview with Source 153 (May 11, 2020); Interview with Nat’l Grocers Ass’n
(May 28, 2020).
1629
Taylor Lyles, Amazon Go’s Cashierless Tech May Come to Whole Foods As Soon As Next
Year, V
ERGE
(Aug. 24, 2020), https://www.theverge.com/2020/8/24/21399607/amazon-cashier
less-go-technology-whole-foods-2021-rumor.
1630
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00170877 (Oct.
11, 2017) (on file with Comm.).
1631
Jeffrey Dastin, Amazon Quietly Dropped $90 Million on a Camera Startup Last Year to
Acquire Its Unique Chip Technology, B
US
. I
NSIDER
(Feb. 12, 2018), https://www.business
insider.com/amazon-blink-camera-maker-acquisition-2018-2.
1632
Dennis Green, Amazon’s $1 Billion Acquisition of the Door Camera Startup Ring Is the
Company Doing What It Does Best—and It Should Terrify Every Other Retailer, B
US
. I
NSIDER
(Mar. 3, 2018), https://www.businessinsider.com/why-amazon-acquired-ring-2018-3.
tion.
1624
In addition to bolstering its position in the grocery mar-
ket, Amazon’s purchase of Whole Foods expanded its touchpoints
with Prime members and gave it access to a unique set of customer
information.
1625
Specifically, the deal enabled Amazon to monitor
and compile data on how the same person shops both online and
in person, data that is particularly useful for targeted advertising
and promotional campaigns.
1626
While the deal was under review by the FTC, then-Ranking
Member Cicilline raised concerns that ‘‘the proposed acquisition
w[ould] result in additional consolidation in the retail sector, erode
American jobs through increased automation, and threaten local
communities through diminished economic opportunity for hard-
working Americans.’’
1627
Amazon’s acquisition of Whole Foods has
added to the platform’s market power in retail by increasing its
buyer power over suppliers,
1628
adding to the platform’s capabili-
ties in online grocery, and expanding the company’s brick-and-mor-
tar retail footprint. In addition, it appears that concerns about di-
minished economic opportunities may have been well-founded as
Amazon reportedly plans to implement cashier-less technology
across all of its Whole Foods stores.
1629
In recent years, Amazon has also made several significant acqui-
sitions of home security companies, further expanding its reach and
visibility into Americans’ homes. An Amazon executive described
the company’s in-home strategy by noting, ‘‘Two senses matter—
eyes and ears.’’
1630
In 2017, Amazon paid $90 million to acquire
Blink, a home security camera company whose technology and en-
ergy-efficient chips could be used by Amazon in its Echo speakers
and other products.
1631
In 2018, Amazon spent $1.2 billion to ac-
quire Ring, a home-security system spanning cameras, doorbells,
and floodlights.
1632
Ring’s ‘‘eyes and ears’’ add significant value to
Amazon’s smart home, allowing customers to virtually interact
with Amazon delivery personnel and instruct them on where to
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00228 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
223
1633
Id.
1634
Leena Rao, Amazon Acquires Robot-Coordinated Order Fulfillment Company Kiva Sys-
tems for $775 Million in Cash, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Mar. 19, 2012), https://techcrunch.com/2012/03/
19/amazon-acquires-online-fulfillment-company-kiva-systems-for-775-million-in-cash/.
1635
Christina Farr, The Inside Story of Why Amazon Bought PillPack in Its Effort to Crack
the $500 Billion Prescription Market, CNBC (May 13, 2019), https://www.cnbc.com/2019/05/
10/why-amazon-bought-pillpack-for-753-million-and-what-happens-next.html.
1636
Evelyn M. Rusli, Amazon.com to Acquire Manufacturer of Robotics, N.Y. T
IMES
:
D
EALBOOK
(Mar. 19, 2012), https://dealbook.nytimes.com/2012/03/19/amazon-com-buys-kiva-
systems-for-775-million/.
1637
Mick Mountz, Kiva the Disrupter, H
ARV
. B
US
. R
EV
. (Dec. 2012), https://hbr.org/2012/
12/kiva-the-disrupter.
1638
Adam Putz, M&A Flashback: Amazon Announces $775 M Kiva Systems Acquisition,
P
ITCHBOOK
(Mar. 19, 2018), https://pitchbook.com/news/articles/ma-flashback-amazon-
announces-775m-kiva-systems-acquisition.
1639
Id.
1640
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00172665 (May
23, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
drop off Amazon packages.
1633
Amazon’s significant investments in
the Internet of Things ecosystem and its strategy, centered on
Amazon’s voice assistant, Alexa, are discussed in other parts of this
Report.
Other notable acquisitions include Kiva Systems in 2012, which
provided Amazon with a robotics company that accelerated its abil-
ity to streamline picking, packing, and shipping e-commerce prod-
ucts;
1634
and PillPack in 2018, which equips Amazon with an on-
line pharmacy and marks its entry into the pharmaceutical mar-
ket.
1635
Amazon’s acquisition of Kiva gave it power over an important
input for competitors. When Amazon bought the robotics company,
Kiva was supplying technology to a large number of retailers, in-
cluding Gap, Staples, and Walgreens.
1636
Many of these customers
had invested a sunk cost of $4 million to $6 million per warehouse
in order to make use of Kiva’s technologies.
1637
Kiva had promised
to keep shipping its technology to non-Amazon customers—regard-
less of whether they competed with Amazon—but in 2015, Amazon
rebranded the company as Amazon Robotics and announced it
would stop servicing other firms.
1638
Amazon stated that retailers
seeking to use Kiva’s robots would need to use Amazon Services to
fulfill orders with Amazon’s technology in Amazon’s ware-
houses.
1639
Documents the Subcommittee reviewed relating to the PillPack
deal, meanwhile, give insight into how Amazon views some acquisi-
tions as opportunities to collect additional customer data and to
cross-sell across its different business lines. One Amazon executive
summarized a potential upside of the PillPack deal, asking, ‘‘Is
there a cross-selling opportunity with amazon.com based on known
maladies from prescriptions? Or is this prohibited by privacy law?
My understanding is there is a number of different ways we could
cross-sell customers in both directions (Rx<>non-Rx).’’
1640
Though
it is unclear whether, and the extent to which, Amazon imple-
mented this strategy, the exchange reveals how Amazon assesses
potential acquisitions and the cross-business opportunities they
create, suggesting that the firm views its vast operations in a high-
ly integrated manner.
The FTC investigated several of these transactions, including
Amazon’s acquisition of Quidsi, the parent company of Dia-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00229 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
224
1641
Letter from April Tabor, Acting Sec’y, Fed. Trade Comm’n, to Thomas Barnett, Covington
& Burling LLP (Aug. 22, 2012).
1642
Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm’n, Statement of Federal Trade Commission’s Acting Di-
rector of the Bureau of Competition on the Agency’s Review of Amazon.com, Inc.’s Acquisition
of Whole Foods Market Inc. (Aug. 23, 2017), https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/press-releases/
2017/08/statement-federal-trade-commissions-acting-director-bureau.
1643
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 39 (statement of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen.
Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1644
See, e.g., CEO Hearing at 323 (response to Questions for the Record of Jeff Bezos, CEO,
Amazon.com, Inc.) (‘‘Amazon makes significant investments to support Amazon’s selling part-
ners.’’); id. at 41 (‘‘Amazon recognizes that third-party sellers are our customers too, and their
trust is critical to Amazon’s success.’’).
1645
Submission from Online Merchants Guild, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Oct. 29,
2019) (on file with Comm.).
1646
See, e.g., Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–
00206715 (Mar. 8, 2016) (on file with Comm.) (describing changes to manual Pricing Rules when
Amazon offer is competing with ‘‘internal 3P competitor’’ offers); id. at AMAZON–HJC–
00038917 (Sept. 2009) (describing a proposal on ‘‘how to treat FBA sellers differently from other
Buy Box (BB) eligible 3P sellers when we’re matching internal competitors for non-media cat-
egories’’); id. at AMAZON–HJC–00171079 (defining Amazon’s ‘‘Standard Price Matching Policy’’
and conditions when ‘‘Internal competitors (3P merchants) are matched on box price’’).
pers.com,
1641
and Whole Foods.
1642
The agency declined, however,
to challenge any of them as a violation of antitrust law, despite: (1)
strong evidence, in some cases, of direct head-to-head competition
on price and quality between the merging firms; and (2) evidence
that many of these mergers would enable Amazon to expand or en-
trench its market power, particularly in e-commerce. For most, if
not all, of the acquisitions discussed in this Report, the FTC had
advance notice of the deals but did not attempt to block any of
them.
In addition to eliminating competitive threats, Amazon’s acquisi-
tion strategy has expanded and protected the company’s domi-
nance. The company’s significant expansion into new markets,
paired with Amazon’s wealth of data from its retail business, has
fueled the platform’s increasing market power. Amazon Associate
General Counsel Nate Sutton testified at the Subcommittee’s hear-
ing last July that ‘‘Amazon is proud to be a company of builders
and we have built our company from within, not through acquisi-
tions.’’
1643
But the evidence examined during the investigation
demonstrates that Amazon’s acquisitions—including acquisitions of
its direct competitors—have been key to Amazon’s attainment,
maintenance, and expansion of market power.
(c) Conduct
(i) Treatment of Third-Party Sellers
(1) Bullying. While Amazon has referred to third-party sellers on
its Marketplace as ‘‘partners’’ and ‘‘customers,’’
1644
numerous
small- and medium-sized businesses told the Subcommittee that
Amazon routinely bullies and mistreats them. The Online Mer-
chants Guild, a trade association representing the interests of sell-
ers engaged in online commerce, stated that they ‘‘have seen Ama-
zon use their position of strength to take advantage of sellers.’’
1645
Underlying Amazon’s public-facing rhetoric is the reality that it
views many of the sellers on its platform as competitors. In its in-
ternal documents, Amazon refers to third-party sellers as ‘‘internal
competitors.’’
1646
At the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Sub-
committee Chair Cicilline asked Mr. Jeff Bezos about Amazon’s ap-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00230 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
225
1647
CEO Hearing at 115 (question of Rep. David N. Cicilline (D–RI), Chair, Subcomm. on
Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
1648
Id. (statement of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon, Inc.).
1649
Competitors Hearing at 22 (statement of David Barnett, CEO & Founder, PopSockets
LLC).
1650
Id. at 20.
1651
Id.
1652
Id. at 17.
1653
Id. at 20–21.
1654
Id. at 4.
1655
Interview with Source 148 (Aug. 26, 2020).
1656
Id.
1657
Id.
1658
Submission from Source 17, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 13 (Nov. 14, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
parent doublespeak.
1647
In response, Mr. Bezos conceded, ‘‘[I]t
wouldn’t surprise me. In some ways, we are competing.’’
1648
Over the course of the investigation, the Subcommittee heard
from numerous sellers who described abusive tactics or mistreat-
ment by Amazon in a variety of circumstances. For example, at the
Subcommittee’s fifth hearing, CEO and Founder of PopSockets
David Barnett testified about Amazon’s bullying tactics, which he
said were enabled by ‘‘the asymmetry in power between Amazon
and its partners.’’
1649
He stated that after the two companies de-
cided on a minimum price at which Amazon would sell PopSockets,
Amazon sold the products for a lower price and then demanded
that PopSockets pay for the lost margin.
1650
As a result,
PopSockets decided to end its relationship with Amazon Retail.
1651
When PopSockets communicated this intent to Amazon, its re-
sponse was, ‘‘No, you are not leaving the relationship.’’
1652
PopSockets did sever its relationship with Amazon Retail for a pe-
riod of time, but reestablished it about a year later.
1653
Mr. Barnett
estimates that, in 2019, his company incurred losses of $10 million
in revenue from when he stopped selling to Amazon Retail and
Amazon blocked one of his authorized distributors from selling on
the marketplace.
1654
The Subcommittee learned about numerous other instances of
Amazon employing strong-arm tactics in negotiations. A company
that conducts business with multiple divisions of Amazon described
how the platform leveraged its dominance in e-commerce to force
acceptance of certain terms and conditions during negotiations over
a different part of its business.
1655
According to this company,
Amazon knows the power they have as a retailer. In the midst of
negotiations, the platform repeatedly referenced its power to
destock the company’s products on Amazon.com as a ‘‘bargaining
chip to force terms’’ unrelated to retail distribution on the com-
pany.
1656
The company added, ‘‘Amazon know[s] they have a lot of
power [in retail e-commerce] and they are not afraid to use it to
get terms they want in other markets.’’
1657
Book publishers described a similar asymmetric power dynamic
with Amazon. According to one publisher, ‘‘Amazon has used retal-
iation . . . to coerce publishers to accept contractual terms that im-
pose substantial penalties for promoting competition’’ with Ama-
zon’s rivals.
1658
The publisher added that the platform’s retaliatory
conduct shows ‘‘Amazon’s ability and willingness to leverage its
market power to prevent publishers from working effectively with
rival e-book retailers and, thereby, maintain and enhance its domi-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00231 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
226
1659
Id. at 3 (Sept. 22, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
1660
See, e.g., David Streitfeld, Amazon Pulls Thousands of E-Books in Dispute, N.Y T
IMES
:
B
ITS
(Feb. 22, 2012), https://bits.blogs.nytimes.com/2012/02/22/amazon-pulls-thousands-of-e-
books-in-dispute/?hpw.
1661
See, e.g., Polly Mosendz, Amazon Blocks Pre-orders of Hachette Books, A
TLANTIC
(May 23,
2014), https://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2014/05/amazon-blacklists-hachette-
books/371545/.
1662
See, e.g., David Streitfeld, Writers Feel an Amazon-Hachette Spat, N.Y. T
IMES
(May 9,
2014), https://www.nytimes.com/2014/05/10/technology/writers-feel-an-amazon-hachette-spat
.html.
1663
Id.
1664
See Interview with Source 155 (Sept. 29, 2020); Submission from Source 17, to H. Comm.
on the Judiciary, 13–18 (Nov. 14, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
1665
Interview with Ass’n of Am. Publishers, Authors Guild & Am. Booksellers Ass’n (Aug.
26, 2020).
1666
Competitors Hearing at 17 (statement of David Barnett, CEO & Founder, PopSockets
LLC).
1667
Class Action Complaint at 20, Frame-Wilson v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. 20–cv–00424 (W.D.
Wash. Mar. 9, 2020).
1668
Interview with Source 150 (July 11, 2020).
1669
Interview with Source 151 (July 2, 2020).
1670
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 196 (statement of Stacy F. Mitchell, Co-
Dir., Inst. for Local Self-Reliance).
nance in e-book distribution.’’
1659
Amazon’s retaliatory tactics
against publishers include removing the ‘‘buy’’ button, which blocks
a customer’s ability to purchase a publisher’s current titles;
1660
and removing the ‘‘pre-order’’ button, which eliminates the ability
for a consumer to pre-order a publisher’s forthcoming titles.
1661
An-
other form of retaliation that Amazon reportedly engaged in was
showing publishers’ titles as out of stock or with delayed shipping
times.
1662
According to credible reports, Amazon used these tactics
in its public battle with Hachette Book Group in 2014 over e-book
pricing,
1663
and it has used them or threatened to use them in
more recent negotiations.
1664
Publishers, authors, and booksellers
have ‘‘significant fear’’ because of Amazon’s dominance.
1665
Amazon can treat sellers in this manner because it knows that
sellers have no other realistic alternatives to the platform. As Mr.
Barnett noted in his testimony:
When there is bullying by an extremely successful company with all these part-
ners that continue to do business with it, one has to ask how is it that such a
successful business maintains partnerships with so many companies while bul-
lying them. It is because of the power asymmetry . . . that companies tolerate
this.
1666
A recent complaint filed against Amazon described the situation
as follows: ‘‘From the third-party retailers’ perspective, Amazon
Marketplace is like Hotel California, a lovely place to start or ex-
pand an online retail business, but check out from Amazon Market-
place and you can quickly find your business in bankruptcy.’’
1667
Additional comments from sellers that the Subcommittee inter-
viewed include, ‘‘We’re stuck. We don’t have a choice but to sell
through Amazon,’’
1668
and, referring to Amazon, ‘‘They’ve never
been a great partner, but you have to work with them.’’
1669
As Stacy Mitchell, Co-Director of the Institute for Local Self-Reli-
ance, noted during the Subcommittee’s hearing on Innovation and
Entrepreneurship, ‘‘Among the most egregious examples of Ama-
zon’s arbitrary treatment of sellers are its abrupt suspensions of
their accounts, frequently made without explanation.’’
1670
Once
Amazon suspends a seller’s account or delists its products, the
business is left with largely ineffective remedies as they watch
their sales disappear. Sellers shared with the Subcommittee that
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00232 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
227
1671
Interview with Source 125 (Jan. 9, 2020); see also Submission from Joel Hellmann, to
H. Comm. on the Judiciary (July 31, 2019) (on file with Comm.) (responding to an automated
message, ‘‘If you were a person and not a robot you would have read that I already tried this
and it failed’’).
1672
Interview with Source 149 (July 22, 2020).
1673
Id.
1674
Id.
1675
Interview with Source 125 (July 7, 2020).
1676
Id.
1677
Id.
1678
CEO Hearing at 113 (statement of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1679
See, e.g., iNOVATECHlMEDICAL, Inventory Being Held Hostage by Amazon for 3
Months, A
MAZON
S
ERVS
. S
ELLER
F
ORUMS
(Apr. 8, 2020, 10:30 p.m.), https://sellercentral
.amazon.com/forums/t/inventory-being-held-hostage-by-amazon-for-3-months/607892.
1680
See Josh Dzieza, Prime and Punishment: Dirty Dealing in the $175 Billion Amazon Mar-
ketplace, V
ERGE
(Dec. 19, 2018), https://www.theverge.com/2018/12/19/18140799/amazon-
marketplace-scams-seller-court-appeal-reinstatement (‘‘Emailing the richest man in the world is
actually the standard method of escalating an Amazon seller appeal. It’s called a Jeff Bomb,
or . . . a Jeff Letter.’’); Interview with Chris McCabe, Founder, ecommerceChris LLC (Dec. 30,
2019) (‘‘Out of desperation, some sellers try to email Jeff Bezos directly.’’); Submission from
Source 125, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Jan. 27, 2020) (on file with Comm.); Submission from
Source 150, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Aug. 16, 2017) (on file with Comm.).
communications to Amazon’s Seller Support Central generally
prompt automated, unhelpful responses, which may be entirely un-
related to the specific case, question, or concern raised by the sell-
er.
1671
The founder of an infant product sold on Amazon told the Sub-
committee that, after her products were mistakenly delisted, ‘‘[i]t
would take weeks of repeated calls—at least 10 or 15 contacts with
Seller Support—before somebody inside would determine that it
was a mistake and error,’’ and take action to fix the prob-
lem.
1672
She stated that this happened at least six times, and that,
in each instance, her listings would be down for two to three weeks
at a time.
1673
Describing how Amazon’s mistakes can threaten a
new business’s survival, this small-business owner said:
When you’re a new company and Amazon suddenly delists you, it creates fear
in the customer. ‘‘Where did it go? Is there something wrong with the product?
What happened?’’ If a customer searched and it’s no longer there, they’re un-
likely to ever come back and buy it .... You’ve probably lost that customer for
good.
1674
In another example, a third-party bookseller told the Sub-
committee that Amazon delisted 99 percent of his business’s inven-
tory in September 2019.
1675
The bookseller requested that Amazon
return its products, which were stored in Amazon’s warehouses.
1676
As of July 2020, Amazon had only returned a small fraction of the
bookseller’s inventory and continued to charge him storage fees.
1677
Amazon blocked the bookseller both from selling its products on its
marketplace and from retrieving its inventory, precluding the seller
from trying to recover some of his losses by making sales through
another, albeit lesser, channel. At the Subcommittee’s sixth hear-
ing, Representative Lucy McBath (D–GA) presented the book-
seller’s story to Mr. Bezos, who responded that this treatment is
‘‘not the systematic approach that [Amazon] take[s].’’
1678
However,
evidence the Subcommittee collected through extensive seller inter-
views shows that Amazon’s poor treatment of sellers is far from an
isolated incident—a fact supported both by public posts on Ama-
zon’s Seller Central forum,
1679
as well as pleas for help routinely
sent directly to Mr. Bezos.
1680
Because of the severe financial repercussions associated with
suspension or delisting, many Amazon third-party sellers live in
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00233 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
228
1681
See, e.g., Submission from Source 125, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (July 17, 2020) (on
file with Comm.) (‘‘My pregnant wife had to visit the ER due to increased anxiety and fear for
the future .... Due to Amazon’s stature, influence, and bullying nature, we are afraid of retalia-
tion.’’); Interview with Source 154 (July 2, 2019) (‘‘[Amazon] know[s] that small sellers have no
power and no ability to avoid them’’ because ‘‘they are the powerhouse giant in the transaction
and they could crush us.’’). See also Submission from Nat’l Ass’n of Wholesaler-Distributors, to
H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (July 22, 2020) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Small businesses that de-
pend upon Amazon for access to their markets, including many of our members, fear retribution
by Amazon if they speak up.’’).
1682
Josh Dzieza, Prime and Punishment: Dirty Dealing in the $175 Billion Amazon Market-
place, V
ERGE
(Dec. 19, 2018), https://www.theverge.com/2018/12/19/18140799/amazon-
marketplace-scams-seller-court-appeal-reinstatement.
1683
Interview with Source 152 (Sept. 18, 2020).
1684
Id.
1685
See, e.g., Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–
00227277 (on file with Comm.) (‘‘The implementation of Hands Off the Wheel in [Site Merchan-
dising] will mean that through automation . . . there is less work for humans .... Project Tiger
combines all Hands off the Wheel (HOTW) programs and Amazon spans of control guidelines.’’);
id. at AMAZON–HJC–00227278 (Apr. 27, 2017) (‘‘We are pursuing three tracks to drive Produc-
tivity savings: (1) FCF initiatives; (2) HOTW; and (3) Defect Reduction & Catalog Improve-
ment.’’).
1686
Interview with Source 149 (July 22, 2020). See also Submission from Source 100, to H.
Comm. on the Judiciary (identifying one concern with Amazon’s treatment of sellers as, ‘‘Pay
or Die—Forcing sellers to pay for their support services to correct Amazon’s wrong doings’’).
1687
Josh Dzieza, Prime and Punishment: Dirty Dealing in the $175 Billion Amazon Market-
place, V
ERGE
(Dec. 19, 2018), https://www.theverge.com/2018/12/19/18140799/amazon-
marketplace-scams-seller-court-appeal-reinstatement (‘‘Emailing the richest man in the world is
actually the standard method of escalating an Amazon seller appeal. It’s called a Jeff Bomb,
Continued
fear of the company.
1681
For sellers, Amazon functions as a ‘‘quasi-
state,’’ and many ‘‘[s]ellers are more worried about a case being
opened on Amazon than in actual court.’’
1682
This is because Ama-
zon’s internal dispute resolution system is characterized by uncer-
tainty, unresponsiveness, and opaque decision-making processes.
Additionally, the sellers interviewed by the Subcommittee gen-
erally indicated that Amazon’s customer service and treatment to-
wards them have declined significantly in recent years. One busi-
ness owner, who has been selling on Amazon for over a decade, told
the Subcommittee that, in the past, a seller could get meaningful
assistance by talking to an Amazon representative over the
phone.
1683
He said, ‘‘I used to think that Amazon was a partner,’’
but, now, ‘‘I don’t think they care about the third party seller ....
They treat us as a commodity.’’
1684
Internal Amazon documents
suggest that the company’s hyper-focus on a cost-cutting strategy
to adopt automated processes for nearly everything—which Ama-
zon refers to as ‘‘HOTW’’ or ‘‘Hands off the wheel’’
1685
—combined
with the platform’s monopoly power over sellers may be to blame
for Amazon’s atrocious levels of customer service for sellers.
Amazon has recently monetized the degradation of its seller serv-
ices, rolling out a program where sellers can pay an extra fee for
a dedicated account representative. Sellers are supposed to pay for
representatives to help them solve the very problems that Amazon
created in the first place. Many sellers say, however, that even
with paid Amazon account managers they are often unable to get
their issues resolved. One seller told the Subcommittee, ‘‘It [i]s a
problem that an algorithm can make a decision that just shuts off
my income stream and there’s nothing I can do to get it back ....
The only thing I can do to get it back is pay $6,000 a month for
a dedicated rep and even then, it doesn’t always work.’’
1686
The last resort for sellers facing these circumstances is the ‘‘Jeff
Bomb,’’ or ‘‘Jeff Letter,’’ in which a seller sends an email to Mr.
Bezos to plead their case.
1687
As the Online Merchants Guild ex-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00234 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
229
or . . . a Jeff Letter.’’). See also Interview with Chris McCabe, Founder, ecommerceChris LLC
(Dec. 30, 2019) (‘‘Out of desperation, some sellers try to email Jeff Bezos directly.’’); Submission
from Source 125, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Jan. 27, 2020) (on file with Comm.); Submission
from Source 150, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Aug. 16, 2017) (on file with Comm.).
1688
Submission from Online Merchants Guild, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Oct. 29,
2019) (on file with Comm.).
1689
Id.
1690
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 545–46 (response to Questions for the
Record, Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.); Amazon Services
Business Solutions Agreement, A
MAZON
S
ELLER
C
ENT
., https://sellercentral.amazon.com/gp/
help/external/G1791 (last visited Sept. 29, 2020).
1691
See, e.g., Interview with Source 125 (Jan. 9, 2020) (explaining the reason for agreeing
to Amazon’s terms, ‘‘What can I do? They don’t give me much choice. You are so small that you
don’t have any leverage.’’).
1692
Submission from Online Merchants Guild, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Oct. 29,
2019) (on file with Comm.).
1693
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 545–47 (response to Questions for the
Record, Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1694
See Cynthia Estlund, The Black Hole of Mandatory Arbitration, 96 N.C. L. R
EV
. 679, 684
(2018) (stating that mandatory arbitration ‘‘effectively enables employers to nullify employee
rights and to insulate themselves from the liabilities that back up crucial public policies’’); see
also Judith Resnik, Diffusing Disputes: The Public in the Private of Arbitration, the Private in
Courts, and the Erasure of Rights, 124 Y
ALE
L.J. 2804, 2873 (2015) (‘‘Mandated arbitration is
also common in web-based sales.’’).
1695
See Submission from Online Merchants Guild, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Oct. 29,
2019) (on file with Comm.).
plained in its submission, ‘‘a ‘Jeff Letter’ is almost like a Writ of
Certiorari within Amazon’s internal kangaroo court system.’’
1688
But by the time this point is reached, ‘‘a seller could be locked out
of their account, or denied funds, for weeks, losing hundreds of
thousands of dollars even if the mistake was Amazon’s.’’
1689
Be-
cause of the large volume of sellers who reach this point of last re-
sort, sending a ‘‘Jeff Letter’’ is not a realistic avenue for most sell-
ers to get their issues addressed.
(2) Forced Arbitration. All of Amazon’s third-party sellers and
most of its vendors are subject to a pre-dispute, binding (forced) ar-
bitration clause,
1690
requiring them to sign away the right to their
day in court if a dispute with Amazon arises. The Subcommittee
heard from sellers who said that if it were not for Amazon’s market
power over them, they would not agree to this term.
1691
As noted
by the Online Merchants Guild, ‘‘Through arbitration, Amazon
knows it holds all the cards, and in many ways has the final say
whenever there is a dispute.’’
1692
As a result, sellers rarely initiate
arbitration actions against Amazon. Between 2014 and 2019, even
as the number of Amazon sellers continued to grow by hundreds
of thousands per year, only 163 sellers and 16 vendors initiated ar-
bitration proceedings.
1693
Because sellers are generally aware that
the process is unfair and unlikely to result in a meaningful remedy,
they have little incentive to bring an action.
As extensive scholarship has shown, forced arbitration often fails
to provide a legitimate forum for resolving disputes and instead
usually serves to insulate those engaging in wrongdoing from liabil-
ity.
1694
The case of Amazon sellers is no different. In practice, arbi-
tration functions as a way for Amazon to keep disputes within its
control, with the scales tipped heavily in its favor. As such, Ama-
zon can withhold payments from sellers, suspend their accounts
without cause, and engage in other abusive behavior without facing
any legal consequences for its actions.
1695
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00235 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
230
1696
See, e.g., Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–
00206936 (Nov. 8, 2013) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Seems like we should be making more on the
seller loans .... Net takeaway is that sellers may be getting too good of a deal .... There are
different ways to fix . . . commitment fees, higher rates, etc. We should get rewarded for satis-
fying a timing spike like this.’’).
1697
S
TACY
M
ITCHELL
, R
ON
K
NOX &
Z
ACH
F
REED
, I
NST
.
OF
L
OCAL
S
ELF
-R
ELIANCE
, R
EPORT
:
A
MAZON
S
M
ONOPOLY
T
OLLBOOTH
3 (2020), https://ilsr.org/amazonsltollbooth/.
1698
Id. See also Interview with Jason Boyce, Founder & CEO, Avenue7Media, LLC (Sept. 15,
2020) (estimating that most sellers are currently paying an average of 35 percent in fees to
Amazon when you add up the referral fees and payments for ads based on his experience).
1699
M
ARKETPLACE
P
ULSE
, M
ARKETPLACES
Y
EAR IN
R
EVIEW
4 (2019), https://cdn
.marketplacepulse.com/misc/marketplaces-year-in-review-2019.pdf.
1700
Id.
1701
See, e.g., Interview with Top Shelf Brands (Sept. 29. 2020) (estimating Top Shelf paid
Amazon over $1 million in fees for advertising in one year); Submission from Top Shelf, to H.
Comm. on the Judiciary, Ex. 1 (Oct. 26, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
1702
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00186540 (Jan.
30, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
1703
See, e.g., J
UNGLE
S
COUT
, T
HE
S
TATE OF THE
A
MAZON
S
ELLER
2020, at 4 (2020), https://
www.junglescout.com/wp-content/uploads/2020/02/State-of-the-Seller-Survey.pdf (‘‘More than a
third (37%) of sellers [surveyed] earn income from Amazon sales alone.’’).
1704
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 5 (statement of Stacy Mitchell, Co-Dir.,
Inst. for Local Self-Reliance) (‘‘Amazon’s [gatekeeper power] allows it to maintain a God-like
view of the transactions of rival businesses and customers, and use this data to move into new
markets with a built-in advantage.’’).
1705
See, e.g., Interview with Source 158 (July 2, 2020); Submission from Nat’l Ass’n of Whole-
saler-Distributors, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (July 22, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
1706
See, e.g., Interview with Jason Boyce, Founder & CEO, Avenue7Media (Sept. 15, 2020).
(3) Seller Fee Increases. Amazon’s treatment of sellers indicates
that it sees them as a source of profit, rather than ‘‘part-
ners.’’
1696
Individuals and small businesses who depend on access
to the platform to make sales report that Amazon has raised seller
fees significantly over the past decade. Over the past five years, a
recent Institute for Local Self-Reliance report estimates that Ama-
zon added an extra 11 percent to its cut of third-party sales.
1697
The platform now takes an average of 30 percent of each sale com-
pared to 19 percent in 2015.
1698
In 2018, third-party sellers paid
Amazon $39.7 billion in fees, which totaled about 25 percent of
Amazon’s $160 billion in Gross Merchandise Volume.
1699
This
amount includes commissions, fulfillment and shipping fees, and
other third-party seller services, but does not include revenue from
the advertising fees for third-party sellers,
1700
which are often sub-
stantial.
1701
An internal Amazon document suggests the company
can increase fees to third-party sellers without concern for them
switching to another marketplace. The document notes that the
amount of ‘‘seller attrition as a result of [2018] fee increases’’ for
its Fulfillment by Amazon program was ‘‘[n]othing significant.’’
1702
Amazon’s pattern of exploiting sellers, enabled by its market
dominance, raises serious competition concerns. For many sellers,
there is no viable alternative to Amazon, and a significant number
of sellers rely on its marketplace for their entire livelihood.
1703
(4) Appropriation of Third-Party Seller Data. One of the widely
reported ways in which Amazon treats third-party sellers unfairly
centers on Amazon’s asymmetric access to and use of third-party
seller data.
1704
During the investigation, the Subcommittee heard
repeated concerns that Amazon leverages its access to third-party
sellers’ data to identify and replicate popular and profitable prod-
ucts from among the hundreds of millions of listings on its market-
place.
1705
Armed with this information, it appears that Amazon
would: (1) copy the product to create a competing private-label
product
1706
; or (2) identify and source the product directly from the
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00236 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
231
1707
See, e.g., Submission from Nat’l Ass’n of Wholesaler-Distributors, to H. Comm. on the Ju-
diciary (July 22, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
1708
CEO Hearing at 302 (response to Questions for the Record of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Ama-
zon.com, Inc.).
1709
Id. at 303.
1710
Jeff Bezos, 2018 Letter to Shareholders, T
HE
A
MAZON
B
LOG
: D
AY
O
NE
(Apr. 11, 2019),
https://blog.aboutamazon.com/company-news/2018-letter-to-shareholders.
1711
CEO Hearing at 304 (response to Questions for the Record of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Ama-
zon.com, Inc.).
1712
Id. at 303–04.
manufacturer to free ride off the seller’s efforts, and then cut that
seller out of the equation.
1707
Amazon claims that it has no incentive to abuse sellers’ trust be-
cause third-party sales make up nearly 60 percent of its sales, and
that Amazon’s first-party sales are relatively small.
1708
Amazon
has similarly pointed out that third-party listings far outnumber
Amazon’s first-party listings.
1709
In a recent shareholder letter,
CEO Jeff Bezos wrote, ‘‘Third-party sellers are kicking our first-
party butt. Badly.’’
1710
In response to a question from the Sub-
committee, however, Amazon admitted that by percentage of
sales—a more telling measure—Amazon’s first-party sales are sig-
nificant and growing in a number of categories. For example, in
books, Amazon owns 74 percent of sales, whereas third-party sell-
ers only account for 26 percent of sales.
1711
At the category level,
it does not appear that third-party sellers are kicking Amazon’s
first-party butt. Amazon may, in fact, be positioned to overtake its
third-party sellers in several categories as its first-party business
continues to grow.
Third-Party vs. First-Party Listings
and Sales on Amazon
1712
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00237 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 21 here 11701.021
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
232
1713
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00142724 (on
file with Comm.).
1714
CEO Hearing at 281 (response to Questions for the Record of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Ama-
zon.com, Inc.).
1715
Id. at 320.
1716
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 42 (statement of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen.
Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1717
Amazon: Former Employee Challenges Executives’ Denial About Company’s Use of Sellers’
Data, C
APITOL
F
ORUM
(July 18, 2019).
1718
Krystal Hu, Amazon Uses Third-Party Seller Data to Build a Private Label Juggernaut,
Y
AHOO
F
IN
. (Sept. 27, 2019), https://finance.yahoo.com/news/amazon-uses-thirdparty-sellers-
data-to-build-private-labels-145813238.html.
1719
Dana Mattioli, Amazon Scooped Up Data from Its Own Sellers to Launch Competing
Products, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (Apr. 23, 2020), https://www.wsj.com/articles/amazon-scooped-up-data-
from-its-own-sellers-to-launch-competing-products-11587650015.
1720
Id.
Amazon recognizes that it competes against many of its third-
party sellers.
1713
In response to concerns about its unfair use of
third-party seller data, Amazon points to its Seller Data Protection
Policy, which it instituted in 2014.
1714
According to the company:
Amazon recognizes that third-party sellers are our customers too, and their trust
is critical to Amazon’s success. In an effort to further this partnership, Amazon
decided years ago to take additional voluntary steps to protect seller data by in-
stituting its voluntarily-adopted Seller Data Protection Policy, which prohibits
Amazon Retail teams from using non-public seller-specific data to compete
against third-party sellers.
1715
Following up on public reporting and information collected dur-
ing the investigation suggesting that Amazon might be abusing its
access to third-party sellers’ data, Representative Pramila Jayapal
(D–WA) asked Amazon lawyer Nate Sutton about this precise issue
at a Subcommittee hearing in July 2019. Sutton testified: ‘‘We do
not use [third-party sellers’] individual data when we’re making de-
cisions to launch private brands.’’
1716
Since the July 2019 hearing, public reporting has made clear
that, contrary to its own internal policy and testimony before Con-
gress, Amazon routinely appropriates seller data to benefit its own
private-label and retail businesses. After the hearing, according to
a July 2019 report, a former employee who worked in product man-
agement told The Capitol Forum, ‘‘I used to pull sellers’ data to
look at what the best products were when I was there .... That
was my job.’’
1717
In September 2019, employees reported to Yahoo
Finance that access to data is a ‘‘free-for-all’’ and that Amazon Re-
tail and Marketplace teams ‘‘share the same access to the data
warehouse, which makes it possible for the retail team to use the
data from marketplace sellers to develop private labels.’’
1718
Earlier this year, in a groundbreaking article, The Wall Street
Journal reported that executives in Amazon’s private-label division
‘‘had access to data containing proprietary information that they
used to research bestselling items they might want to compete
against, including on individual sellers on Amazon’s website.’’
1719
In one case, Amazon employees reportedly used non-public sales
data about a third-party seller of car-trunk organizers named
Fortem to develop an Amazon private-label version of the very
same product.
1720
In light of the April 2020 report from The Wall Street Journal,
the Committee requested that Jeff Bezos testify before Congress to
address the possibility that Amazon’s lawyer had misled Con-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00238 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
233
1721
Letter from Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. David N.
Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the
Judiciary, Hon. F. James Sensenbrenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commer-
cial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Joe Neguse, Vice Chair, Subcomm.
on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Pramila
Jayapal, Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on
the Judiciary, Hon. Ken Buck, Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law
of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. Matt Gaetz, Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Com-
mercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, to Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com,
Inc. (May 1, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
1722
CEO Hearing at 280 (response to Questions for the Record of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Ama-
zon.com, Inc.).
1723
Id. at 66 (statement of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1724
Id. at 121 (question of Rep. Ken Buck (R–CO), Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Com-
mercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
1725
Amazon Policy (@amazonlpolicy), T
WITTER
(Apr. 24, 2020, 3:36 p.m.), https://twitter
.com/amazonlpolicy/status/1253769684425625601.
1726
Letter from Brian Huseman, Vice President, Pub. Pol’y, Amazon.com, Inc., to Hon. Jerrold
Nadler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Anti-
trust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. F. James Sensen-
brenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.
Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. Jim Jordan, Ranking Member, H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Oct.
4, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
1727
Id.
gress.
1721
Despite significant public reporting on the issue and ref-
erences to it in Amazon’s internal documents, Mr. Bezos claimed to
be unaware of these practices. According to Mr. Bezos, ‘‘Amazon
first learned about the alleged violations of Amazon’s voluntarily
adopted Seller Data Protection Policy recently reported in The Wall
Street Journal from The Wall Street Journal.’’
1722
When Rep-
resentative Pramila Jayapal (D–WA) again asked in July 2020
about whether Amazon uses third-party seller data to benefit its
private-label products, Bezos could only respond: ‘‘I can’t answer
that question yes or no .... [W]e have a policy against using seller-
specific data to aid our private-label business, but I can’t guarantee
you that that policy has never been violated.’’
1723
Representative Ken Buck (R–CO) similarly raised this issue with
Mr. Bezos, stating, ‘‘I’m concerned that you’ve used Amazon’s domi-
nant market position to unfairly harm competition. We’ve heard
from a number of companies that Amazon uses proprietary data
from third-party companies to launch its own private-label prod-
ucts.’’
1724
Later in the hearing, Representative Kelly Armstrong
(R–ND) described this as an ‘‘important issue,’’ and asked whether
‘‘Amazon is conducting an internal investigation into the use of
third-party data,’’ to which Mr. Bezos answered in the affirmative.
Mr. Bezos agreed to inform the Subcommittee of the outcome of
that investigation.
In October 2020, approximately six months after Amazon said
that it had initiated the investigation,
1725
the company informed
the Committee that it had completed it.
1726
According to Amazon’s
Vice President of Public Policy, Brian Huseman, ‘‘Amazon’s records
of past data queries related to the two products cited in The Wall
Street Journal report show that a single former employee pulled
and analyzed only aggregate data for both products in compliance
with the Seller Data Protection Policy.’’
1727
The results of this lim-
ited investigation do not alter the views of the Subcommittee on
Amazon’s use of third-party seller data as set forth in this Report.
The Subcommittee uncovered evidence in interviews with former
Amazon employees, as well as current and former sellers, that is
consistent with the public reporting about Amazon’s misuse of sell-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00239 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
234
1728
See Submission from Nat’l Ass’n of Wholesaler-Distributors, to H. Comm. on the Judici-
ary (July 22, 2020) (on file with Comm.) (describing a member’s experience in which Amazon
allowed a distributor to sell a product for about a year, ‘‘then went out and replicated the prod-
uct and began selling their own branded product, terminating the distributor .... Amazon be-
came the winner and the distributor was left empty handed’’).
1729
Submission from Source 91, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Sept. 16, 2020) (on file with
Comm.).
1730
Id.
1731
Interview with Source 154 (July 2, 2019).
1732
Id.
1733
Interview with Jason Boyce, Founder & CEO, Avenue7Media (Sept. 15, 2020).
1734
Id.
1735
Id.
er data.
1728
In a submission to the Subcommittee, a former em-
ployee said:
In 2010, I started working on the Amazon marketplace team .... It was widely
known that many (10+) of my peers were running very successful [third-party]
accounts, where they were pulling private data on Amazon seller activity, so they
could figure out market opportunity, etc. Totally not legitimate, but no one mon-
itored or seemed to care.
1729
Referring to accessibility of third-party seller data, the same indi-
vidual told the Subcommittee, ‘‘It’s a candy shop, everyone can
have access to anything they want,’’ and added, ‘‘There’s a rule, but
there’s nobody enforcing or spot-checking. They just say, don’t help
yourself to the data . . . it was ‘wink wink,’ don’t access.’’
1730
The Subcommittee interviewed a third-party seller who described
how Amazon uses a request for proof of authenticity to collect pro-
prietary information about a seller’s business. According to the sell-
er, Amazon will submit a product authenticity claim to sellers, forc-
ing the retailer to submit their original sales receipts as proof that
the items are authentic.
1731
Although a seller is supposed to be
able to black out price information, sometimes the platform will re-
ject a submission on the basis that it is an ‘‘altered document.’’
1732
With insight into the seller’s costs and supplier, combined with its
knowledge of the seller’s retail price among a virtually
unfathomable amount of other data, it appears that Amazon Retail
can easily replicate the seller’s listing to offer a competing product.
A former third-party seller and retired U.S. Marine told the Sub-
committee about several instances over his seventeen years as a
seller when Amazon leveraged his work, undercut him on price,
and eventually drove him out of business. In each instance, he had
to change his business model after Amazon took over the Buy Box
for his listings, ‘‘killing’’ his sales.
1733
On at least two different oc-
casions, his company did all the legwork to create a new, top-sell-
ing product or product line, as well as creating the product listings,
only to have Amazon copy the idea and offer a competing product.
Amazon used different tactics each time, but the result was always
the same: Amazon profited from his work and made it impossible
for him to fairly compete.
1734
As part of his last attempt to sell on Amazon, his business cre-
ated its own line of table game products with a unique design and
color palette. Once these products became top sellers, Amazon
again swooped in to reap the rewards of his work. Amazon copied
his designs, down to the color palette, and started selling their
competing products at unsustainable prices. Ultimately, he exited
his seller business, gave up on trying to bring new products to con-
sumers, and founded a consulting agency for Amazon sellers.
1735
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00240 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
235
1736
CEO Hearing at 116 (question of Rep. David N. Cicilline (D–RI), Chair, Subcomm. on
Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
1737
Letter from David Zapolsky, Gen. Couns., Amazon.com, Inc., to Hon. David N. Cicilline,
Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary
(July 26, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
1738
Dana Mattioli, Amazon Scooped Up Data from Its Own Sellers to Launch Competing
Products, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (Apr. 23, 2020), https://www.wsj.com/articles/amazon-scooped-up-data-
from-its-own-sellers-to-launch-competing-products-11587650015.
1739
CEO Hearing at 132 (statement of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1740
Dana Mattioli, Amazon Scooped Up Data from Its Own Sellers to Launch Competing
Products, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (Apr. 23, 2020), https://www.wsj.com/articles/amazon-scooped-up-data-
from-its-own-sellers-to-launch-competing-products-11587650015.
In addition to its private-label business, Amazon also uses third-
party seller data to benefit its Amazon Retail business, where the
company functions more like a retailer. At the Subcommittee’s
sixth hearing, Chair David N. Cicilline (D–RI) asked Mr. Bezos
about this conduct, recounting the story that a former third-party
seller shared with the Subcommittee:
During this investigation, we have heard so many heartbreaking stories of small
businesses who sunk significant time and resources into building a business and
selling on Amazon, only to have Amazon poach their best-selling items and drive
them out of business.
So I want to talk to you about one company that really stood out from the rest.
I want you to pay close attention to how they described your partnership, Mr.
Bezos. We heard from a small apparel company that makes and sells what they
call ‘‘useful apparel’’ for people who work on their feet and with their hands, like
construction workers and firefighters.
This particular business discovered and started selling a unique item that had
never been a top seller for the brand. They were making about $60,000 a year
on just this one item. One day, they woke up and found that Amazon had started
listing the exact same product, causing their sales to go to zero overnight. Ama-
zon had undercut their price, setting it below what the manufacturer would gen-
erally allow it to be sold so that, even if they wanted to, they couldn’t match
the price.
1736
Amazon has tried to draw a meaningful distinction between indi-
vidual and aggregate data, but this is largely beside the point when
it comes to the concerns that Subcommittee members have about
the platform’s conduct and its effect on competition. Amazon says
it only uses ‘‘aggregate’’ seller data across multiple sellers, not ‘‘in-
dividual’’ data about any specific seller.
1737
Importantly, though, it
chooses how those terms are defined and uses various methods to
deem seller data as aggregate rather than individual. According to
The Wall Street Journal report, because Fortem accounted for
99.95 percent of total sales in the car-trunk organizer product cat-
egory, not 100 percent, Amazon considered that data aggregate
rather than individual.
1738
And at the Subcommittee’s hearing in
July 2020, Bezos confirmed that Amazon indeed allows the use of
aggregate data to inform private-label brands when there are only
two or three sellers of a product.
1739
Separately, if there is only
one seller of an item, and Amazon is selling returned or damaged
versions of that item through its Amazon Warehouse Deals pro-
gram, that data is considered aggregate.
1740
An Amazon ‘‘Frequently Asked Questions’’ (FAQ) document from
2014 suggests that Amazon was aware that the Seller Data Protec-
tion Policy had significant loopholes. For example, the document in-
dicates that even seller-specific data can be used for ‘‘strategic busi-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00241 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
236
1741
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00221869
(June 30, 2014) (on file with Comm.).
1742
Id.
1743
See, e.g., id. at AMAZON–HJC–00207035 to –00207036 (Sept. 19, 2013) (on file with
Comm.) (‘‘On the top selling Owl necklace . . . we should go deep and see what we can learn
including how much it would costs [sic] to manufacture this?’’).
1744
See Colin Lecher, How Amazon Escapes Liability for the Riskiest Products on Its Site,
V
ERGE
(Jan. 28, 2020), https://www.theverge.com/2020/1/28/21080720/amazon-product-liabil-
ity-lawsuits-marketplace-damage-third-party.
1745
See generally CEO Hearing (statements of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1746
See generally Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing (statements of Nate Sutton,
Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1747
P
UB
. C
ITIZEN
, P
RIME
G
OUGING
: H
OW
A
MAZON
R
AISED
P
RICES TO
P
ROFIT FROM THE
P
AN
-
DEMIC
5 (2020), https://www.citizen.org/article/prime-gouging/ (also noting ‘‘a pattern of
Continued
ness decision at the category level or above.’’
1741
The answer to an
FAQ also makes clear that the line between ‘‘aggregated’’ data and
‘‘Seller-specific’’ data is fuzzy: ‘‘As a general rule, if information
isn’t directly tied or easily attributed to a specific Seller, it can be
considered aggregated and non-Seller-specific.’’ As to how aggre-
gated information attributed to a small group of Sellers should be
treated, the guidance is also ambiguous: ‘‘This is a high judgment
area. If Seller-specific information could be easily derived from ag-
gregated information, it should be treated as Seller-specific.’’
1742
In addition to collecting data relating to sales, Amazon may also
be able to reverse engineer third-party sellers’ cost structures
through the tools that it offers sellers to track profits, costs, ad
spend, and other expenses, as well as fulfillment services through
Fulfillment by Amazon (FBA). An internal document suggests that
Amazon may use its FBA service as an avenue to identify popular
third-party seller items and gather competitively sensitive informa-
tion about them.
1743
FBA provides another avenue for Amazon to
access competing sellers’ third-party data.
The documents and information that the Subcommittee reviewed
suggest that instances of Amazon’s data misappropriation go be-
yond what is in the public domain. Furthermore, the Subcommittee
rejects Amazon’s contention that Amazon’s use of third-party seller
data is no different from a traditional brick-and-mortar retailer’s
use of data. The Subcommittee also does not believe that the mar-
ketplace-derived data the platform uses to inform Amazon Retail’s
product pipeline, among other decisions, is equally available to all
Amazon Marketplace sellers.
On many fronts, Amazon makes inconsistent arguments depend-
ing on the forum and issue in support of its attempts to escape li-
ability. In the context of lawsuits regarding liability for counterfeits
and unsafe products sold on its site, Amazon insists it is a market-
place and not a retailer.
1744
By contrast, in his testimony before
the Subcommittee, Mr. Bezos referred to Amazon as a ‘‘store’’ and
a ‘‘retailer.’’
1745
Similarly, when Nate Sutton testified before the
Subcommittee, he stated, ‘‘Amazon is one of the leading retail-
ers.’’
1746
In response to price gouging allegations, Amazon switches
back to the position that it is just a marketplace. As Public Citizen
observed in a recent report titled Prime Gouging:
Amazon is trying to have the best of both worlds by enabling third-party sellers
to exploit the crisis (and benefiting from facilitating those sales), but also seeking
to immunize itself from responsibility for directly engaging in price gouging by
shifting the focus on to the unscrupulous actions of third-party sellers, not only
in the eye of the public but also in the eye of the law.
1747
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00242 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
237
significant price increases on essential products sold directly by Amazon, as well as price
gouging by third-party sellers’’).
1748
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00221867
(June 30, 2014) (on file with Comm.) (listing information protected by the Seller Data Protection
Policy as ‘‘Seller pricing plans (e.g., future promotions), Seller inventory levels, Seller sourcing
information, Seller sales (e.g., unit sales, GMS), [and] Seller performance (e.g., non-public
metrics)’’).
1749
See Stigler Report at 45 (‘‘Traditional brick-and-mortar stores and online platforms differ
greatly in their advertising and personalization capabilities.’’).
1750
Submission from Source 91, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Sept. 22, 2020) (on file with
Comm.).
Amazon identified a few types of non-public seller data that it
has access to, but which are supposed to be protected by its Seller
Data Protection Policy.
1748
It is obvious from this small glimpse
into the data Amazon has at its disposal that the type and scope
of data the platform can access is very different from the informa-
tion available to traditional brick-and-mortar stores. Physical
stores have much less detailed information about the competing
products they offer for sale alongside their private-label items.
Physical stores also have far less information about customers’
shopping habits and preferences.
1749
(5) Self-Preferencing. By virtue of its role as an intermediary in
the marketplace, Amazon can give itself favorable treatment rel-
ative to competing sellers. It has done so through its control over
the Buy Box, as well as by granting itself access to data and tools
that are off-limits for third-party sellers. Most recently, there have
been reports that Amazon has given preferential treatment to its
own non-essential products over competitors’ non-essential products
during the pandemic.
(a) Critical Inputs. Amazon has control over critical inputs for
competing sellers and other types of competitors—including con-
sumer data, fulfillment and delivery services, and advertising and
other marketing tools—that give it the ability to advantage itself
over rivals. During the investigation, the Subcommittee conducted
numerous interviews with market participants that, along with
credible public reporting and Amazon’s documents, confirm that
Amazon employed this business strategy as early as 2009 and con-
tinues to do so today.
(b) Access to Market Data. Amazon has access to data that gives
it greater insight into consumer behavior and preferences than
competing sellers on its platform. A former Amazon employee that
the Subcommittee interviewed summarized the significance of this
information asymmetry:
It’s important to understand that Amazon has access to every piece of data on
what products each customer has searched and purchased [or] not purchased ....
With information about what customers have searched, Amazon is able to create
customized marketing [and] targeting of products for the individual customer. ‘‘Is
Amazon using a particular [third-party] seller’s data here? No,’’ but it is using
all of the aggregate site data to develop a highly targeted marketing plan for
each customer. Should Amazon choose to use that targeting information to focus
[on] its own products, it can, while [third-party] sellers don’t have access to simi-
lar data.
1750
Although Amazon provides its sellers with access to some helpful
data and tools—which is a key differentiator from other market-
places with no or limited seller tools—there is a large amount of
data that is off-limits, only available at a largely prohibitive cost,
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00243 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
238
1751
Robyn Johnson, Amazon Just Made the $30k Amazon Retail Analytics Premium Data
Free, S
EARCH
E
NGINE
J. (Feb. 26, 2020), https://www.searchenginejournal.com/amazon-retail-
analytics-premium-data-free/350692.
1752
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00188405 to
–00188406 (Dec. 14, 2017) (on file with Comm.).
1753
Id.
1754
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00188536 (Dec. 15, 2017).
1755
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 509 (response to Questions for the Record
of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1756
See, e.g., Interview with Source 125 (July 7, 2020) (explaining that the inability to move
customer reviews from Amazon to other marketplaces is a barrier to use of other marketplaces,
due to the importance of customer feedback for seller reputation).
1757
Elizabeth Weise, Amazon Bans ‘‘Incentivized’’ Reviews, USA T
ODAY
(Oct. 3, 2016),
https://www.usatoday.com/story/tech/news/2016/10/03/amazon-bans-incentivized-reviews/
91488702/.
1758
Id.
1759
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00146732 (Dec.
14, 2017) (on file with Comm.); Spencer Soper, Amazon Doles Out Freebies to Juice Sales of Its
Own Brands, B
LOOMBERG
N
EWS
(Oct. 16, 2018), https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/
2018-10-16/amazon-doles-out-freebies-to-juice-sales-of-its-own-brands.
or unhelpful because it is outdated or inaccurate. One paid service
that Amazon offered sellers was called Amazon Retail Analytics
Premium. Sellers who paid extra to participate in this program
could access some, but not all, of the data Amazon collected on
marketplace activity. But the program was expensive: Vendors re-
portedly had to pay a minimum of $30,000 to get access to this
database.
1751
Another example of this asymmetric access to data is evident
from an Amazon internal email discussion. The discussion began
with a consultant alerting Amazon employees about a problem with
its Marketplace Web Services APIs that caused it to report infor-
mation to sellers that is ‘‘disconnected from the reality and often
misleading.’’
1752
According to the representative, ‘‘This is a huge
issue and causes sellers losses and inconvenience.’’
1753
In re-
sponse, an Amazon employee said that there was not a problem
with the API functionality; rather, the Pricing APIs just do not pro-
vide sellers with information at the level of granularity requested.
Further, she explained that this is ‘‘a feature request for adding lo-
cation aware information to the Pricing APIs,’’ which is ‘‘currently
below the line for 2018 for the pricing team.’’
1754
(c) Marketing Tools. One tool that Amazon Retail uses to benefit
its own business is Amazon Vine, a review-generating pro-
gram.
1755
In interviews with market participants, many sellers
said that good reviews are critical for a product to be successful on-
line.
1756
Accordingly, sellers aim to obtain as many positive reviews
as possible early in a product’s life cycle. At one time, it was per-
missible for Amazon sellers to provide incentives such as free sam-
ples to reviewers. However, in 2016, it was widely reported that
some sellers were generating fake reviews.
1757
In response to these
reports, Amazon announced that it would ban incentivized reviews
except for those obtained through its own incentivized review pro-
gram, Amazon Vine.
1758
As a result, sellers lost access to this pro-
gram, regardless of whether they were engaged in bad conduct or
not.
For many years, including after the incentivized-reviews ban, the
Amazon Vine program was not available to third-party sellers,
while Amazon continued to enjoy the program’s ability to ‘‘mini-
mize marketing costs associated with generating awareness early
in a product’s lifecycle,’’ among other benefits.
1759
An Amazon in-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00244 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
239
1760
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00146732 (Dec.
14, 2017) (on file with Comm.); see also id. at AMAZON–HJC–0059576 (Nov. 22, 2010) (describ-
ing the program as ‘‘[g]reat for new product launches—good for seeding’’).
1761
Dana Mattioli et al., Amazon Restricts How Rival Device Makers Buy Ads on Its Site,
W
ALL
S
T
. J. (Sept. 22, 2020), https://www.wsj.com/articles/amazon-restricts-advertising-
competitor-device-makers-roku-arlo-11600786638.
1762
Id.
1763
Interview with Source 148 (Aug. 26, 2020).
1764
Id.
1765
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00129156 (Dec.
14, 2017) (on file with Comm.).
1766
Id.
1767
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00065094 (May 28, 2009) (on file with Comm.).
ternal document describes other advantages of the program as,
‘‘[d]rive conversion and sales with more insightful reviews on detail
pages,’’ and ‘‘can contribute to higher order counts and sales.’’
1760
By both banning incentivized reviews and excluding third-party
sellers from the Amazon Vine program, Amazon allocated to itself
a significant marketing advantage over the other businesses with
which it competes on its platform.
Amazon’s dual position as both operator and seller on its online
marketplace also provides it with the ability to disadvantage com-
petitors that seek to sell or advertise on its platform. One way that
Amazon does this is by limiting certain rivals’ ability to buy Ama-
zon.com search advertising—ads that present products at the top
of the search results when consumers enter specific search terms
or a product name. Although ‘‘search advertising is a lucrative part
of the company’s business,’’ Amazon ‘‘won’t let some of its own
large competitors buy sponsored-product ads tied to searches for
Amazon’s own devices.’’
1761
The Wall Street Journal reported this
month that Roku, Inc. ‘‘can’t even buy [ ] Amazon ads tied to its
own products.’’
1762
Consistent with this report, a competitor of
Amazon that manufacturers voice-enabled devices told the Sub-
committee that Amazon prohibited it from buying ads on Ama-
zon.com.
1763
The competitor expressed concerns about the harm
this could cause consumers, who may be confused or deceived when
they receive ads promoting Amazon products even when they spe-
cifically search for a competitor’s product on Amazon.com.
1764
The Subcommittee’s investigation also uncovered internal docu-
ments showing that Amazon executives have long understood the
competitive advantage Amazon wields due to the company’s control
over search advertising on Amazon.com. In an internal email de-
scribing an ad block against Groupon and other ‘‘deal site
ecommerce competitors,’’
1765
an Amazon executive wrote that
‘‘Groupon is blocked let’s keep a clear line on this. No deal site
ecommerce competitors allowed to advertise on amazon.x sites.’’
1766
Similarly, an email discussion in 2009 among high-level Amazon
executives discussed the possibility of implementing an ad block
against Diapers.com, saying:
Do we really think it is ok that Diapers.com flipped from selling on the platform
to being a large scale user of Product Ads totally unscrrutinized [sic]? I don’t ....
We’re under no obligation to allow them to advertise on our site. I’d argue we
should block them from buying Product Ads immediately or at minimum price
those ads so they truly reflect the opportunity cost of a lost diaper buyer (or to
reflect the true value of a new customer to such a competitor[ ]).
1767
The executive suggests that Amazon should maintain a ‘‘watch
list’’ of strategic competitors and set up ‘‘[a]n automatic trigger
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00245 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
240
1768
Id.
1769
Dana Mattioli et al., Amazon Restricts How Rival Device Makers Buy Ads on Its Site,
W
ALL
S
T
. J. (Sept. 22, 2020), https://www.wsj.com/articles/amazon-restricts-advertising-
competitor-device-makers-roku-arlo-11600786638.
1770
CEO Hearing at 286–87 (response to Questions for the Record of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Ama-
zon.com, Inc.).
1771
C
HANGE TO
W
IN
, A
MAZON
COVID–19 W
ORKER
S
URVEY
D
ATA
B
RIEF
3 (2020), https://
static1.squarespace.com/static/5d374de8aae9940001c8ed59/t/5ec67b15a155792a0f9ef435/15900
65963743/Amazon-Worker-COVID-19-Data-Brief.pdf.
1772
Id.
1773
See, e.g., Submission from Source 91, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Sept. 16, 2020)
(‘‘When we looked at Amazon private-label products during April/early May, they were almost
all available for immediate Prime delivery, while comparable national brands were not able to
get the same shipment times. Definitely preference was given to many Amazon private-label
products during times of ‘essential’/‘non-essential’ classification.’’); Interview with Source 152
(Sept. 18, 2020).
1774
CEO Hearing at 287 (response to Questions for the Record of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Ama-
zon.com, Inc.) (‘‘After instituting these changes, Amazon became aware that shipments of certain
Amazon devices that did not fall into the priority categories had been inadvertently included
in the list of products with faster delivery promises. This was unintentional.’’).
when a merchant on [the] watch list . . . attempts to launch a sig-
nificant quantity of product ads—with escalated approval required
to allow their ads to launch.’’
1768
The Wall Street Journal’s report,
based on discussions with Amazon employees, confirms that Ama-
zon ultimately implemented a plan of this type. According to the
report, ‘‘Tier 1 Competitors’’ are blocked from buying certain ads
and employees are allegedly instructed to ‘‘mark any discussion of
this practice . . . with ‘privileged and confidential’ to evade regu-
lators.’’
1769
In March 2020, Amazon announced that it would begin tempo-
rarily delaying shipments of all non-essential products from its
warehouses, regardless of whether they were sold by Amazon or by
competing third-party sellers.
1770
The company claimed it was
doing so to better serve customers in need while also helping to en-
sure the safety of warehouse workers. The effect of this change was
to block third-party sellers of items that Amazon designated ‘‘non-
essential’’ from shipping new inventory using Fulfillment by Ama-
zon.
Amazon reportedly excepted itself from this policy and continued
to ship non-essential items sold by Amazon Retail from its ware-
houses. According to a survey of Amazon workers conducted by
Change to Win between April 29 and May 9, 2020, workers re-
ported that Amazon had ‘‘continued to ship non-essential items
such as hammocks, fish tanks, sex toys, and pool floaties.’’
1771
More than two-thirds of fulfillment center workers reported that 50
percent or more of the items they handled during this period were
non-essential. Based on the survey results, Change to Win con-
cluded that ‘‘Amazon has continued to place workers in danger of
contracting COVID–19 in order to ship non-essential goods.’’
1772
A
number of market participants that the Subcommittee interviewed
also indicated that Amazon prioritized shipping its own items over
those sold by third-party sellers.
1773
Amazon confirmed that it did
give preferential treatment to its own products for a period of time,
but claimed it was ‘‘unintentional.’’
1774
(6) Tying and Bundling—Fulfillment by Amazon and Advertising
(a) Fulfillment by Amazon. There is a strong link between Ama-
zon Marketplace and Fulfillment by Amazon (FBA), Amazon’s paid
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00246 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
241
1775
Fulfillment by Amazon, A
MAZON
, https://sell.amazon.com/fulfillment-by-amazon.html
(last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
1776
Pascal, The Seller Fulfilled Prime Team, Important Updates to Seller Fulfilled Prime,
A
MAZON
S
ERVS
. S
ELLER
F
ORUMS
(Aug. 18, 2020), https://sellercentral.amazon.com/forums/t/
important-updates-to-seller-fulfilled-prime/682240.
1777
See, e.g., Interview with Jason Boyce, Founder & CEO, Avenue7Media, LLC (Sept. 15,
2020) (‘‘It used to be possible, but hard, to be a Seller Fulfilled Prime seller. There were only
200 sellers that were able to meet the requirements. What’s changing recently is that they used
to allow you to have the Prime badge in certain regions, but now they say you need the Prime
badge nationally, i.e., you need to have multiple warehouses across the country plus ship on Sat-
urdays, etc.’’).
1778
Regan McPhee, How to Sell on Amazon Prime in 2020, J
UNGLE
S
COUT
(May 27, 2020),
https://www.junglescout.com/blog/how-to-sell-on-amazon-prime/.
1779
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00186643 (July
23, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
1780
See J. Clament, Fulfillment by Amazon (FBA) Usage Among Top Marketplace Sellers
Worldwide 2017–2018, S
TATISTA
(Jan. 7, 2020), https://www.statista.com/statistics/1020046/
global-fba-usage-top-amazon-sellers/.
1781
See, e.g., Submission from Source 43, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 30 (Oct. 26, 2019)
(on file with Comm.).
1782
F
EEDVISOR
, T
HE
2019 A
MAZON
C
ONSUMER
B
EHAVIOR
R
EPORT
10 (2019), https://
fv.feedvisor.com/CNl2019lAmazon-Consumer-Behavior-Report.html.
1783
Submission from Online Merchants Guild, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 7 (Oct. 23,
2019) (on file with Comm.).
logistics service. Amazon uses its dominance in each of these mar-
kets to strengthen and reinforce its position in the other.
Amazon’s FBA program combines warehousing, packing, and
shipping services, and most importantly, access to Prime cus-
tomers.
1775
For a seller’s products to get the Prime badge, which
is essential to making sales on the platform, a seller must either
qualify for Amazon’s Seller Fulfilled Prime (SFP) program or use
Amazon’s FBA service. On August 18, 2020, Amazon informed sell-
ers of changes to Seller Fulfilled Prime which render it an entirely
impractical option for most sellers.
1776
Even before this change,
only a very small percentage of sellers could meet the onerous eligi-
bility requirements for Seller Fulfilled Prime.
1777
This means FBA
is functionally the only way for sellers to get the Prime badge for
their product listings.
1778
A document setting forth draft Q&A be-
fore a 2018 earnings call for Amazon Chief Financial Officer Brian
Olsavsky explained the connection between Prime and FBA: ‘‘Prime
and FBA reinforce each other—they are inextricably linked. FBA
adds Prime eligible selection. Prime member growth and pur-
chasing habits attract sellers to FBA.’’
1779
Due to a lack of alternatives, third-party sellers have no choice
but to purchase fulfillment services from Amazon. More than 73
percent of all Marketplace sellers worldwide reportedly rely on
FBA services.
1780
Numerous third-party sellers told the Sub-
committee that they feel they have no choice but to pay for FBA
to maintain a favorable search result position, to reach Amazon’s
more than 112 million Prime members, and to win the Buy Box—
through which the vast majority of Amazon sales are made.
1781
A
recent consumer survey indicated that 75 percent of Amazon Prime
customers specifically search for products flagged as Prime-eligi-
ble.
1782
As a result, as the Online Merchant’s Guild told the Sub-
committee, many sellers will ‘‘say that without Prime you are
dead.’’
1783
In response to concerns about Amazon tying a seller’s ability to
make sales on its platform to participation in FBA, Amazon has of-
fered contradictory statements. In the Subcommittee’s second hear-
ing, Representative Lucy McBath (D–GA) asked Amazon’s Asso-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00247 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
242
1784
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 50 (question of Rep. Lucy McBath (D–GA),
Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judici-
ary).
1785
Id.
1786
Id. at 499 (response to Questions for the Record of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Com-
petition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1787
CEO Hearing at 161 (question of Rep. Mary Gay Scanlon (D–PA), Vice Chair, H. Comm.
on the Judiciary).
1788
Id. (statement of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1789
Id. at 282 (response to Questions for the Record of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1790
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00141750
(Mar. 25, 2010) (on file with Comm.).
1791
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00142724.
1793
Submission from Source 43, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 29 (Oct. 26, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1794
Id.
1795
Id.; see also Interview with Source 920 (July 14, 2020); Interview with Source 100 (July
24, 2020).
ciate General Counsel, Nate Sutton, whether Amazon ‘‘privilege[d]
vendors who use Amazon Fulfillment Services over those who chose
not to.’’
1784
Mr. Sutton asserted that Amazon ‘‘do[es] not favor . . .
products that use FBA over others.’’
1785
He also indicated that Ful-
fillment by Amazon is not a factor in Amazon’s ranking algo-
rithm.
1786
At the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Representative Mary Gay
Scanlon (D–PA) asked Mr. Bezos about whether there is a connec-
tion between a seller’s use of FBA and its ability to win the Buy
Box.
1787
In response, Mr. Bezos said, ‘‘I’m not sure if it’s direct,
but, indirectly, I think the Buy Box does favor products that can
be shipped with Prime.’’
1788
Given that FBA is effectively the only
way for sellers to get a Prime badge, this indicates that Amazon
does favor sellers who use FBA over those who do not for both its
search rankings and the Buy Box. Amazon claims that it favors
sellers who use FBA because it is in the best interest of consumers
and that it ‘‘does not consider profitability as part of the Featured
Merchant Algorithm.’’
1789
Documents reviewed by the Sub-
committee, however, suggest that Amazon has used profitability—
also referred to internally as ‘‘contribution profit’’ or ‘‘CP’’—as a
factor in awarding the Buy Box.
1790
Furthermore, Amazon’s own documents show that it has consid-
ered FBA participation for purposes of determining the Buy Box
winner.
1791
An Amazon document that sets forth pricing rules for
a pilot program appears to favor third-party sellers that use FBA
over those who do not for awarding the Buy Box.
One third-party seller provided the Subcommittee with anecdotal
evidence that Amazon favors sellers who participate in Amazon’s
fulfillment program over sellers who do not. The seller set up an
experiment where he sold the same product, one self-fulfilled and
the other fulfilled through FBA, and ran different test cases.
1793
The seller found that, ‘‘Even when the consumer price of the self-
fulfilled order was reduced and sold for a lower price (7% lower)
than the FBA offer, the FBA still ‘won’ the ‘Buy Box.’ ’’
1794
The
seller indicated that, without this favorable treatment for FBA,
they would not choose to use FBA, as they found Amazon’s fulfill-
ment service was often slower and less reliable than self-fulfill-
ment.
1795
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00248 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
243
1792
Prepared by the Subcommittee based on Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the
Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00141750 (Mar. 25, 2010) (on file with Comm.).
1796
CEO Hearing at 161 (statement of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1797
Interview with Source 89 (July 22, 2020).
1798
Interview with Source 149 (Feb. 26, 2020).
Internal Pricing Strategy Document
1792
Although Jeff Bezos told the Subcommittee that Fulfillment by
Amazon ‘‘is probably the greatest invention that we ever created
for sellers,’’ and that ‘‘it’s working for sellers,’’ information that the
Subcommittee reviewed suggests that it has significant short-
falls.
1796
One third-party seller told the Subcommittee, ‘‘We use
both FBA and self-fulfillment, [and] all of our negative comments
are on items shipped through FBA.’’
1797
According to another seller
that uses FBA, at one point, Amazon decided to change the pack-
aging on her products from cardboard boxes to padded envelopes,
causing damage to her products in transit. When the damaged
items started arriving at her customers’ homes in a damaged state,
this caused a surge of negative reviews and requests for returns.
When she asked Amazon to remove these bad reviews, which were
caused by FBA’s shipping methods, Amazon refused.
1798
A competing online marketplace described how Amazon’s effec-
tively forced-on-sellers FBA program makes it more difficult to
compete with Amazon for sellers, stating, ‘‘[T]hrough anticompeti-
tive strategies and practices by Amazon, many . . . sellers are being
pulled into Amazon’s tied marketplace-and-ecommerce-fulfilment
ecosystem in a manner that makes them not only less independent
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00249 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 22 here 11701.022
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
244
1799
Submission from Source 11, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 1 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1800
Id. at 2.
1801
See. e.g., Press Release, It. Competition Auth., Amazon: Investigation Launched on Pos-
sible Abuse of a Dominant Position in Online Marketplaces and Logistic Services (Apr. 15,
2019), https://en.agcm.it/en/media/press-releases/2019/4/A528 (announcing the launch of an
investigation into whether ‘‘Amazon would unduly exploit its dominant position in the market
for e-commerce platforms intermediary services in order to significantly restrict competition in
the e-commerce logistics market, as well as—potentially—in the e-commerce platform market,
to the detriment of final consumers’’).
1802
See, e.g., Shira Ovide, Amazon Advertising Is Just a Toll in Disguise, B
LOOMBERG
(July
15, 2019), https://www.bloomberg.com/opinion/articles/2019-07-15/amazon-advertising-is-just-
a-toll-in-disguise.
1803
F
EEDVISOR
, T
HE
2019 A
MAZON
C
ONSUMER
B
EHAVIOR
R
EPORT
5 (2019), https://
fv.feedvisor.com/CNl2019lAmazon-Consumer-Behavior-Report.html.
1804
F
EEDVISOR
, B
RANDS AND
A
MAZON IN THE
A
GE OF
E-C
OMMERCE
, 2020 E
DITION
12 (2020),
https://fv.feedvisor.com/CNl2020lBrands-and-Amazon-in-the-Age-of-E-Commerce.html.
1805
Id.
1806
S
TACY
M
ITCHELL
, R
ON
K
NOX &
Z
ACH
F
REED
, I
NST
.
OF
L
OCAL
S
ELF
-R
ELIANCE
, R
EPORT
:
A
MAZON
S
M
ONOPOLY
T
OLLBOOTH
9 (2020), https://ilsr.org/amazonsltollbooth/.
but directly dependent on Amazon.’’
1799
It further explained that,
because of Amazon’s dominance in online commerce, ‘‘Even sellers
who sell on other marketplaces are pushed into FBA, because it is
the only practicable way to obtain sales on the Amazon market-
place.’’
1800
In addition to the Subcommittee’s investigation, anti-
trust enforcement agencies are currently investigating Amazon for
tying these two services together.
1801
(b) Advertising. Consistent with public reporting,
1802
evidence
that the Subcommittee reviewed suggests that Amazon may re-
quire sellers to purchase their advertising services as a condition
of making sales on the platform. Because 44 percent of consumers
tend to only look through the first two search pages when shopping
on Amazon, a seller is practically invisible if it does not show up
on one of the first two pages.
1803
Amazon’s Sponsored Products and
Sponsored Brand tools allow sellers to ensure they are prioritized
in search results for specific key terms. A 2020 survey of large
brands found that at least 73 percent used Amazon’s advertising
services, with 65 percent spending at least $40,000 a month on ad-
vertising on the site.
1804
In just one year, the number of brands
with this monthly advertising spend increased by 33 percent.
1805
A
recent report issued by the Institute for Local Self-Reliance ex-
plained:
Sellers that decline to advertise risk losing their place in Amazon’s organic
search results, no matter how many glowing customer reviews they have. That’s
because the Amazon algorithm that delivers the search results favors products
with more sales. As more orders are driven by ads, sellers than don’t advertise
lose out on those sales and, as their share of sales declines, they also slip in the
search rankings, further reducing their sales in a negative cycle.
1806
Similarly, the Online Merchants Guild told the Subcommittee in
a submission, ‘‘[i]t is now common belief in the Amazon seller com-
munity that the only way to sell on Amazon is through Amazon’s
Pay-Per-Click (‘PPC’) offering.’’ The submission describes the situa-
tion as ‘‘pay-to-play,’’ adding that ‘‘[Pay-Per-Click advertising] has
become a major point of frustration for many sellers, with many
sellers left feeling as if they are paying a mandatory fee, and have
even described [Pay-Per-Click] as a way for Amazon to increase
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00250 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
245
1807
Submission from Online Merchants Guild, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 8 (Oct. 23,
2019) (on file with Comm.); see also Interview with Jason Boyce, Founder & CEO,
Avenue7Media, LLC (Sept. 15, 2020) (‘‘Pay-Per-Click is now mandatory.’’).
1808
Submission from Online Merchants Guild, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 8 (Oct. 23,
2019) (on file with Comm.).
1809
S
TACY
M
ITCHELL
, R
ON
K
NOX &
Z
ACH
F
REED
, I
NST
.
OF
L
OCAL
S
ELF
-R
ELIANCE
, R
EPORT
:
A
MAZON
S
M
ONOPOLY
T
OLLBOOTH
10 (2020), https://ilsr.org/amazonsltollbooth/.
1810
Interview with Jason Boyce, Founder & CEO, Avenue7Media, LLC (Sept. 15, 2020).
1811
Submission from Online Merchants Guild, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 8 (Oct. 23,
2019) (on file with Comm.).
1812
See, e.g., CEO Hearing at 131 (statement of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.) (‘‘I think
what you’re referring to is the fact that we offer an advertising service basically for third party
sellers to drive additional promotion to their products. That is a voluntary program. Some sell-
ers use it. Some don’t.’’).
1813
During the investigation, the Committee also heard concerns about Amazon using ‘‘brand
gating’’ to block competitors from selling certain products on its platform. See, e.g., Submission
from Source 5, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Sept. 15, 2020) (on file with Comm.) (raising con-
cerns about ‘‘brand gating,’’ which allows Amazon, on its own, or in concert with ‘‘a trademark
owner/manufacturer/seller, who is registered on the Brand Registry, to block other third party
sellers from selling a particular brand, unless certain conditions are met’’); Submission from
Source 100, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Jan. 10, 2020) (on file with Comm.) (raising concerns
that Amazon ‘‘gates’’ a brand when it decides that it wants to source items directly from the
manufacturer and limit competition from third-party sellers and stating, ‘‘[w]e have lost literally
millions of dollars on [inventory from] brands that Amazon has gated, purchases directly from
manufacturers and we are no longer able to sell on Amazon’’).
1814
Alexandra Berzon, Shane Shifflett & Justin Scheck, Amazon Has Ceded Control of Its
Site. The Result: Thousands of Banned, Unsafe or Mislabeled Products, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (Aug. 23,
2019), https://www.wsj.com/articles/amazon-has-ceded-control-of-its-site-the-result-thousands-
of-banned-unsafe-or-mislabeled-products-11566564990.
their seller fees without looking like they are increasing their seller
fees.’’
1807
At the same time that advertising services have become ‘‘less of
an option and more of a requirement for sellers to compete’’ on the
platform, Amazon’s ads have also become more expensive.
1808
The
ads’ costs are determined by reverse auction—businesses bid on
keywords that customers may use to search for a given product. In
just a year, ‘‘the cost-per-click for sponsored ads increased by about
15% on average,’’ and for some, by as much as 127 percent.
1809
A
former third-party seller told the Subcommittee that this harms
both sellers and consumers, adding that ‘‘those were the good old
days; before [Pay-Per-Click], products would rise on the mer-
its.’’
1810
Similarly, the Online Merchants Guild said, ‘‘[i]n the past,
the belief was more reviews would create a trending product.’’
1811
In response to concerns about tying, Amazon claims that it pro-
vides non-discriminatory access to the Buy Box and that participa-
tion in Fulfillment by Amazon and its Pay-Per-Click advertising
program is voluntary.
1812
Amazon’s revenue from these sources is
increasing, however, and sellers continue to raise concerns that in-
creased fees for compulsory fulfillment and advertising services are
squeezing their business.
(7) Strategic Platform Management and Mismanagement. During
the investigation, the Subcommittee also heard concerns that Ama-
zon engages in strategic mismanagement of its platform by: (1) al-
lowing the proliferation of counterfeit and unsafe goods; (2) using
its ability to control the flow of counterfeits as leverage; and (3)
putting in place ineffective counterfeit prevention tools that result
in the suspension of a large number of innocent sellers.
1813
As Amazon’s dominance in e-commerce has grown, so has the
proliferation of dangerous and counterfeit products on its market-
place.
1814
A 2019 Wall Street Journal investigation found that
Amazon had active listings for over 4,000 items ‘‘that have been de-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00251 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
246
1815
Id.
1816
Id.
1817
Blake Ellis & Melanie Hicken, Dozens of Amazon’s Own Products Have Been Reported
as Dangerous—Melting, Exploding or Even Bursting into Flames. Many Are Still on the Market,
CNN B
US
. (Sept. 10, 2020), https://www.cnn.com/2020/09/10/business/amazonbasics-
electronics-fire-safety-invs/index.html.
1818
Submission from Retail Industry Leaders Ass’n, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 9 (July
16, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
1819
Id.
1820
Competitors Hearing at 19–20 (statement of David Barnett, CEO & Founder, PopSockets
LLC); see also Laura Stevens & Sara Germano, Nike Thought It Didn’t Need Amazon—Then the
Ground Shifted, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (June 28, 2017), https://www.wsj.com/articles/how-nike-resisted-
amazons-dominance-for-years-and-finally-capitulated-1498662435.
1821
Jouzas Kaziukenas, Amazon’s Apple Moment, M
ARKETPLACE
P
ULSE
(Nov. 27, 2018),
https://www.marketplacepulse.com/articles/amazon-apple-moment.
1822
See Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00190195
(Feb. 15, 2018) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘We understand Apple’s IP team may not be happy with
elements of our anti-counterfeiting program.’’).
clared unsafe by federal agencies [and] are deceptively labeled or
are banned by federal regulators.’’
1815
In the worst cases, these
products have even caused bodily injury or even death to
unsuspecting consumers.
1816
As recently as September 2020, CNN
released a report describing multiple instances in which Amazon’s
own private-label products, such as a phone charging cable, have
caught fire while in use by consumers.
1817
The spread of counterfeit products also has serious consequences
for vendors and brand manufacturers who rely on their reputa-
tions, and consumer trust, to maintain successful businesses. Ama-
zon’s marketplace platform is designed in a way that makes it dif-
ficult for consumers to identify counterfeit products. As the Retail
Industry Leaders Association (RILA) noted in a submission to the
Subcommittee, ‘‘Where a platform both obfuscates the origin or
source and provides fulfillment services, a seller of counterfeits is
harder for consumers to uncover because the item appears to have
the backing of the platform.’’
1818
Although it claims to take its counterfeit problem seriously, Ama-
zon’s business model incentivizes it to do less, not more. Because
Amazon’s profits increase with the number of sales on the platform,
the company has an incentive to turn a blind eye to counterfeit
products that contribute to its increased sales volume. Regardless
of the source, more sales generally result in more profits for Ama-
zon because it typically ‘‘profits twice from a sale through purchase
and fulfillment[,] and potentially three times through adver-
tising.’’
1819
For example, the Subcommittee uncovered evidence during the
investigation that Amazon has used its ability to police counterfeits
more or less aggressively as leverage in contract negotiations with
brands who attempt to resist Amazon pressure to sell on its plat-
form—referred to internally at Amazon as ‘‘holdouts.’’
1820
This re-
cently occurred when it agreed to increase efforts to crack down on
counterfeit Apple products as part of Apple’s agreeing to establish
a wholesale relationship with Amazon Retail.
1821
Documents re-
ceived by the Subcommittee suggest that Apple was dissatisfied
with Amazon’s anti-counterfeiting program and sought the fol-
lowing as a condition of selling Apple products wholesale to Ama-
zon: ‘‘Amazon must proactively monitor platform for counterfeits/
knockoffs and cooperate with Apple to remove and prevent
them.’’
1822
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00252 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
247
1823
Competitors Hearing at 19–20 (statement of David Barnett, CEO & Founder, PopSockets
LLC).
1824
See, e.g., Press Release, Amazon, Amazon Establishes Counterfeit Crimes Unit to Bring
Counterfeiters to Justice (June 24, 2020), https://press.aboutamazon.com/news-releases/news-
release-details/amazon-establishes-counterfeit-crimes-unit-bring-counterfeiters.
1825
CEO Hearing at 131 (statement of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1826
See, e.g., Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–
00173394 (Sept. 6, 2016) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Additional gating requirements were put in
place to reduce counterfeit and improve product safety, but did not have the right processes in
place to limit the number of false negatives (declining Seller applications despite the seller’s
ability to provide the correct documentation).’’).
1827
Interview with Chris McCabe, Founder, ecommerceChris, LLC (June 12, 2020).
1828
Id.
1829
Submission from Source 100, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Sept. 18, 2020) (on file with
Comm.).
1830
Id.
At the Subcommittee’s field hearing in Colorado, PopSockets
founder David Barnett testified that ‘‘Amazon was aware that large
quantities’’ of counterfeit PopSockets products were selling on its
platform, but that Amazon allowed the problem to continue until
PopSockets agreed to spend nearly two million dollars on Amazon
marketing services.
1823
Mr. Barnett further testified that Amazon
was not just facilitating the sale of counterfeit PopSockets prod-
ucts, but that Amazon itself was engaged in selling knockoffs. Rep-
resentative Ken Buck (R–CO) and Representative Henry C. ‘‘Hank’’
Johnson, Jr. (D–GA) confronted Mr. Bezos on Amazon’s behavior
towards PopSockets at the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing. Mr.
Bezos responded, ‘‘if those are the facts and if someone somewhere
inside Amazon said, you know, ‘Buy X dollars in ads, and then we’ll
help you with your counterfeit problem,’ that is unacceptable. And
I will look into that, and we’ll get back to your office with that.’’
To date, however, Amazon has not followed up with the Sub-
committee to provide additional information.
In response to criticism and negative publicity about the pro-
liferation of counterfeit products on its platform, Amazon an-
nounced several initiatives to combat fake products.
1824
During the
Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Mr. Bezos testified that Amazon
‘‘invest[s] hundreds of millions of dollars in systems’’ that police
counterfeits.
1825
However, Amazon’s approach appears to be inef-
fective, resulting in suspensions of many innocent, third-party sell-
ers, with devastating effects on some sellers’ businesses.
1826
For example, the Subcommittee interviewed a former Amazon
employee and current consultant for Amazon sellers who described
recent unfair changes in Amazon’s treatment of sellers suspected
of being counterfeiters. He said that, in the past, Amazon would
only suspend accounts and withhold funds from third-party sellers
it confirmed were selling counterfeit goods.
1827
However, increas-
ingly, ‘‘Amazon rejects invoices or fails to verify suppliers without
any justification or basis as to why . . . and they are using that as
a reason to hold funds indefinitely.’’
1828
One third-party seller told the Subcommittee that Amazon
blocked some of her listings, citing a number of her products as
‘‘inauthentic.’’
1829
The seller provided evidence to Amazon that, not
only were her vendor’s products authentic, but Amazon actively
sold the same products, sourced from the same vendor, through its
first-party sales.
1830
Despite elevating the issue to Amazon execu-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00253 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
248
1831
Id.
1832
Submission from Source 17, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 9 (Nov. 15, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1833
Id. at 10.
1834
Interview with Source 155 (Sept. 29, 2020).
1835
Id.
1836
Letter from Maria A. Pallante, President & CEO, Ass’n of Am. Publishers, Mary E.
Rasenberger, Exec. Dir., Authors Guild, Allison K. Hill, CEO, Am. Booksellers Ass’n, to Hon.
David. N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.
Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Aug. 17, 2020), https://publishers.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/
08/Joint-Letter-to-Rep-Cicilline-081720.pdf.
1837
George Packer, Cheap Words, N
EW
Y
ORKER
(Feb. 10, 2014), https://www.newyorker.com/
magazine/2014/02/17/cheap-words (noting that, in 2007, the prices of e-books on Kindle were
‘‘below wholesale in some cases, and so low that [they] represented a serious threat to the mar-
ket .... By 2010, Amazon controlled ninety per cent of the market in digital books—a dominance
that almost no company, in any industry, could claim.’’).
tives in July 2020, this issue has still not been resolved as of Sep-
tember 2020.
1831
(ii) Most-Favored-Nation and Price Parity Provisions. Amazon
also uses its dominant position in e-commerce as leverage with
other businesses to require most-favored-nation (MFN) clauses or
similar price parity provisions to guarantee that it will always re-
ceive the best prices and most favorable terms. While these clauses
are not inherently anticompetitive, Amazon has a history of using
MFN clauses to ensure that none of its suppliers or third-party
sellers can collaborate with an existing or potential competitor to
make lower-priced or innovative product offerings available to con-
sumers.
The anticompetitive effects of Amazon’s use of MFN clauses are
particularly pronounced in the book market. According to a book
publisher, Amazon used its market power in print and e-book sales
to force a price MFN on it and other book publishers.
1832
As the
publisher explained, the result has been that ‘‘publishers are com-
pletely handcuffed from stimulating platform competition because
Amazon’s price MFN causes publishers to incur significant finan-
cial penalties if they offer Amazon’s rivals better pricing.’’
1833
An-
other publisher told the Subcommittee that ‘‘Amazon always has
and still does require MFNs.’’
1834
According to this publisher, the
MFN provisions prevent publishers from partnering with any of
Amazon’s competitors and reinforces Amazon’s ‘‘stranglehold’’ and
‘‘control’’ over book distribution.
1835
Although Amazon has changed
the name and specific mechanisms over the years, it appears that
the company continues to impose contract provisions that effec-
tively function as MFNs on book publishers.
In a joint letter to Subcommittee Chair Cicilline following the
Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, a group of organizations rep-
resenting authors, publishers, and booksellers wrote that Amazon’s
use of MFNs has ‘‘stifle[d] the emergence and growth of competitive
alternatives in the book distribution marketplace.’’
1836
When Ama-
zon entered the e-book market through its release of the Kindle
and Kindle Store in 2007, it unseated incumbent booksellers in
market position by offering steep discounts on best-selling
books.
1837
Over a decade later, Amazon’s dominance in e-books and
its anticompetitive application of price parity clauses to its busi-
ness relationships in this market ‘‘eliminate the ability of rivals or
new entrants to gain any meaningful competitive advantage rel-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00254 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
249
1838
Letter from Maria A. Pallante, President & CEO, Ass’n of Am. Publishers, Mary E.
Rasenberger, Exec. Dir., Authors Guild, Allison K. Hill, CEO, Am. Booksellers Ass’n, to Hon.
David. N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.
Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Aug. 17, 2020), https://publishers.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/
08/Joint-Letter-to-Rep-Cicilline-081720.pdf.
1839
Submission from Online Merchants Guild, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 7 (Oct. 29,
2019) (on file with Comm.).
1840
Id. at 8.
1841
Submission from Jason Boyce, Founder & CEO, Avenue7Media (Sept. 25, 2020) (on file
with Comm.).
1842
Submission from Source 11, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 4 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.); see also Submission from Jason Boyce, Founder & CEO, Avenue7Media (Sept. 25, 2020)
(on file with Comm.) (‘‘Amazon prohibiting sellers from offering lower prices on other online re-
tail platforms clearly hurts consumers if the only way for sellers to regain their listing on Ama-
zon is to raise their prices on other platforms or remove their listings all together, therefore
limiting competition.’’).
1843
Submission from Int’l Bhd. Of Teamsters, Commc’n Workers of Am., United Food & Com-
mercial Workers Int’l Union, Serv. Emps. Int’l Union & Change to Win, to H. Comm. on the
Judiciary, 4 (Mar. 10, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
1844
Saul Hansen, Technology; Amazon Reports First Full-Year Profit, N.Y. T
IMES
(Jan. 28,
2004), https://www.nytimes.com/2004/01/28/business/technology-amazon-reports-first-full-
year-profit.html.
ative to Amazon.’’
1838
Essentially, Amazon disrupted this market,
dominated it, and now wields its immense power to effectively
guarantee that no competitor could possibly do the same.
Amazon also aggressively enforces price parity rules on Amazon
Marketplace’s third-party sellers. It imposed MFN provisions on
U.S. sellers until 2019. In response to antitrust scrutiny, the plat-
form replaced those provisions with a ‘‘Fair Pricing Policy,’’ which
has the same effect of blocking sellers from offering lower prices to
consumers on other retail sites.
1839
To enforce the policy, Amazon
uses ‘‘computer software to regularly scan listings on competitors’
websites, and pressuring their sellers to change their price if their
Amazon price is substantially higher.’’
1840
A violation, or even a
perceived violation, of the policy can lead to suspension of a seller’s
account, with dire consequences for the seller. A former third-party
seller explained that Amazon uses ‘‘Buy Box Suppression,’’ where
Amazon will remove a seller’s ability to win the Buy Box, as a way
to penalize sellers that offer products at a lower price on competing
sites.
1841
One of Amazon’s competitors told the Subcommittee that, ‘‘as
Amazon raises the costs to sellers, and requires that Amazon have
the lowest prices available, for a seller to be able to make signifi-
cant sales on its marketplace, these sellers will raise the price on
competitor sites to match Amazon’s price.’’
1842
Amazon’s ‘‘Fair
Price Policy,’’ which has been described as a ‘‘thinly-veiled MFN re-
striction,’’ is likely anticompetitive with respect to blocking com-
petition from other marketplaces, and does not result in lower
prices for consumers as Amazon has claimed.
1843
(iii) Predatory Pricing. As part of its business strategy, Amazon
has historically placed a higher premium on long-term growth at
the expense of short-term profitability. As noted earlier in this Re-
port, Amazon did not post its first full-year profit until 2003—a
decade after the company was founded.
1844
Consistent with this
trend, Amazon has adopted a predatory-pricing strategy across
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00255 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
250
1845
In this Report, the term ‘‘predatory pricing’’ should be understood in its broadest sense
to refer to any situation where a dominant firm prices a good or service below cost in a way
that is harmful to competition.
1846
Submission from Source 91, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Sept. 22, 2020) (on file with
Comm.).
1847
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00216088 (Oct.
28, 2013) (on file with Comm.).
1848
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00068510 (Sept. 8, 2010).
1849
Id.; see also id. at AMAZON–HJC–00184863 (May 7, 2015) (‘‘The value differentiation for
Prime members accelerates the Prime flywheel creating an additional reason to become a Prime
member and concentrate household spend with Amazon.’’).
1850
See, e.g., Stu Woo, Amazon ‘‘Primes’’ Pump for Loyalty, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (Nov. 14, 2011),
http://www.wsj.com/articles/SB10001424052970203503204577036102353359784.
1851
Nanette Byrnes, How Amazon Loses on Prime and Still Wins, MIT T
ECH
. R
EV
. (July 12,
2016), https://www.technologyreview.com/2016/07/12/158869/how-amazon-loses-on-prime-
and-still-wins/ (last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
1852
J.P. M
ORGAN
, R
ETAIL VS
. A
MAZON
: L
IFE IN A
P
OST
COVID–19 W
ORLD
(2020), https://
markets.jpmorgan.com/research/email/-lbk68f4/Alp1kP9tQUPS29jlzWlbOg/GPS-3397412-0;
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00184863 (May 7,
2015) (on file with Comm.).
multiple business lines at various stages in the company’s his-
tory.
1845
Because of the nature of its marketplace business, Amazon’s
below-cost prices on products and services tend to lock customers
into Amazon’s full marketplace ecosystem. As a former Amazon
employee told the Subcommittee, ‘‘[A]bove all else, Amazon’s goal
is to keep the customer shopping on Amazon.’’
1846
Once a customer
is locked in, they are less likely to change their behavior even when
Amazon’s pricing is not competitive.
(1) Prime. The most prominent example of Amazon’s use of stra-
tegic losses to lock customers into the platform’s ecosystem is its
popular membership program, Amazon Prime. As of August 2020,
a Prime membership costs $119 per year, up from its original $79
at its launch in February 2005 and $99 from March 2014 to April
2018. An Amazon executive wrote in 2013, in reference to pricing
Prime, ‘‘the better course is to let the existing Prime program grow
. . . and then raise prices later assuming a lower elasticity in future
years,’’
1847
once customers are locked in.
An Amazon internal document describes the rationale behind
Amazon Prime and its other membership programs: ‘‘Membership
programs are created with a long-term, company-wide perspective
with the goal of increasing loyalty and cross-category shopping be-
havior. The programs do not optimize for short-term gain or profit-
ability in a single category.’’
1848
Another internal Amazon docu-
ment describes these membership programs as, ‘‘[d]oubl[ing] down
on ‘Big Moats,’ ’’ aiming to create an impenetrable barrier around
its dominant position.
1849
Despite Amazon Prime’s popularity and wide membership base,
it is a loss-leader for the company. Many industry analysts have es-
timated Amazon’s Prime losses over the years, finding that it is un-
profitable, and that Amazon is willing to spend significant amounts
of money to prop up the program.
1850
In 2016, a Forrester Re-
search analysis estimated that Prime costs Amazon $1 billion per
year.
1851
In 2019, J.P. Morgan estimated that, though priced at
$119, a Prime subscription is valued at about $860, up 10 percent
from its estimated value in 2018.
1852
A Prime membership also in-
cludes access to Prime Video, Amazon’s library of digital video con-
tent, and Amazon Music, its music streaming service.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00256 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
251
1853
Submission from Artist Rights Alliance, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (July 31, 2019)
(on file with Comm.).
1854
Id.
1855
Fareeha Ali, Amazon Prime Has 112 Million Members in the U.S., D
IG
. C
OMMERCE
360
(Jan. 24, 2020), https://www.digitalcommerce360.com/article/amazon-prime-membership/.
1856
Jack Houston & Irene Anna Kim, How Amazon Gets You to Spend More Money, B
US
. I
N
-
SIDER
(Sept. 17, 2020), https://www.businessinsider.com/amazon-prime-members-spend-more-
money-sneaky-ways-2019-9.
1857
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00130737 (Aug.
31, 2010) (on file with Comm.).
1858
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00159560 (Apr. 2010).
1859
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00035545 (July 20, 2010) (‘‘[W]e can see that Moms . . . have a fa-
vorable year one downstream value relative to the average customer.’’).
1860
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00154656.
1861
Submission from Source 11, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1862
Id. at 3.
The Artist Rights Alliance, an advocacy group for the digital
rights of music creators, raised concerns that Amazon’s inclusion of
a streaming music service in its Prime program poses a severe risk
of ‘‘driv[ing] down royalties in an uncompetitive way.’’
1853
Accord-
ing to its submission:
Amazon’s ongoing efforts to launch a streaming music service as part of its
Prime family of products should be carefully scrutinized .... [W]e are concerned
about the dangers of predatory/sub-market pricing in a service that Amazon op-
erates as a ‘‘loss leader.’’ In general, creators need an economy that more accu-
rately sees and values their work; not one with cut-rate prices that entangles
music even more deeply in a web of soulless data collection and ‘‘content dis-
tribution’’ operations.
1854
Although Amazon Prime is a loss-leader for the company, it is
one of Amazon’s most effective drivers of growth. Amazon Prime
members account for 65 percent of Amazon shoppers as of Q4
2019.
1855
While the average Amazon customer spends about $600
per year on Amazon.com, Prime members reportedly spend more
than double that—an average of $1400 per year.
1856
In 2010, Amazon started its Amazon Mom program, now called
Amazon Family, another membership service that offers discounts
on diapers and other items associated with parenthood.
1857
At the
outset, Amazon was willing to lose money to ensure the success of
this program. A 2010 document outlining the lead-up to the official
launch of Amazon Mom included a plan to discount diapers and
wipes at a rate that would ‘‘put [their] product below cost.’’
1858
And
selling diapers was not the goal of this program—instead Amazon
recognized that ‘‘a long-lasting, sticky relationship’’ with Amazon
Mom members was the source of its true value.
1859
Additionally, an
internal presentation observed that ‘‘[e]arly results from our Ama-
zon Mom program’’ showed that ‘‘[n]ew Amazon customers, whose
first purchase included diapers, spend over three times as much
($292 vs. $91) during their first year as the average new Amazon
customer.’’
1860
Some of Amazon’s rivals view this dynamic as harmful to com-
petition, saying that Amazon is ‘‘[u]nderpricing Prime to consumers
to build a huge and highly targetable share of ecommerce de-
mand.’’
1861
Once consumers have paid the yearly fee for Prime,
they are incentivized to use it as much as possible to maximize re-
turn on their investment, ‘‘whereas they might otherwise multi-
source.’’
1862
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00257 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
252
1863
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00151723 (Feb.
9, 2009) (on file with Comm.).
1864
CEO Hearing at 110 (statement of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1865
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00132026
(June 8, 2010) (on file with Comm.).
1866
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00151722 (Feb. 9, 2009).
1867
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00057007 (Apr. 5, 2010).
1868
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00009716 (Sept. 21, 2010).
1869
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00009596 (Nov. 2, 2010).
1870
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00142833 (May 12, 2009).
1871
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00167480.
1872
Laura Stevens, Sharon Terlep & Annie Gasparro, Amazon Targets Unprofitable Items,
with a Sharper Focus on the Bottom Line, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (Dec. 16, 2018), https://www.wsj.com/
articles/amazon-targets-unprofitable-items-with-a-sharper-focus-on-the-bottom-line-11544965201.
(2) Diapers.com. The Amazon Mom program served another im-
portant function and had a central role in one of Amazon’s early
applications of its predatory-pricing strategy. In 2009, Bezos and
other Amazon executives noticed and began discussing the rise of
Diapers.com, a competitor in the baby and personal-care product
markets.
1863
What followed was a year-long price war, ending in
Amazon’s eventual acquisition of Quidsi, the parent company of
Diapers.com.
At the Subcommittee’s hearing, Mr. Bezos testified that Amazon
was always a price follower in its war with Diapers.com.
1864
How-
ever, Amazon’s ‘‘ ‘plan to win’ against [D]iapers.com’’ explicitly in-
cluded price-leading on diapers.
1865
Recognizing that Diapers.com
was the company’s ‘‘#1 short term competitor,’’ Amazon executives
decided that going after them required a ‘‘need to match pricing . . .
no matter what the cost.’’
1866
Amazon internal documents indicate
that Amazon was willing to lose $200 million in one month alone
on products in the relevant competitive categories.
1867
Offering 30
percent cash back on diapers and a free year’s worth of Prime
membership to Amazon Mom members, an Amazon executive pre-
dicted in November 2010 that it would seriously wound Quidsi,
stating, ‘‘[T]hey expect to lose lots of money over the nxt [sic] few
yrs [sic]—this will make it worse.’’
1868
Quidsi explicitly identified
‘‘Predatory Pricing’’ as a ‘‘Near-Term Risk’’ in a 2009 presen-
tation.
1869
In November 2010, Amazon acquired its self-described
‘‘largest and fastest growing competitor in the on-line diaper and
baby care space.’’
1870
(3) ‘‘Can’t Realize Any Profit’’. Once Amazon succeeds in trapping
enough customers in its ‘‘flywheel’’ to secure dominant position
across varied markets, it can then raise prices or remove incentives
or allowances for Marketplace sellers to sell products at favorable
prices for consumers. One example of the latter is Amazon’s treat-
ment of ‘‘CRAP,’’ a term coined internally which refers to products
on which Amazon ‘‘Can’t Realize Any Profit.’’
1871
CRAP products
are low-priced items that are heavy and expensive to ship—often
consumables, like packs of bottled water.
1872
These items were integral to Amazon’s pursuit of dominance in
the e-commerce market. But once Amazon began to switch its focus
from pure growth to profitability, it reversed course on these prod-
ucts, engaging in an ongoing ‘‘CRAP-Out Process,’’ by which Ama-
zon attempts to make CRAP profitable through a variety of meth-
ods, such as raising delivery fees or requiring vendors to repackage
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00258 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
253
1873
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00167484 (on
file with Comm.) (‘‘How to deal with CRAP.’’).
1874
Id.
1875
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–0014302 (Sept. 30, 2010).
1876
Id.
1877
Submission from Source 38, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 19 (Sept. 1, 2019) (citing
T
ECH
I
NSIGHTS
).
1878
Id.; see also Samantha Gordon, Prime Day Is Almost Over—These Are the Best Deals You
Can Still Get, USA T
ODAY
(July 15, 2019), https://www.usatoday.com/story/tech/reviewedcom/
2019/07/15/prime-day-2019-best-amazon-deals-you-can-get-during-massive-sale/1683589001/
(‘‘Echo Dot—$22.’’).
1879
Sean Hollister, Amazon Doesn’t Sell Echo Speakers at a Loss, Says Bezos—Unless They’re
on Sale, V
ERGE
(July 29, 2020), https://www.theverge.com/2020/7/29/21347121/amazon-echo-
speaker-price-undercut-rivals-loss-sale-antitrust-hearing.
1880
Competitors Hearing at 12–13 (statement of Patrick Spence, CEO, Sonos, Inc.).
1881
CEO Hearing at 123 (question of Rep. Jamie Raskin (D–MD), Member, Subcomm. on
Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
products.
1873
This increases costs for sellers and brands, who have
no choice but to acquiesce to the changed shipping and packaging
rules given their dependence on Amazon for e-commerce sales.
Amazon executives acknowledged that CRAP was an element of its
plan for growth, noting in a strategy session that, ‘‘We want to en-
sure that if despite all our efforts to improve our cost structure, we
lose money on an ASIN [Amazon Standard Identification Number]
it is for the long term strategic growth of Amazon.’’
1874
Amazon documents provided in response to the Committee’s re-
quests show the extent to which Amazon was committed to below-
cost pricing. A 2010 review of its baby formula business identified
Amazon’s ‘‘most frequently matched internal competitor’’ as
ABCBabyFormula, which ‘‘typically [ ] price[d] 15–20% below [Ama-
zon’s] cost.’’
1875
Identifying this company as the most significant
influence on Amazon’s baby formula profit loss, the document notes
of ABCBabyFormula that ‘‘[m]anufacturers do not sell to them di-
rectly and believe they are sourcing black market stolen goods.’’
1876
Amazon frequently price-matched, at significantly below cost, a
competitor that it had reason to believe was sourcing baby formula
from illegal and potentially dangerous sources—indicating the
lengths to which Amazon was willing to go to ensure product selec-
tion and, in turn, growth.
(4) Amazon Devices. Finally, Amazon sells its own branded hard-
ware devices on its Marketplace and has often priced those devices
below cost in an attempt to corner the market for those devices and
adjacent markets. In Amazon’s effort to ‘‘own the smart home,’’ for
example, Amazon sometimes prices its Echo Speaker below cost.
Market estimates suggest that Amazon’s Echo Dot third generation
materials cost is $37.68,
1877
while the company listed it at $22 dur-
ing its 2019 Prime Day.
1878
Other market research of Amazon
products found that Amazon Echo products are on sale as often as
they are at full price.
1879
Illustrating how low prices may not al-
ways be in consumers’ best interest, Patrick Spence, the CEO of
Sonos, testified before the Subcommittee that these pricing habits
‘‘hamstring[] those companies that have better products that can-
not be sold at a loss.’’
1880
At the Subcommittee’s hearing, Rep-
resentative Jamie Raskin (D–MD) raised this concern with Mr.
Bezos.
1881
In response, Mr. Bezos responded that the Amazon Echo
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00259 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
254
1882
Id. at 124 (statement of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1883
See Fulfillment by Amazon Usage Among Top Sellers Worldwide 2017–2018, S
TATISTA
,
https://www.statista.com/statistics/1020046/global-fba-usage-top-amazon-sellers/ (last visited
Oct. 4, 2020).
1884
Submission from Online Merchants Guild, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 8 (Oct. 23,
2019) (on file with Comm.).
1885
Fill Orders from Other Sales Channels (Multi-Channel Fulfillment), A
MAZON
S
ELLER
C
ENT
., https://sellercentral.amazon.com/gp/help/external/200332450 (last visited Oct. 4, 2020)
(explaining that ‘‘Multi-Channel Fulfillment (MCF) is a program within Fulfillment by Amazon
(FBA),’’ that fills orders from sales channels placed on sites other than Amazon.com).
1886
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 515 (response to Questions for the Record
of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1887
Press Release, Amazon, Continued Growth for Amazon’s Air Network (June 28, 2019),
https://press.aboutamazon.com/news-releases/news-release-details/continued-growth-amazons-
air-network-expand-prime-fast-free.
1888
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 515 (response to Questions for the Record
of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1889
Press Release, Amazon, Continued Growth for Amazon’s Air Network (June 28, 2019),
https://press.aboutamazon.com/news-releases/news-release-details/continued-growth-amazons-
air-network-expand-prime-fast-free.
1890
I
NST
.
FOR
L
OCAL
S
ELF
-R
ELIANCE
, A
MAZON
S
M
ONOPOLY
T
OLLBOOTH
8 (2020), https://
cdn.ilsr.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/07/ILSRlReportlAmazon TollboothlFinal.pdf.
1891
Id.
is ‘‘often on promotion, and sometimes when it’s on promotion it
may be below cost.’’
1882
3. Fulfillment and Delivery
(a) Market Power. As Amazon’s e-commerce business has grown,
it has also developed a significant logistics business surrounding
fulfillment and delivery of third-party orders with its Fulfillment
by Amazon (FBA) program. More than 73 percent of all Amazon
Marketplace sellers reportedly rely on this program to fulfill their
orders.
1883
Because of this, a trade association that represents
third-party sellers refers to Amazon’s fulfillment operation ‘‘as the
railroad of [e-commerce].’’
1884
In addition to its fulfillment oper-
ation, Amazon is also one of the largest shippers in the world. The
company provides global shipping services for its own products and
independent sellers that sell on Amazon.com, as well as other e-
commerce sites.
1885
Amazon’s ground shipping infrastructure consists of ‘‘trucks,
trailers, intermodal containers, and delivery vehicles.’’
1886
Its
truck fleet consists of more than 10,000 trailers.
1887
It also has its
own freight airline, Amazon Air, with about 50 leased aircrafts,
1888
and plans to expand its fleet to 70 by 2021.
1889
Amazon has also
built hundreds of package sorting and delivery centers across the
United States and has established its own network of contracted
delivery providers exclusively dedicated to delivering packages for
Amazon.
1890
In recent years, the size and scope of Amazon’s delivery services
network have grown significantly. When Amazon first launched
Fulfillment by Amazon, it stored products and packed orders in its
warehouses, but relied on other carriers to handle shipping and de-
livery. Today, Amazon ships a growing number of products itself.
In 2019, ‘‘Amazon delivered about half of its own packages, up from
15 percent just two years before.’’
1891
Amazon has also lessened its
use of large delivery companies during this time, using ‘‘800 small,
independent contractors [which] are now responsible for around 48
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00260 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
255
1892
Submission from Int’l Bhd. of Teamsters, Commc’n Workers of Am., United Food & Com-
mercial Workers Int’l Union, Serv. Emps. Int’l Union & Change to Win, to H. Comm. on the
Judiciary, 13 (Mar. 10, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
1893
Id. at 14.
1894
I
NST
.
FOR
L
OCAL
S
ELF
-R
ELIANCE
, A
MAZON
S
M
ONOPOLY
T
OLLBOOTH
8 (2020), https://
cdn.ilsr.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/07/ILSRlReportlAmazon TollboothlFinal.pdf.
1895
Rachel Premack, Amazon Is Piling Up Fulfillment Center Square Footage, and It Shows
Bezos Thinks the Pandemic-Driven Online Shopping Surge Is Here to Stay, B
US
. I
NSIDER
: M
KTS
.
(July 31, 2020), https://markets.businessinsider.com/news/stocks/amazon-fulfillment-center-
growth-reveals-pandemic-online-ordering-surge-2020-7-1029456709# (last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
1896
I
NST
.
FOR
L
OCAL
S
ELF
-R
ELIANCE
, A
MAZON
S
M
ONOPOLY
T
OLLBOOTH
8 (2020), https://
cdn.ilsr.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/07/ILSRlReportlAmazon TollboothlFinal.pdf.
1897
Id.
1898
Submission from Int’l Bhd. Of Teamsters, Commc’n Workers of Am., United Food & Com-
mercial Workers Int’l Union, Serv. Emps. Int’l Union & Change to Win. to H. Comm. on the
Judiciary, 12 (Mar. 10, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
1899
What Amazon Does to Wages, E
CONOMIST
(Jan. 20, 2018), https://www.economist
.com/united-states/2018/01/20/what-amazon-does-to-wages.
1900
See, e.g., Colin Lecher, How Amazon Automatically Tracks and Fires Warehouse Workers
for ‘‘Productivity,’’ V
ERGE
(Apr. 25, 2019), https://www.theverge.com/2019/4/25/18516004/
amazon-warehouse-fulfillment-centers-productivity-firing-terminations.
1901
What Amazon Does to Wages, E
CONOMIST
(Jan. 20, 2018), https://www.economist
.com/united-states/2018/01/20/what-amazon-does-to-wages.
percent of Amazon’s last mile deliveries.’’
1892
These smaller pro-
viders are economically dependent on Amazon, and ‘‘many are in
fact reliant on Amazon for 100 percent of their business.’’
1893
Parcel volume handled by Amazon’s delivery service now rivals
the top carriers, including UPS, FedEx, and the U.S. Postal Serv-
ice. ‘‘In 2019, Amazon delivered 2.5 billion parcels, or about one-
fifth of all e-commerce deliveries,’’
1894
and anticipates growth. In
a July 2020 investor call, Amazon CFO Brian Olsavsky stated that
Amazon ‘‘expect[s] a meaningfully higher year-over-year square
footage growth of approximately 50%,’’ which includes ‘‘strong
growth in new fulfillment center space as well as sort centers and
delivery stations.’’
1895
An analysis by Morgan Stanley concluded that Amazon will over-
take UPS and FedEx in market share for delivery by 2022. Amazon
has already surpassed the U.S. Postal Service, which has been
downsized dramatically under its current leadership.
1896
Last year,
the U.S. Postal Service had a decrease in parcel volume for the
first time in nearly a decade.
1897
(b) Monopsony Power. Amazon exercises monopsony power in
labor markets directly and indirectly. As one of the largest employ-
ers in America, Amazon exercises direct power over hundreds of
thousands of workers across the United States.
1898
Amazon em-
ployees make up 22 percent of the U.S. labor market in
warehousing and storage, excluding seasonal workers.
1899
There
has been a growing amount of public reporting in recent years re-
garding Amazon’s treatment of warehouse employees, including
strenuous working conditions, unforgiving packing and sorting
quotas, and unfair firings.
1900
Amazon warehouses also have a
tendency to depress wages when they enter a local labor market.
For example, since Amazon opened a warehouse in Lexington
County, South Carolina in 2011, the county has seen average an-
nual wages for warehouse workers fall more than 30 percent, from
$47,000 to $32,000 annually.
1901
Indirectly, Amazon has wage-setting power through its ability to
set route fees and other fixed costs for independent contractors in
localities in which it dominates the delivery labor market. These
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00261 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
256
1902
Submission from Int’l Bhd. Of Teamsters, Commc’n Workers of Am., United Food & Com-
mercial Workers Int’l Union, Serv. Emps. Int’l Union & Change to Win, to H. Comm. on the
Judiciary, 14 (Mar. 10, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
1903
Id.
1904
Id. at 13.
1905
Sebastian Herrera, Amazon to Keep Most of the Jobs It Added During Pandemic, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (May 28, 2020), https://www.wsj.com/articles/amazon-to-keep-most-of-the-jobs-it-added-
during-pandemic-11590661802.
1906
See, e.g., Chris Welch, Amazon Just Surprised Everyone with a Crazy Speaker that Talks
to You, V
ERGE
(Nov. 6, 2014), https://www.theverge.com/2014/11/6/7167793/amazon-echo-
speaker-announced; Nick Statt, Amazon Wants Alexa to Be the Operating System for Your Life,
V
ERGE
(Sept. 27, 2018), https://www.theverge.com/2018/9/27/17911300/amazon-alexa-echo-
smart-home-eco-system-competition.
1907
See supra Section IV.
1908
Amazon Lab126, A
MAZON
J
OBS
, https://amazon.jobs/en/teams/lab126/ (last visited
Sept. 29, 2020).
1909
See Johanna Ambrosio, Amazon Smart Devices to Expand in Homes and Businesses,
T
ECH
T
ARGET
(Mar. 23, 2020), https://searchaws.techtarget.com/feature/Amazon-smart-devices-
to-expand-in-homes-and-businesses.
1910
Echo Frames—Eyeglasses with Alexa—Black—A Day 1 Editions Product, A
MAZON
,
https://www.amazon.com/dp/B07W72XKPJ. See also AmazonBasics Microwave, Small, 0.7 Cu.
Ft., 700–W, Works with Alexa, A
MAZON
, https://www.amazon.com/dp/B07894S727 (last visited
Sept. 29, 2020).
entities are dependent on Amazon for a large majority—or even
100 percent—of their delivery business.
1902
As a result, they have
little choice but to ‘‘submit to Amazon’s prices and other
terms.’’
1903
Amazon’s dominance also enables it to compel logistics
employees to quit their jobs and instead act as independent con-
tractors, removing employment protections. A group of labor unions
stated in their submission to the Subcommittee, ‘‘By virtue of its
size and power as a buyer of delivery services, Amazon can impose
monopolistic restraints on the treatment of workers within its sup-
ply chain while, at the same time, avoiding legal responsibility for
their fair treatment.’’
1904
Despite the loss of jobs and economic activity in the wake of the
COVID–19 pandemic, Amazon’s monopsony power has likely in-
creased. In response to higher demand for goods and services, Ama-
zon hired 175,000 temporary workers in March and April of 2020,
making 125,000 of those jobs permanent in May 2020.
1905
4. Alexa’s Internet of Things Ecosystem
(a) Overview. Amazon has significant investments in the Internet
of Things ecosystem, centering its strategy around Amazon’s voice
assistant, Alexa. In 2014, Amazon launched the Alexa-enabled
Echo smart speaker.
1906
Since then, Amazon has built the largest
ecosystem of devices and applications connected to the Internet of
Things,
1907
creating a broad portfolio of services, development
tools, and devices for its Alexa platform. Amazon’s research and de-
velopment team, Lab126, leads the development of Amazon’s Inter-
net of Things hardware expansion, including the development of
Amazon Echo and Fire TV.
1908
These devices represent a ‘‘critical
touchpoint that generates insights into user behavior, which can
then be used to deepen the relationship with consumers and expose
them to new products through personalized recommendations.’’
1909
Amazon encourages consumers to use Alexa through its Echo smart
speakers and other Alexa compatible devices, ranging from smart
microwaves to its Echo Frames.
1910
In 2015, Amazon launched a kit for independent developers to
access Alexa in the cloud and create new Alexa apps, which Ama-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00262 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
257
1911
David Isbitski, Introducing the Alexa Skills Kit, Enabling Developers to Create Entirely
New Voice Driven Capabilities, A
MAZON
D
EV
. (June 25, 2015), https://developer
.amazon.com/blogs/post/Tx205N9U1UD338H/Introducing-the-Alexa-Skills-Kit-Enabling-Devel-
opers-to-Create-Entirely-New-Voic.
1912
Satish Iyer, Introducing the Alexa Voice Service Device SDK for Commercial Device Mak-
ers, A
MAZON
A
LEXA
(Aug. 17, 2017), https://developer.amazon.com/blogs/alexa/post/7a72f14e-
66d6-42fb-b369-c60af364489a/introducing-the-alexa-voice-service-avs-device-sdk-for-commercial-
device-makers.
1913
What Are Alexa Built-in Devices?, A
MAZON
A
LEXA
, https://developer.amazon.com/en-US/
alexa/devices/alexa-built-in (last visited Sep. 29, 2020).
1914
Works with Alexa Program, A
MAZON
A
LEXA
, https://developer.amazon.com/en-US/alexa/
connected-devices/launch/works-with-alexa (last visited Sept. 29, 2020).
1915
Class Action Complaint at 8, B.F. v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. 2:19–cv–910 (W.D. Wash.
June 11, 2019).
1916
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00200464 (July
26, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
1917
Id.
1918
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 536 (response to Questions for the Record
of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1919
Daniel Newman, Opinion, Amazon’s Alexa Is About to Become Even More of a Fixture in
Our Lives, M
ARKET
W
ATCH
(Sept. 30, 2019), https://www.marketwatch.com/story/amazons-
alexa-is-about-to-become-even-more-of-a-fixture-in-our-lives-2019-09-27.
1920
See supra Section IV.
1921
Submission from Source 38, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 7 (Sept. 1, 2019).
zon refers to as ‘‘skills.’’
1911
Two years later, in an effort to expand
its ecosystem of devices, Amazon launched Alexa Voice Service.
This suite of services allows manufacturers of hardware with
microphones and speakers to receive and respond to Alexa voice
commands, making the device ‘‘Alexa-enabled,’’
1912
or ‘‘Alexa built-
in.’’
1913
Additionally, Amazon oversees Works with Alexa, an
Alexa-compatible device certification program for devices that re-
ceive commands through an Alexa-enabled device, such as a smart
speaker.
1914
Amazon does not charge third-party device manufac-
turers for access to its integration services, which promotes rapid
adoption of Alexa in a larger number of devices, which, in turn,
drives greater adoption by consumers.
1915
These programs indicate that Amazon is focused on expanding
Alexa’s reach rather than short-term profitability, consistent with
the early stages of its marketplace strategy. Amazon CFO Brian
Olsavsky confirmed this in an earnings call in July 2019, saying
that the company’s ‘‘emphasis is around expanding the reach of
Alexa and the usefulness.’’
1916
He added that, at the time, Alexa
had ‘‘over 45,000 skills’’ and was in ‘‘over 13,000 smart home de-
vices from 2,500 unique brands.’’
1917
Lastly, Amazon’s Alexa ecosystem is a major source of consumer
data; it tracks if the home owner’s lights are off and the events on
their calendar.
1918
Amazon is also building a series of devices that
allow people to have ‘‘Alexa in [their] ears, on [their] eyes, and
around [their] fingers.’’
1919
(b) Market Power. Amazon’s Alexa represents one of three emerg-
ing voice assistant platforms domestically, along with Google As-
sistant and Apple’s Siri, but has a more expansive collection of in-
tegrated devices and voice applications than its competitors.
1920
The Echo collection of smart speakers—the hub of Alexa’s eco-
system—captures over 60 percent of the smart speaker market in
the U.S.
1921
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00263 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
258
1922
Kyle Wiggers, The Alexa Skills Store Now Has More than 100,000 Voice Apps,
V
ENTURE
B
EAT
(Sept. 25, 2019), https://venturebeat.com/2019/09/25/the-alexa-skills-store-now-
has-more-than-100000-voice-apps/.
1923
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00200465 (July
26, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
1924
H. Tankovska, Total Number of Amazon Alexa Skills in Selected Countries as of January
2020, S
TATISTA
(Aug. 27, 2020), https://www.statista.com/statistics/917900/selected-countries-
amazon-alexa-skill-count/722/worldwide-google-action-disappearance-by-language.
1925
Shanhong Liu, Number of Google Assistant Actions Worldwide 2019, by Language,
S
TATISTA
(June 17, 2020), https://www.statista.com/statistics/1062.
1926
Build the Future of the Connected Home with AWS IoT and Amazon Alexa, Amazon Web
Servs., https://aws.amazon.com/iot/solutions/connected-home/iot-and-alexa/ (last visited Sept.
29, 2020).
1927
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00172104
(Mar. 9, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
1928
Submission from Source 39, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 39–00000098, at 19
(Sept. 16, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
1929
See infra Appendix.
1930
Sam Byford, Amazon Acquires Yap, Move into Speech Recognition?, V
ERGE
(Nov. 9, 2011),
https://www.theverge.com/2011/11/9/2550764/amazon-acquires-yap-speech-recognition-siri.
1931
Emma Bryce, How Amazon’s Alexa Was ‘‘Born’’ and Where Voice-Controlled Tech Will
Take Us Next, W
IRED
(Feb. 14, 2017), https://www.wired.co.uk/article/amazon-alexa-ai-evi.
As of September 2019, there were 85,000 Works with Alexa de-
vices available for consumers to purchase.
1922
The current network
of Alexa-enabled devices includes companies like Sonos, Hewlett-
Packard, and BMW.
1923
The U.S.-based Alexa Skills Store as of
January 2020 includes 70,729 skills.
1924
In comparison, as of De-
cember 2019, Google’s voice application ecosystem had just over
18,826 Google Actions.
1925
The voice assistant market has strong entry barriers due to the
significant investments required to compete in the market. These
include investments in artificial intelligence, voice-enabled hard-
ware, and cloud computing infrastructure, which are critical inputs
Amazon has been developing for years. Amazon’s Alexa Voice Serv-
ice is also hosted on Amazon Web Services, allowing it to bind
products and developers to its cloud platform.
1926
In turn, this rela-
tionship gives Amazon a potential head-start on turning its Alexa
business partners into customers through the cross-sale of Amazon
Web Services and other Amazon products and services down the
line.
Voice assistants collect significant amounts of personal data and
learn users’ preferences over time. For example, when Alexa users
add more devices that integrate with Alexa, they often manage the
settings for these devices through mobile applications and websites
that are tied to their Amazon credentials, thereby creating a robust
user profile.
1927
As Amazon continues to expand Alexa’s reach, this
customization of features allows Amazon to better ‘‘understand’’ its
users, which may affect their willingness to retrain a new voice as-
sistant.
1928
In addition to the cost of replacing their devices, this
friction—retraining a new voice assistant—may increase costs asso-
ciated with switching to another voice assistant ecosystem.
(c) Merger Activity. Amazon has expanded its voice assistant eco-
system by acquiring artificial intelligence companies to strengthen
Alexa’s functionality and voice-enabled device manufacturers to ex-
pand Alexa’s reach.
1929
In 2011, Amazon acquired Yap, a speech
recognition platform.
1930
The next year, in 2012, Amazon acquired
Evi, a technology for understanding natural language.
1931
Over the
years, Amazon has continued to acquire other businesses engaged
in natural language processing, machine learning, and other re-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00264 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
259
1932
See infra Appendix.
1933
Paresh Dave, Amazon Acquires Santa Barbara Start-Up Graphiq to Try to Bolster Alexa,
L.A. T
IMES
(July 20, 2017), https://www.latimes.com/business/technology/la-fi-tn-graphiq-
amazon-20170719-story.html.
1934
Id.
1935
Jacob Kastrenakes, Amazon Buys Smart Camera and Doorbell Startup Blink, V
ERGE
(Dec. 22, 2017), https://www.theverge.com/circuitbreaker/2017/12/22/16810516/amazon-
blink-acquisition-smart-camera-doorbell-company; see also Samuel Gibbs, Amazon Buys Video
Doorbell Firm Ring for Over $1bn, G
UARDIAN
(Feb. 28, 2018), https://www.theguardian
.com/technology/2018/feb/28/amazon-buys-video-doorbell-ring-smart-home-delivery.
1936
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00169702
(Mar. 9, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
1937
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00170877 (Oct. 11, 2017).
1938
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00173560 (Dec. 15, 2017).
1939
CEO Hearing at 124 (question of Rep. Jamie Raskin (D–MD), Member, Subcomm. on
Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
1940
Id. (statement of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.).
lated technologies in support of its continued efforts to improve
Alexa’s artificial intelligence functionality.
1932
One of Amazon’s strategic goals for Alexa has been to use its
voice assistant to reinforce the company’s dominance in e-commerce
and strengthen its presence in offline retail. In 2017, Amazon ac-
quired Graphiq, a technology company that collects and organizes
details about ‘‘products, places, and people to simplify online re-
search.’’
1933
This acquisition appears to have been part of Ama-
zon’s effort to improve Alexa’s overall search capabilities, most no-
tably product search, as the technology includes ‘‘features to tailor
comparisons around individual preferences.’’
1934
In 2017, Amazon purchased Blink, followed by Ring in 2018—
both to solidify its position in the home security market.
1935
In an
internal document, Amazon recognized that security could ‘‘feed our
flywheels (Prime, Alexa) while being a large, profitable business in
its own right.’’
1936
Prior to these acquisitions Jeff Helbling, Vice
President at Amazon, emailed a group of Amazon executives, recap-
ping a discussion on the transactions he had with Mr. Bezos.
There, he detailed the twin justification for the acquisitions, saying
that ‘‘two senses matter—eyes and ears.’’
1937
Amazon had already
locked down ‘‘ears’’ through its continued development of Alexa.
Ring and Blink would act as Amazon’s ‘‘eyes’’ right outside the
home.
Amazon’s internal documents show that, in large part, it pur-
chased Ring to capture the company’s share of the smart home se-
curity market. In December 2017, Mr. Bezos wrote to Dave Limp,
the Senior Vice President of Devices & Services, that Amazon was
really ‘‘buying market position’’ by acquiring Ring.
1938
During the
Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Representative Jamie Raskin (D–
MD) asked Mr. Bezos about this exchange.
1939
Mr. Bezos re-
sponded:
Sir, market position is valuable in almost any business, and it’s one of the pri-
mary things that one would look at in an acquisition. There are multiple reasons
that we might buy a company. Sometimes we’re trying to buy some technology
or some IP. Sometimes it’s a talent acquisition. But the most common case is
market position, that the company has traction with customers, they’ve built a
service, maybe they were the first mover. There could be any number of reasons
why they have that market position. But that’s a very common reason to acquire
a company.
1940
This response suggests that adding Ring’s users to the Alexa eco-
system quickly was also important to Amazon’s rationale.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00265 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
260
1941
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00169706
(Mar. 9, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
1942
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00170869 (Nov. 1, 2017).
1943
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00169706 (Mar. 9, 2018); Alexa.DoorbellEventSource Interface,
A
MAZON
A
LEXA
, https://developer.amazon.com/en-US/docs/alexa/device-apis/alexa-doorbell
eventsource.html (last visited Sept. 30, 2020).
1944
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00172104
(Mar. 9, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
1945
Lisa Eadicicco & Alexei Oreskovic, Amazon Paid $97 Million to Acquire Eero in a Fire
Sale Deal that Left Some Shareholders with Practically Nothing, According to Leaked Docu-
ments, B
US
. I
NSIDER
(Apr. 5, 2019), https://www.businessinsider.com/amazon-paid-97-million-
to-acquire-eero-in-fire-sale-leaked-documents-2019-4.
1946
See Lisa Eadicicco, A Year After Selling to Amazon for $1 Billion, the Chief Inventor of
the Ring Video Doorbell Explains How He’s Bringing His Entrepreneurial Spirit to the Online
Retailer, B
US
. I
NSIDER
(Apr. 9, 2019), http://static7.businessinsider.com/ring-founder-jamie-
siminoff-life-after-amazon-acquisition-2019-4 (quoting Jamie Siminoff, Founder of Ring, describ-
ing the importance of Eero and his support of Amazon’s acquisition, ‘‘[Ring is] a product that
requires great Wi-Fi connectivity. We use a lot of bandwidth so we we’re certainly very sensitive
to Wi-Fi networks.’’).
1947
Amazon Frustration-Free Setup Frequently Asked Questions, A
MAZON
, https://www
.amazon.com/gp/help/customer/display.html?nodeId=GMPKVYDBR223TRPY (last visited Oct.
4, 2020).
1948
Legal: Privacy Policy for Eero Devices, Applications and Services, E
ERO
, https://
eero.com/legal/privacy (last visited Sept. 29, 2020); Legal: Privacy Policy for Eero Websites,
E
ERO
, https://eero.com/legal/privacy-website (last visited Sept. 29, 2020).
1949
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 537 (response to Questions for the Record
of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
A 2017 internal memorandum further explains Amazon’s strat-
egy behind these acquisitions. As the memorandum notes, while ac-
quiring each company independently would make Amazon stronger,
acquiring both ‘‘would put us in a meaningfully better position than
we are today (and we would not want to stake our chances in the
segment on closing any one opportunity).’’
1941
Douglas Booms, the
Vice President of Corporate Development at Amazon, sent an email
summarizing the thoughts of other senior executives at the com-
pany, which included: ‘‘I don’t know how we can get big fast in that
segment without an [sic] acquiring someone.’’
1942
The documents and other relevant information reviewed by the
Subcommittee demonstrate that Amazon acquiring Ring and Blink
was in part to expand and reinforce its market power for its other
business lines. Internally, Amazon executives discussed how home
surveillance acquisitions would help them implement unattended
package delivery. Similarly, they discussed the idea that the acqui-
sitions would help Amazon develop its Alexa Doorbell application
program interface, an AWS service that allows Alexa Skills devel-
opers to build apps that respond to a ringing doorbell.
1943
Amazon
referred to this strategy as an ‘‘integration approach’’ to ‘‘remove
impediments to future growth.’’
1944
More recently, Amazon purchased Eero, a mesh networking com-
pany, for $97 million in 2019.
1945
The purchase was part of Ama-
zon’s strategy to offer ‘‘frustration-free setup’’ for smart home de-
vices in the Alexa ecosystem, another move aimed at removing im-
pediments to growing the platform’s presence in the home.
1946
‘‘Amazon Wi-Fi Simple Setup’’ scans the user’s Eero network dur-
ing the initial set-up of an Alexa-enabled device, applying the
user’s stored credentials to automatically connect to other smart
devices, such as outlets and Fire TV devices.
1947
To achieve this,
Eero must continually understand which devices are connected to
the network, including the IP addresses of those devices.
1948
This
acquisition gives Amazon access to another important input for
consumer data.
1949
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00266 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
261
1950
Competitors Hearing at 12 (statement of Patrick Spence, CEO, Sonos, Inc.).
1951
Do More with Alexa, A
MAZON
, https://www.amazon.com/alexa-voice-shopping/
b?ie=UTF8&node=14552177011 (last visited Sept. 30, 2020).
1952
Submission from Source 39, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 39–00000097, at 19
(Sept. 16, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
1953
Julie Creswell, How Amazon Steers Shoppers to Its Own Products, N.Y. T
IMES
(June 23,
2018), https://www.nytimes.com/2018/06/23/business/amazon-the-brand-buster.html.
1954
Aaron Cheris, Darrell Rigby & Suzanne Tager, Dreaming of an Amazon Christmas, B
AIN
&
C
O
. (Nov. 9, 2017), https://www.bain.com/insights/retail-holiday-newsletter-2017-issue-2/.
1955
CEO Hearing at 125 (question of Rep. Jamie Raskin (D–MD), Member, Subcomm. on
Antirust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
1956
Id. (statement of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.).
(d) Conduct. During the Subcommittee’s investigation, market
participants raised concerns about Amazon’s business practices in
the smart home market. As these market participants note, Ama-
zon uses Alexa to favor its own goods and services, including
AmazonBasics and Prime Music. Amazon has also imposed barriers
to entry for other voice-enabled device manufacturers through
predatory pricing of Alexa-enabled devices, and through its domi-
nance as a leading distribution channel for smart home devices.
(i) Self-Preferencing. Amazon has the largest voice application
‘‘store’’ of third-party skills, as well as first-party services that rep-
resent popular voice assistant applications, such as Amazon Music
and an e-commerce platform that it can favor over third-party ap-
plications.
1950
Amazon favors its services in Alexa by making them
defaults for common voice commands. For example, Amazon.com is
the default store for basic voice commands related to shopping.
‘‘Alexa, add milk to my cart,’’ adds milk to the user’s Amazon shop-
ping cart.
1951
Besides favoring Amazon services with default voice commands,
Alexa also allows Amazon to favor its retail products over products
offered by third-party sellers. When users shop via voice command,
they are presented with one spoken offer and an option for a fol-
low-up question, which is distinct from an online user interface
that shows the additional offers ranked. This increases the impor-
tance of being Alexa’s featured offer.
1952
For example, The New York Times reported in 2018 that when
a user says, ‘‘Alexa, buy batteries,’’ Alexa responds with the
AmazonBasics option.
1953
Similarly, a study conducted by Bain &
Company found that for categories in which Amazon offered a pri-
vate-label product, Alexa recommended those products 17 percent
of the time, despite its private-label goods representing only about
2 percent of total volume sold.
1954
During the Subcommittee’s sixth
hearing, Representative Jamie Raskin (D–MD) asked Mr. Bezos,
‘‘[H]as Alexa ever been trained to favor Amazon products when
users shop by voice?’’
1955
Mr. Bezos responded that he didn’t ‘‘know
if it’s been trained in that way,’’ but ‘‘it wouldn’t surprise me if
Alexa sometimes does promote our own products.’’
1956
Amazon
chooses the products Alexa suggests based on a range of features,
including products that ‘‘customers frequently purchase based on
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00267 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
262
1957
Id. at 284 (response to Questions for the Record of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.);
see also Aaron Cheris, Darrell Rigby & Suzanne Tager, Dreaming of an Amazon Christmas,
B
AIN &
C
O
. (Nov. 9, 2017), https://www.bain.com/insights/retail-holiday-newsletter-2017-issue-
2/.
1958
Aaron Cheris, Darrell Rigby & Suzanne Tager, Dreaming of an Amazon Christmas, B
AIN
&
C
O
. (Nov. 9, 2017), https://www.bain.com/insights/retail-holiday-newsletter-2017-issue-2/.
1959
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 535 (response to Questions for the Record
of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1960
Khari Johnson, Voicelabs Ditches Analytics Service to Launch Alpine.ai for Ecommerce
Voice Apps, V
ENTURE
B
EAT
(Jan. 29, 2018), https://venturebeat.com/2018/01/29/voicelabs-
ditches-analytics-service-to-launch-alpine-ai-for-ecommerce-voice-apps/.
1961
CEO Hearing at 5 (response to Questions for the Record of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com,
Inc.).
1962
See Alexa Skills: Shopping, A
MAZON
, https://www.amazon.com/s/ref=lpl13727921011
lnrlnl16?fst=as%3Aoff&rh=n%3A13727921011%2Cn%3A%2113727922011%2Cn%3A142848
62011&bbn=13727922011&ie=UTF8&qid=1600864849&rnid=13727922011 (last visited Sept. 30,
2020).
1963
Set Up Your Echo, A
MAZON
, https://www.amazon.com/gp/help/customer/display.html?
nodeId=GKFJXZCLQ83HGHQZ (last visited Oct. 3, 2020).
1964
See CEO Hearing at 124 (statement of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1965
Competitors Hearing at 11–12 (statement of Patrick Spence, CEO, Sonos, Inc.).
their past orders’’ and Amazon’s Choice designation.
1957
Amazon’s
method for determining ‘‘Amazon’s Choice’’ is opaque.
1958
Amazon minimizes concerns about favoring its first-party goods
through voice shopping by highlighting how rare it is for people to
purchase goods through Alexa.
1959
Reporting suggests, however,
that there is an increasing number of queries from users who ex-
pect to hear product information or to complete a transaction while
interacting with a voice assistant.
1960
Amazon also justified the
fact that third-party sales through Alexa are lower than third-party
sales on Amazon.com—42 percent compared to 58 percent—by say-
ing that ‘‘customers disproportionately use Alexa to order house-
hold consumable items (like paper towels or batteries) for which
Amazon’s offers are particularly competitive.’’
1961
This dem-
onstrates the problem, however, given that voice shopping is most
useful for products in which consumers do not have to do much re-
search or engage in price comparison. Alexa’s algorithm, in con-
junction with the AmazonBasics business model, provides a conven-
ient avenue for Amazon to favor first-party products.
Although it is technically possible for Alexa users to voice shop
at other stores, there is significant friction. Users must first enable
the shopping skills for other online retailers, which then requires
the user to set up a completely separate billing profile, even though
it contains similar information to their Amazon user profile.
1962
Alexa-enabled devices are tied to the user’s Amazon account, which
populates the user’s saved credit card and shipping information for
use during general shopping commands.
1963
(ii) Predatory Pricing and Bundling. Amazon uses a predatory
pricing strategy to increase its sales of smart home devices by pric-
ing its products below cost.
1964
It is common for Amazon to sell
these products in bundles at steep discounts. Several smart home
device manufacturers told the Subcommittee that, when Amazon
sells certain devices in a bundle or at a steep discount, it makes
it nearly impossible for companies who specialize in making one
piece of voice-assistant enabled hardware to compete on its mer-
its.
1965
Furthermore, as described earlier in this Report, aggressive
pricing of smart home devices—specifically ‘‘hubs’’ such as the
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00268 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
263
1966
Interview with Source 148 (Aug. 26, 2020).
1967
Steve Kovach, Amazon Will Stop Selling Nest Smart Home Devices, Escalating Its War
with Google, B
US
. I
NSIDER
(Mar. 2, 2018), https://www.businessinsider.com/amazon-wont-sell-
nest-products-from-google-2018-3.
1968
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04258793–993 (Jan.
29, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
1969
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00172104
(Mar. 9, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
1970
Submission from Source 38, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 27 (Sept. 1, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1971
Interview with Source 148 (Aug. 26, 2020).
Echo—has created a significant barrier to entry for companies that
want to compete with the leading voice assistant platforms.
(iii) Use of Gatekeeper Power. Amazon Marketplace is an impor-
tant distribution channel for voice-enabled electronics in its Alexa
ecosystem. Amazon decides the availability and placement of prod-
ucts on its site. As a result, Amazon can use the threat of delisting
a product on its marketplace to ensure that Alexa is enabled on
other companies’ devices or to secure other favorable contractual
terms.
In an interview with the Subcommittee, a seller that sells a sig-
nificant number of its device on Amazon.com said that, during con-
tract negotiations, Amazon repeatedly refers to its power to delist
the company’s product if Amazon’s services are not prominent
enough on the device.
1966
In 2017, Amazon also reportedly in-
formed one of its main home security competitors—the Google-
owned smart home company Nest—that it would not list any of its
recently announced products, including its latest smart thermostat
and home security system.
1967
Notwithstanding its own market
power, Google’s internal communications describe Amazon as hav-
ing ‘‘changed the dynamics,’’ observing that there is a ‘‘built in in-
centive to partner with Alexa, since [Amazon] will pull you from
their store if you don’t support it.’’
1968
Additionally, Amazon controls the prominence of competing
voice-enabled devices on its marketplace and promotes its first-
party voice-enabled devices on Amazon.com. In an internal memo-
randum to Amazon executives about the Ring acquisition, Michael
Deal, Amazon’s Vice President and Associate General Counsel, said
that Amazon ‘‘can promote Ring’s products and subscription plans
heavily on our sites as we do with our current [first-party] de-
vices.’’
1969
Relatedly, Amazon can also use advertisement placement as le-
verage during negotiations with other device manufacturers. In
interviews with and submissions to the Subcommittee, several mar-
ket participants said that ad placement was used as leverage in ne-
gotiations. In one instance, Amazon placed a competing brand’s ad
beneath the product of the firm it was negotiating with ‘‘to influ-
ence negotiations.’’
1970
Additionally, the Subcommittee heard from
a voice-enabled device manufacturer that offers a competitive prod-
uct to Amazon’s first-party devices that it was prohibited from buy-
ing ads on Amazon.com.
1971
The competitor expressed concern
about the harm this causes consumers, who may be confused or de-
ceived when they receive ads promoting Amazon products even
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00269 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
264
1972
Id.
1973
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04261582 to
–04261585 (Nov. 27, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
1974
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 536 (response to Questions for the Record
of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
1975
Dana Mattioli & Cara Lombardo, Amazon Met with Startups About Investing, Then
Launched Competing Products, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (July 23, 2020), https://www.wsj.com/articles/ama-
zon-tech-startup-echo-bezos-alexa-investment-fund-11595520249.
1976
See Tice v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. 5:10–cv–1311 (C.D. Cal. Mar. 25, 2020); C.O. v. Ama-
zon.com, Inc., No. C19–910 (W.D. Wash. Sept. 23, 2019).
1977
See id.
1978
Dana Mattioli & Cara Lombardo, Amazon Met with Startups About Investing, Then
Launched Competing Products, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (July 23, 2020), https://www.wsj.com/articles/
amazon-tech-startup-echo-bezos-alexa-investment-fund-11595520249.
1979
Id.
when they specifically search for a competitor’s product on Ama-
zon.com.
1972
Even Google, which ranks just behind Amazon in online shop-
ping queries, believes it has a disadvantage with Amazon. In an in-
ternal email about smart speakers, a Google employee noted that
‘‘fighting Amazon with a very-hard-to-differentiate product and a
channel disadvantage and a huge economic disadvantage (due to
channel mix margin differences) is already like fighting a shark on
a surfboard.’’
1973
(iv) Misuse of Data. Amazon has access to information about con-
sumer use of third-party applications on Alexa-enabled devices and
uses its dominant position in the voice assistant market to collect
more data from within the Alexa ecosystem.
Amazon has insight into which Alexa skills are invoked by Alexa
users and the frequency of usage.
1974
Considering Amazon’s use of
third-party seller’s data in e-commerce and cloud customer’s data
on Amazon Web Services, Amazon may use the same tactics with
other firms’ voice application data to determine which voice assist-
ant skills it should invest in.
Additionally, Amazon uses its market power to collect third-party
voice application data. According to a July 2020 report by The Wall
Street Journal, Amazon told Vivint, a manufacturer of smart-home
devices that, ‘‘it would only allow the company to remain on the
Echo if Vivint agreed to give it not only the data from its Vivint
function on Echo, but from every Vivint device in those customers’
homes at all times.’’
1975
Amazon has also faced civil suits related to its storage of voice
data.
1976
When Alexa hears a ‘‘wake’’ word—such as ‘‘Alexa’’ or
‘‘Echo’’—it records the user’s voice command, including conversa-
tions in the background, and saves a permanent recording of the
user’s voice to its own servers, as opposed to temporary storage for
artificial intelligence training purposes.
1977
(v) Copying Nascent Competitors’ Technology. The Subcommit-
tee’s investigation produced evidence consistent with public report-
ing that Amazon uses information collected through Alexa Fund in-
vestments to inform and improve Amazon’s smart home ecosystem.
When Amazon invests in a startup, it obtains access to the com-
pany’s non-public financial information, strategic plans, and other
proprietary information.
1978
According to a recent Wall Street Jour-
nal report, eight months after Alexa Fund invested in Nucleus,
Amazon announced the Echo Show, a very similar Alexa-enabled
video-chat device.
1979
This report described several other examples,
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00270 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
265
1980
Id.
1981
CEO Hearing at 121 (statement of Rep. Ken Buck (R–CO), Member, Subcomm. on Anti-
trust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
1982
Production from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00214240 (Oct.
18, 2017) (on file with Comm.).
1983
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00220705 (Nov. 4, 2017).
1984
Id. at AMAZON–HJC–00220703.
1985
Ron Miller, How AWS Came To Be, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(July 2, 2016), https://techcrunch.com/
2016/07/02/andy-jassys-brief-history-of-the-genesis-of-aws/.
1986
What’s New, A
MAZON
W
EB
S
ERVS
. (Oct. 4, 2006), https://aws.amazon.com/about-aws/
whats-new/2006/.
1987
Id.
1988
Ron Miller, How AWS Came To Be, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(July 2, 2016), https://techcrunch.com/
2016/07/02/andy-jassys-brief-history-of-the-genesis-of-aws/.
including Vocalife, the inventors of a ‘‘speech-detection technology,’’
which filed a lawsuit against Amazon alleging it improperly used
proprietary technology.
1980
At the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing,
Representative Ken Buck (R–CO) said that allegations that Ama-
zon incorporated features demonstrated to it by Vocalife’s founders
during an investment meeting ‘‘are serious, especially because the
size and scope of these practices couldn’t happen without Amazon’s
monopolistic control of the marketplace.’’
1981
Prior to Amazon’s acquisition of Ring, Amazon invested in Ring
through the Alexa Fund, and internal emails about meetings dur-
ing this time demonstrate how Amazon is able to obtain crucial in-
sights into young companies. Amazon was able to learn about
Ring’s ‘‘roadmap, future products, [and] two acquisitions they have
done.’’
1982
While Amazon often denies public reporting that it
steals and copies technology from young startups, Amazon’s emails
suggest that it does replicate some of the startups it meets with or
invests in. An email out of Amazon’s Lab126 regarding Ring indi-
cated that Amazon ‘‘could easily replicate all of their hardware to
be better, [and] operate in a more secure and robust infrastructure,
for a LOT less than [the] cost of buying them.’’
1983
In the same
email chain, Amazon employees wondered, ‘‘[I]f we move forward
with due diligence, then decide not to buy [Ring], could we have
legal issues if we go into the market by ourselves as a competitor
and materially impact their business?’’
1984
5. Amazon Web Services
(a) Overview. Amazon Web Services (AWS) is considered the pio-
neer of cloud computing and has sustained a first-mover advantage
for over a decade.
1985
AWS officially launched in 2006, featuring
two of its core IaaS offerings, Simple Storage Service (S3) and Elas-
tic Compute Cloud (EC2).
1986
While Amazon.com was AWS’s first
customer, in the early 2000s AWS began creating cloud offerings
for third-party merchants, who could use AWS to ‘‘build online
shopping sites on top of Amazon’s e-commerce engine.’’
1987
For
AWS, meanwhile, this partnership with third parties gave the com-
pany experience in creating well-documented APIs for internal de-
velopers.
1988
Over the next few years, AWS rolled out additional
programs to expand its network of third-party software vendors
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00271 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
266
1989
Introducing AWS Marketplace, A
MAZON
W
EB
S
ERVS
. (Apr. 19, 2012), https://aws
.amazon.com/about-aws/whats-new/2012/04/19/introducing-aws-marketplace/.
1990
Jeff Barr, Announcing the AWS Partner Network, AWS N
EWS
B
LOG
(Apr. 17, 2012),
https://aws.amazon.com/blogs/aws/announcing-the-aws-partner-network/ (in beta).
1991
Frank Konkel, Federal Cloud Spending Trends Toward All-Time High, N
EXTGOV
(Sept.
12, 2018), https://www.nextgov.com/it-modernization/2018/09/federal-cloud-spending-trends-
toward-all-time-high/151221/.
1992
Id.
1993
The Trusted Cloud for Government, A
MAZON
W
EB
S
ERVS
., https://aws.amazon.com/gov-
ernment-education/government/ (last visited Sept. 30, 2020).
1994
Amazon.com, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 26 (Feb. 1, 2018), https://s2.q4cdn.com/
299287126/files/doclfinancials/annual/AmazonlAR.PDF.
1995
Amazon.com, Inc., Quarterly Report (Form 10–Q) 17 (Apr. 30, 2020), http://
d18rn0p25nwr6d.cloudfront.net/CIK-0001018724/708a19c5-7d8c-4fc9-ab37-bfaa7a31629b.pdf.
and implementation partners, including AWS Marketplace
1989
and
the AWS Partnership Network (APN) in 2012.
1990
Over the last decade, AWS has also secured significant govern-
ment contracts. Most notably, in 2014, AWS signed a $600 million
Commercial Cloud Services (C2S) contract to build the AWS Secret
Region, a cloud offering tailored for the U.S. intelligence commu-
nity.
1991
The deal marked the largest cloud infrastructure contract
at the time and signaled the government’s shift from investing in
on-premise server capacity to cloud services.
1992
Today, AWS
boasts work ‘‘with over 6,500 government agencies’’ and states that
Amazon has been ‘‘among the first to solve government compliance
challenges facing cloud computing,’’ while also ‘‘consistently
help[ing] our customers navigate procurement and policy issues re-
lated to adoption of cloud computing.’’
1993
AWS contributes immense value to Amazon’s overall business. In
each quarter since Amazon began publicly reporting its financials
for cloud, AWS has accounted for an outsized share of Amazon’s op-
erating profits. While AWS contributes to less than 15 percent of
Amazon’s annual revenue, it consistently accounts for over 50 per-
cent of the company’s operating income. In 2017, AWS accounted
for over 100 percent of Amazon’s operating income, due to losses
in the company’s international business.
1994
In the first quarter of
2020, AWS accounted for 13.5 percent of Amazon’s total revenues
but 77 percent of its operating income.
1995
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00272 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
267
1996
Prepared by the Subcommittee based on Amazon.com, Inc., Annual Reports (Form 10–
K) (2015–2019).
1997
Submission from Source 48, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 8 (Nov. 8, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
1998
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00216209 (Aug.
24, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
1999
See Letter from Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Doug Col-
lins, Ranking Member, H. Comm on the Judiciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm.
on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James
Sensenbrenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the
Continued
Contributions to Amazon’s Revenue and Operating Profit
over Time
1996
Profits earned through its cloud services enable Amazon to invest
heavily in expanding its cloud operation, as well as to support its
other lines of business. Several market participants expressed con-
cerns to the Subcommittee that Amazon uses its high and steady
profits from AWS to subsidize these other lines of business, includ-
ing its retail operation.
1997
In an internal document produced in
response to the Committee’s requests for information, Amazon in-
structs its employees to rebut this claim by referring to it as a
‘‘myth.’’
1998
However, Amazon failed to produce the financial data
that would have enabled the Subcommittee to make an inde-
pendent assessment.
1999
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00273 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 23 here 11701.023
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
268
H. Comm. on the Judiciary, to Jeff Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc., attach. § A.6, at 2–3 (Sept.
13, 2019) (on file with Comm.) (requesting data).
2000
Letter from David Zapolsky, Gen. Couns., Amazon.com, Inc., to Hon. David N. Cicilline,
Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
6 (July 26, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
2001
Id.; Press Release, Katie Costello, Gartner, Gartner Forecasts Worldwide Public Cloud
Revenue to Grow 17.5 Percent in 2019 (Apr. 2, 2019), https://www.gartner.com/en/newsroom/
press-releases/2019-04-02-gartner-forecasts-worldwide-public-cloud-revenue-to-g.
2002
Jordan Novet, AWS Tops $10 Billion in Quarterly Revenue for the First Time, CNBC (Apr.
30, 2020), https://www.cnbc.com/2020/04/30/aws-earnings-q1-2020.html.
2003
David Ramel, AWS vs. Azure Heats Up in Federal Market, W
ASH
. T
ECH
. (Sept. 14, 2018),
https://washingtontechnology.com/articles/2018/09/14/aws-vs-azure-public-sector.aspx.
2004
Interview with Source 31 (May 27, 2020).
2005
Letter from David Zapolsky, Gen. Couns., Amazon.com, Inc., to Hon. David N. Cicilline,
Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
6 (July 26, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
2006
Id.
2007
Complaint at 5, Amazon Web Servs, Inc. v. United States, 147 Fed. Cl. 146 (2020) (No.
1:19–cv–01796), https://www.courthousenews.com/wp-content/uploads/2019/12/amazon-trump
-cafc.pdf.
2008
See supra Section IV.
(b) Market Power. As discussed earlier in this Report, AWS is the
largest provider of cloud computing services, capturing approxi-
mately 24 percent of the U.S. spend in 2018 on cloud computing
services, including IaaS, PaaS, and SaaS.
2000
AWS represents close
to half of global spending on cloud infrastructure services, with
three times the market share of Microsoft, its closest compet-
itor.
2001
Its growth continues to soar. In the first quarter of 2020,
AWS crossed $10 billion in quarterly revenue while growing 33 per-
cent on an annualized basis.
2002
Amazon has a ‘‘lion’s share of the government cloud infrastruc-
ture market.’’
2003
Exact data on AWS’s share of government cloud
expenditure is opaque because most of AWS’s public sector revenue
comes through subcontracts, which are harder to track, and con-
tracts related to the intelligence community, which are listed as
classified spending and are rarely reported. Market participants,
however, emphasize that AWS is considered a major player in fed-
eral cloud contracts.
2004
In its submissions to the Subcommittee, Amazon describes itself
as a relatively small player representing ‘‘less than 1% of IT spend-
ing globally and less than 2% in the United States.’’
2005
Amazon
states that AWS competes with a large array of offerings including
on-premise computing.
2006
In other contexts, however, Amazon has
highlighted its leading position, describing itself as the ‘‘largest
cloud software marketplace’’ and the ‘‘only cloud provider with ex-
isting classified infrastructure.’’
2007
Through a careful review of Amazon’s internal documents and
other evidence during the investigation, the Subcommittee found
that Amazon has a dominant position in cloud computing. Ama-
zon’s dominance in cloud computing traces in part to its first-mover
advantage and the high fixed costs and economies of scale associ-
ated with this market.
2008
But evidence suggests that Amazon has
also taken steps to lock in and extend this dominance in ways that
risk harming customers, businesses, and the broader public.
Network effects incentivized Amazon to build out AWS offerings
quickly. As with other sectors of the digital economy, the value of
Amazon’s cloud offerings increases with the number of businesses
and customers that use it. Introducing more services and partner-
ship programs draws more customers and attracts more developers
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00274 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
269
2009
Submission from Google, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, GOOG–HJC–04260401 (Aug. 25,
2016) (on file with Comm.).
2010
AWS Marketplace, A
MAZON
W
EB
S
ERVS
., https://aws.amazon.com/marketplace (last vis-
ited Sept. 30, 2020).
2011
CEO Hearing at 285 (response to Questions for the Record of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Ama-
zon.com, Inc.).
2012
AWS Marketplace, A
MAZON
W
EB
S
ERVS
., https://aws.amazon.com/marketplace (last vis-
ited Sept. 30, 2020); Brad Lyman, See What’s New for AWS Marketplace Sellers, AWS P
ARTNER
N
ETWORK
B
LOG
(Mar. 9, 2018), https://aws.amazon.com/blogs/apn/see-whats-new-for-aws-
marketplace-sellers.
2013
Interview with Source 736 (June 10, 2020).
2014
Interview with Source 126 (June 29, 2020).
2015
See supra Section IV.
2016
Interview with Source 111 (Apr. 6, 2020).
2017
Submission from Source 32, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 32–000009 (Oct. 29,
2019) (on file with Comm.).
2018
Id. at Source 32–000017.
and implementation partners, which, in turn, draws additional cus-
tomers.
2009
AWS is considered to have the largest collection of cloud offer-
ings. Its AWS Management Console and supporting technologies
span many categories, including storage and computing, databases,
migration services, and machine learning tools.
2010
Many of these
products are based on open-source software or on the technology of
companies that Amazon acquired.
2011
In addition to selling cloud
offerings directly, AWS also runs a cloud marketplace where third-
party vendors can list their products. The AWS Marketplace enjoys
over 1,300 vendors as of 2018, and over 9,000 products, functioning
as the largest cloud marketplace in the sector.
2012
The widespread adoption of AWS’s developer certification pro-
grams, partner networks, and student programs has meant that
there are far more engineers familiar with AWS technology than
with any other platform.
2013
Several market participants listed the
availability of AWS-trained engineers as a reason for selecting
AWS over other cloud vendors and as a barrier for switching plat-
forms or attempting to multi-cloud.
2014
High switching costs reinforce Amazon’s dominance in the cloud
market.
2015
A cloud-based application company interviewed by the
Subcommittee explained these costs:
We’ve looked at other services (Google, Microsoft, Oracle) but we’ve relied on
AWS for so long that we couldn’t just flip a switch, and we’ve run down a lot
of engineering problems with AWS .... There are other providers we could go
to, but it would take work. We could also build some functionality internally, but
that would also take a lot of work.
2016
For cloud-based application developers, whose entire product is
dependent on AWS, the fears of lock-in are even greater. One mar-
ketplace participant said:
[A]ny transition of the cloud services currently provided by AWS to another
cloud service provider would be difficult to implement and would cause us to
incur significant time and expense and could disrupt or degrade our ability to
deliver our products and services. Our business relies on the availability of our
services for [users] and advertisers.
2017
Amazon has also taken steps to lock-in its position, including
through long-term contracts, volume minimums, and the use of fees
to move data to other cloud providers, which are also known as
egress fees. In submissions to the Subcommittee, numerous market
participants noted that AWS often seeks multi-year contracts dur-
ing negotiations.
2018
These contracts are also commonplace in com-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00275 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
270
2019
Lyft, Annual Report (Form 10–K) 7 (Feb. 28, 2020), https://investor.lyft.com/static-files/
981ad93a-5d97-4f7f-8937-5682ca83cba7.
2020
Slack, Registration Statement (Form S–1) 90 (Apr. 26, 2019), http://d18rn0p25
nwr6d.cloudfront.net/CIK-0001764925/b6da15ae-25c5-4447-ba38-c287bf11e624.pdf.
2021
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00206893 (May
11, 2017) (on file with Comm.).
2022
Interview with Source 170 (May 27, 2020).
2023
Kevin McLaughlin & Amir Efrati, AWS Holds the Line on Cloud Bills as Customers Ask
for Relief, I
NFORMATION
(Apr. 17, 2020), https://www.theinformation.com/articles/aws-holds-
the-line-on-cloud-bills-as-customers-ask-for-relief.
2024
Id.
2025
See supra Section IV.
2026
Ron Miller, Update: Amazon Has Acquired Israeli Disaster Recovery Service CloudEndure
for Around $200M, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Jan. 8, 2019), https://techcrunch.com/2019/01/08/
Continued
panies’ investor statements. For example, according to Lyft’s 2020
investor filing, it agreed to pay ‘‘an aggregate of at least $300 mil-
lion between January 2019 and December 2021 on AWS serv-
ices.’’
2019
According to Slack’s investor filling, in 2018, it committed
to a five-year contract with minimum annual commitments of $50
million.
2020
The Subcommittee also uncovered evidence that Amazon some-
times requires a volume agreement when a large company seeks to
negotiate lower prices. In an internal email discussion on this topic,
a senior executive at AWS wrote that Amazon has ‘‘a private rate
card which has a commit level for bandwidth pricing. Rates at or
above the private rate card are pre-approved. Anything below that
has to be first approved by me and then the price goes to service
GM.’’
2021
When an Amazon customer chooses to move data to another
cloud provider, they are charged an egress fee. Market participants
told the Subcommittee that they view these fees less as a cost for
Amazon to transport data and more as friction imposed by Amazon
for switching providers, noting that Amazon charges egress fees
even when data is staying locally within the same data center.
2022
The COVID–19 pandemic has underscored the centrality of cloud
computing to the functioning of an increasing swath of busi-
nesses—highlighting how cloud services have come to resemble
critical infrastructure. Reporting by The Information in April 2020
discussed how the major cloud providers are facing requests from
many customers for financial relief, while the demand for cloud
computing has increased.
2023
As this reporting noted, ‘‘AWS has
been the least willing to offer flexible terms on customer bills, ac-
cording to numerous customers. That stands in contrast to Micro-
soft and Google which have shown some flexibility, partners
say.’’
2024
(c) Merger Activity. Amazon has acquired a significant number of
cloud computing firms over the past decade. Although a full discus-
sion of this activity is beyond the scope of this Report, Amazon’s
acquisition activity in the cloud market appears to be part of a
broader trend among dominant cloud providers to make serial ac-
quisitions, any one of which may seem insignificant, but which col-
lectively serve to solidify and expand their dominance.
2025
In some
instances AWS has acquired cloud technologies that previously in-
tegrated with multiple clouds, only for AWS to make it an AWS-
specific product after acquisition, foreclosing competitors and in-
creasing consumers’ switching costs.
2026
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00276 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
271
amazon-reportedly-acquired-israeli-disaster-recovery-service-cloudendure-for-around-200m/. See
also CloudEndure Deprecation, G
OOGLE
C
LOUD
, https://cloud.google.com/compute/docs/dep-
recations/cloudendure (last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
2027
Christina Farr & Ari Levy, Target Is Plotting a Big Move Away from AWS as Amazon
Takes Over Retail, CNBC (Aug. 29, 2017), https://www.cnbc.com/2017/08/29/target-is-moving-
away-from-aws-after-amazon-bought-whole-foods.html). See also Netflix on AWS, A
MAZON
W
EB
S
ERVS
., https://aws.amazon.com/solutions/case-studies/netflix/ (last visited Sept. 30, 2020).
2028
Interview with Source 146 (May 28, 2020).
2029
Interview with Source 126 (June 29, 2020).
2030
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00216210 (Aug.
24, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
2031
Barb Darrow, Why Cloud Users Should Care that Amazon Just Kicked Apple TV to the
Curb, F
ORTUNE
(Oct. 2, 2015), http://fortune.com/2015/10/02/why-aws-users-should-care-that-
amazon-nixed-apple-tv/.
2032
Interview with Source 126 (June 29, 2020).
(d) Competitive Significance of AWS to Amazon’s Other Lines of
Business. Amazon’s dual role as a dominant provider of cloud infra-
structure and as a dominant firm in other markets creates a con-
flict of interest that Amazon has the incentive and ability to ex-
ploit.
Amazon’s dominance in cloud computing alongside its integration
across an array of businesses—online retail, music and video, and
smart home devices—creates a core conflict of interest. Cloud com-
puting customers like Netflix and Target are in the position of com-
peting with Amazon while also relying on AWS. Firms in their po-
sition effectively have to choose between switching to one of the al-
ternative cloud infrastructure providers or funding their primary
competitor.
2027
One venture capitalist described Amazon as ‘‘useful
but dangerous’’ because ‘‘it’s hard to predict what Amazon wants
to get into .... [Y]ou can’t know.’’
2028
Similarly, a business-to-busi-
ness application developer told the Subcommittee that they felt
pressure to switch their entire product to Microsoft Azure because
of its client’s concerns with Amazon’s anticompetitive conduct in
the online retail sector.
2029
Amazon acknowledges that its cloud customers—which are also
its competitors—are wary of using AWS. One internal document
had guidance on how to discuss the issue with customers. One FAQ
sheet listed, ‘‘What do you say to customers who are worried that
using AWS services will support Amazon’s competitive growth in
the retail space?’’ Amazon’s sample answer stated, ‘‘How can you
afford to not compete with the best possible tools in such a tough
market like retail?’’
2030
The Subcommittee also spoke with market participants that ex-
pressed concern about how this conflict of interest shapes Amazon’s
behavior in its other lines of business. For example, in 2015, Ama-
zon kicked Google Chromecast and Apple TV—direct competitors
with the Amazon Fire Stick and Fire TV Cube—out of its retail
store.
2031
AWS is also positioned to use customer and seller data
from one line of business to inform decisions in other lines of busi-
ness, analogous to its conduct in Amazon Retail. At least one mar-
ket participant who spoke with the Subcommittee had evidence
that AWS engaged in this cross-business data sharing.
2032
In an-
other internal document with guidance for staff on ‘‘AWS Competi-
tive Messaging,’’ employees were advised to offer the following re-
sponse:
Q: Walmart is warning its suppliers that they don’t want them to be running
on AWS because they don’t want Amazon.com, a competitor of Walmart’s,
to have access to their data. How are you addressing that?
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00277 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
272
2033
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00216213 (Aug.
24, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
2034
Interview with Source 146 (May 28, 2020).
2035
CEO Hearing at 296 (response to Questions for the Record of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Ama-
zon.com, Inc.).
2036
Interview with Source 146 (May 28, 2020); Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at
44 (response to Questions for the Record of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Ama-
zon.com, Inc.).
2037
Interview with Source 146 (May 28, 2020).
2038
Alistair Barr, Amazon Finds Startup Investments in the ‘‘Cloud,’’ R
EUTERS
(Nov. 9, 2011),
http://www.reuters.com/article/amazon-cloud-idUSN1E7A727Q20111109.
2039
Id.
2040
AWS Activate, A
MAZON
W
EB
S
ERVS
., https://aws.amazon.com/activate/ (last visited
Sept. 30, 2020).
A: Even though Amazon’s consumer business has no access to any customer
data in AWS, I can understand why Walmart would be paranoid in making
sure that their data is private. So, I think it’s a pretty reasonable expecta-
tion for them to ask their suppliers to encrypt that data in AWS.
2033
Engineers and market participants have also raised concerns
that AWS employees may have access to Amazon’s Key Manage-
ment Services (KMS), which customers can use to store encryption
keys.
2034
If an employee were able to access a customer’s
encryption keys, they could potentially see the contents of a cus-
tomer’s application, including proprietary code, business trans-
actions, and data on their users. In response to questions from the
Subcommittee, Amazon said that the company’s ‘‘policies prohibit
employees from accessing and reading customer keys in KMS. KMS
is designed such that customer keys in the service cannot be re-
trieved in plain text (unencrypted) form by anybody, including
AWS employees.’’
2035
Even if AWS employees can never access the
content of their customers applications, AWS tracks a host of com-
mercially sensitive metrics, including any changes in demand for
storage and compute services, the components of their application’s
architecture, the requests to a specific database per second, data-
base size, and the types of requests.
2036
One industry expert told
the Subcommittee:
They don’t need to see the encrypted content of a movie to see that there are
a ton of requests to particular data .... [If Netflix] announced five new movies
this weekend and there’s a ton of data to five new objects ..., you don’t need
all the information to know what’s happening.
2037
Finally, AWS provides Amazon with unparalleled insights into
the trajectory of startups using its services—information that it can
use to guide acquisitions and replicate promising technology. Data
that AWS collects on cloud computing customers can provide
unique business intelligence—information that investors, other
firms, and entrepreneurs lack.
A report from 2011 published in Reuters, profiling the AWS
Start-up Challenge, describes cases where AWS has used insights
gleaned from its cloud computing service to inform its venture cap-
ital investment decisions.
2038
Adam Selipsky, then Vice President
of AWS, told Reuters, ‘‘AWS has great relationships with many
young companies and there have been cases where we’ve been able
to help with investment opportunities.’’
2039
Today, one way Ama-
zon leverages AWS is through relationships with startups. The
AWS Activate program provides startups with free credits, tech-
nical support, and training.
2040
The Subcommittee interviewed a startup and beneficiary of AWS
Activate that had engaged in partnership conversations with Ama-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00278 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
273
2041
Interview with Source 126 (May 11, 2020).
2042
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 541 (response to Questions for the Record
of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
2043
Id. at 539.
2044
Id. at 538.
2045
Submission from Amazon, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, AMAZON–HJC–00225832
(June 15, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
zon. During these discussions, the startup shared information
about how its product was built with AWS. Within a few years, the
startup learned that Amazon had introduced a replica product.
This company said that Amazon ‘‘had so many incentives[,] [r]ate
cuts, and free services. Not having a lot of resources, it’s hard to
turn that down. But fast forward, we basically helped them build
their offering that they copied from us.’’
2041
As part of its investigation, the Subcommittee asked Amazon
whether it uses or has ever used AWS usage patterns or data to
inform its investment decisions. Amazon responded:
AWS uses data on individual customers’ use of AWS to provide or improve the
AWS services and grow the business relationship with that customer. This data
may inform AWS’s decisions about how AWS invests in infrastructure, such as
data centers, edge networks, hardware, and related software solutions in order
improve the customer experience.
2042
Amazon’s response leaves unclear whether it would view it as ap-
propriate to use a firm’s AWS data to develop products competing
with that firm, so long as Amazon could identify some benefit to
the broader ‘‘customer experience.’’
Prior to 2017, Amazon also required that AWS customers agree
‘‘not to assert any intellectual property claim against any AWS
service used by that customer.’’
2043
Amazon removed that condition
from the AWS online customer agreement on June 28, 2017.
2044
In addition to creating a significant information advantage for
Amazon, AWS may also reinforce its market power in other ways.
Because startups often rely heavily on AWS, Amazon is a natural
choice when pursuing a sale or seeking investment. In an internal
email produced to the Subcommittee, Peter Krawiec, Amazon’s Vice
President of Worldwide Corporate Development, recapped a meet-
ing with a recently acquired company, noting that the company
was ‘‘[s]uper excited about Amazon and relieved that Walmart will
not be the buyer. Engineering team thrilled that they won’t have
to unplug from AWS under a Walmart world.’’
2045
(e) Conduct. The leading position AWS enjoys in the market
traces in part to its first-mover advantage, network effects, and
steep investments that the company made in building out the phys-
ical infrastructure on which the cloud resides. However, AWS has
also engaged in a series of business practices designed to maintain
its market dominance at the expense of choice and innovation.
Through a combination of self-preferencing, misappropriation, and
degradation of interoperability, Amazon has sought to eliminate
cross-platform products with Amazon-only products. Amazon’s con-
duct has already led several open-source projects to become more
closed—a move driven by a need for protection from Amazon’s mis-
appropriation. If unchecked, Amazon’s tactics over the long-term
risk solidifying lock-in and diminishing the incentive to invest. Be-
cause the cloud is the core infrastructure on which the digital econ-
omy runs, ensuring its openness and competitiveness is paramount.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00279 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
274
2046
See supra Section IV.
2047
Interview with Source 152 (Apr. 15, 2020).
2048
Open Source Licenses by Category, O
PEN
S
OURCE
I
NITIATIVE
, https://opensource.org/
licenses/category (last visited Sept. 30, 2020).
2049
Nicholas Loulloudes et al., Enabling Interoperable Cloud Application Management
Through an Open Source Ecosystem, 19 IEEE I
NTERNET
C
OMPUTING
54 (2015), https://
ieeexplore.ieee.org/document/7111887.
2050
Max Schireson & Dharmesh Thakker, The Money in Open-Source Software, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Feb. 9, 2016), https://techcrunch.com/2016/02/09/the-money-in-open-source-software/.
2051
Interview with Source 152 (Apr. 15, 2020).
2052
Id.
2053
Id.
2054
Interview with Source 146 (May 28, 2020).
2055
Interview with Source 31 (May 27, 2020).
(i) Misappropriation of Data. As described earlier in this Report,
cloud platform vendors compete by expanding their first-party
cloud offerings, such as those offered through the AWS Manage-
ment Console.
2046
Market participants note that one way AWS has
expanded its offerings is by creating proprietary versions of prod-
ucts that have been developed under open-source licenses.
2047
Open-source licenses allow software to be freely used, modified,
and shared.
2048
Open-source software can run on any infrastruc-
ture, local machine, server room, or on the cloud, reducing lock-in
to a specific hardware vendor.
2049
Companies based on open-source
software bring in revenue by selling additional features under pro-
prietary licenses or services.
2050
In recent years, open-source devel-
opment has been a leading model for software development, at-
tracting significant venture capital investment.
2051
Market participants note that the rise of cloud computing serv-
ices has led to a shift in the way open-source software is delivered
and used. Many open-source software companies allowed engineers
to download free versions of their software from their website, often
without collecting any personal data about their users. As engi-
neers outgrew the functionality of the free version, they would pur-
chase more powerful versions.
2052
As cloud computing grew in pop-
ularity, open-source software vendors began offering versions of
their software on the AWS Marketplace, where application devel-
opers could easily integrate the software. Market participants ex-
plain that AWS was able to use the data collected on their cus-
tomers, including usage metrics, to learn which third-party soft-
ware was performing well and ultimately to create their own pro-
prietary version offered as a managed service. Creating a ‘‘knock-
off’’ version of software was particularly easy when the product was
using an open-source license, which provides more visibility to the
underlying code.
2053
In interviews with the Subcommittee, market participants re-
peatedly said that AWS relied on innovations from open-source
software communities to gain dominance. A venture capitalist told
the Subcommittee that ‘‘open-source is critical for AWS getting
market power. They’re standing on the shoulders of giants and
they’re not paying the giants.’’
2054
A long-time cloud vendor like-
wise said that ‘‘Amazon never built a database, never built cloud
services, never built any of their AWS offerings. They took open
source and offered it out on [the] cloud. At the time that was inno-
vative.’’
2055
AWS has developed many of its offerings using this practice and
has created products that are only accessible as first-party offerings
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00280 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
275
2056
What Is the AWS Management Console, A
MAZON
W
EB
S
ERVS
., https://docs.aws
.amazon.com/awsconsolehelpdocs/latest/gsg/getting-started.html#learn-whats-new (last visited
Sept. 30, 2020).
2057
Daisuke Wakabayashi, Prime Leverage: How Amazon Wields Power in the Technology
World, N.Y. T
IMES
(Dec. 16, 2019), https://www.nytimes.com/2019/12/15/technology/amazon-
aws-cloud-competition.html. See also Interview with Source 152 (Apr. 15, 2020).
2058
Id.
2059
Id.
2060
Complaint at 2, Elasticsearch, Inc. v. Amazon.com, Inc., No. 4:19–cv–06158 (N.D. Cal.
Sept. 27, 2019), http://ipcasefilings.com/wp-content/uploads/2019/10/ElasticSearchlAmazon
.pdf.
2061
Interview with Source 144 (Apr. 17, 2020).
2062
Server Side Public License FAQ, M
ONGO
DB, https://www.mongodb.com/licensing/server-
side-public-license/faq (last visited Sept. 30, 2020).
2063
CEO Hearing at 285 (response to Questions for the Record of Jeff Bezos, CEO, Ama-
zon.com, Inc.).
2064
Interview with Source 152 (Sept. 24, 2020).
through the AWS Management Console.
2056
An example frequently
cited by market participants is Amazon Elasticsearch Service
(AESS), a tool for searching and analyzing data, and a first-party
product listed on the AWS Management Console.
2057
According to
public reporting and interviews with market participants, this
product is a copy of Elastic’s Elasticsearch open-source product that
was available for purchase on the AWS Marketplace.
2058
According
to public reporting, within a year of introducing the product, Ama-
zon was generating more money from its replica of Elasticsearch
than Elasticsearch itself was generating. One key advantage that
Amazon’s ‘‘knock-off’’ had was that Amazon had given it superior
placement in AWS Management Console.
2059
Additionally, as de-
scribed in the Elasticsearch v. Amazon case, AWS can name their
open-source ‘‘knock-off’’ products in a way that can mislead cus-
tomers into believing that the ‘‘knock-off’’ product is sponsored by
the open-source software vendor.
2060
The Subcommittee’s investigation uncovered evidence relating to
numerous instances in which Amazon has offered proprietary man-
aged services based on knock-offs of open-source code. One open-
source market participant interviewed by the Subcommittee said
that, because of this conduct, the benefits of open source ‘‘weren’t
accruing to [the] open-source community. People were feeling, we
develop all this work and then some large company comes and
monetizes that.’’
2061
MongoDB, a document-based database, has
similarly commented that, ‘‘once an open source project becomes in-
teresting, it is too easy for large cloud vendors to capture all the
value but contribute nothing back to the community.’’
2062
When the Subcommittee inquired about this practice, Amazon re-
sponded that, ‘‘Projects where AWS has developed distributions on
top of OSS [open-source software], like Open Distro for Elastic-
search and Amazon Corretto, add to, not supplant, the set of capa-
bilities provided by the upstream open-source projects .... [I]t al-
lows them to move between deploying OSS themselves and using
managed services for open-source.’’
2063
Market participants told
the Subcommittee, however, that in the instances when AWS cre-
ates a ‘‘knock-off’’ version of an open-source software by adding ‘‘ad-
ditional developments,’’ those additional developments often only
work with AWS infrastructure and are no longer cross-platform—
heightening the risk of lock-in.
2064
As one third-party explains, ‘‘So,
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00281 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
276
2065
Id.
2066
Jeff Barr, New-Amazon DocumentDB (with MongoDB Compatibility): Fast, Scalable, and
Highly Available, A
MAZON
W
EB
S
ERVS
.: AWS N
EWS
B
LOG
(Jan. 9, 2019), https://aws
.amazon.com/blogs/aws/new-amazon-documentdb-with-mongodb-compatibility-fast-scalable-
and-highly-available/.
2067
Interview with Source 152 (Sept. 24, 2020).
2068
Open Source Licenses by Category, O
PEN
S
OURCE
I
NITIATIVE
, https://opensource.org/
faq#permissive (last visited Sept. 30, 2020) (‘‘A ‘permissive’ license is simply a non-copyleft open
source license—one that guarantees the freedoms to use, modify, and redistribute, but that per-
mits proprietary derivative works.’’).
2069
Interview with Source 144 (Apr. 17, 2020).
2070
Confluent Community License FAQ, C
ONFLUENT
, https://www.confluent.io/confluent-
community-license-faq/ (last visited Sept. 30, 2020).
2071
Frederic Lardinois, Redis Labs Changes Its Open-Source License—Again, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Feb. 21, 2019), https://techcrunch.com/2019/02/21/redis-labs-changes-its-open-source-license-
again/.
2072
Tom Krazit, Another Open-Source Database Company Will Tighten Its Licensing Strategy,
Wary of Amazon Web Services, G
EEK
W
IRE
(June 4, 2019), https://www.geekwire.com/2019/an-
other-open-source-database-company-will-tighten-licensing-strategy-wary-amazon-web-services/.
2073
Interview with Source 152 (Apr. 15, 2020).
2074
Interview with Source 146 (May 28, 2020).
the earlier benefits of open-source go out the window as Amazon
takes over each of these product areas.’’
2065
For example, while MongoDB is an open-source document-based
database project, Amazon offers a proprietary product called Ama-
zon DocumentDB. According to AWS, DocumentDB implements the
open-source MongoDB API and is designed to ‘‘emulate the re-
sponses that a MongoDB client expects from a MongoDB serv-
er.’’
2066
When a cloud customer chooses to build an application
using DocumentDB they are tied to AWS’s infrastructure. If they
ever wanted to switch to another provider they would have to ex-
tensively re-engineer their product in another software, whereas,
had they built their application using MongoDB—on AWS or any
other cloud provider’s infrastructure—their applications could move
to other platforms.
2067
(ii) Harms to Innovation. Amazon’s practice of offering managed
service versions of open-source software has prompted open-source
software companies to make defensive changes, such as closing off
advanced features and changing their open-source license to be less
permissive.
2068
One open-source vendor that recently started offer-
ing premium closed-sourced features said they were ‘‘paranoid’’ in
light of Amazon cloning Elastic’s features, noting that if this had
happened to them they ‘‘would not have a business.’’
2069
Amazon’s
conduct has also reduced the availability of features in open-source
software. Confluent,
2070
Redis Labs,
2071
and CochroachDB,
2072
along with several other open-source software vendors, have made
similar license and business model changes, reducing the level of
access to their software.
2073
Market participants believe that these changes significantly un-
dermine innovation. Several noted that more closed-off licenses will
result in fewer free, open-source features available to startups
building prototypes and research labs that cannot afford access to
paid features.
2074
The Subcommittee also spoke with cloud com-
puting customers in the public sector who worry about the changes
and ambiguity in open-source licenses. One cloud computing cus-
tomer told the Subcommittee that three pieces of open-source soft-
ware that they use underwent license changes in the last year and
that, due to strict ‘‘open source only’’ policies, they are ‘‘now stuck
using older versions of the software [from] before the license
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00282 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
277
2075
Interview with Source 49 (May 20, 2020).
2076
Interview with Source 126 (June 29, 2020).
2077
Interview with Source 146 (May 28, 2020).
2078
Interview with Source 152 (Sept. 24, 2020).
2079
Amazon Virtual Private Cloud, A
MAZON
W
EB
S
ERVS
., https://aws.amazon.com/vpc/ (last
visited Sept. 30, 2020).
2080
Daisuke Wakabayashi, Prime Leverage, How Amazon Wields Power in the Technology
World, N.Y. T
IMES
(Dec. 16, 2019), https://www.nytimes.com/2019/12/15/technology/amazon-
aws-cloud-competition.html.
2081
Interview with Source 146 (May 28, 2020).
2082
Apple, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 1 (Sept. 28, 2019), https://s2.q4cdn.com/
470004039/files/doclfinancials/2019/ar/l10-K-2019-(As-Filed).pdf.
2083
See Angelique Richardson & Ellen Terrell, Apple Computer, Inc., L
IB
.
OF
C
ONG
. (Apr.
2008), https://www.loc.gov/rr/business/businesshistory/April/apple.html.
change which requires additional work to improve the code base,
implement the same functionality in-house or switch to a competi-
tive product.’’
2075
(iii) Self-Preferencing. According to market participants, once a
product—based on open source or otherwise—is available in the
AWS Management Console, it becomes an easier choice for existing
AWS customers relative to purchasing a managed service from a
third-party vendor or self-managing open-source software. In an
interview with the Subcommittee, one startup said they purchased
software services through the AWS Management Console as op-
posed to identical or nearly identical software from a third-party
vendor because they were a small company and, ‘‘instead of us
managing everything, it was hit a button . . . they are all in one,
it was easier.’’
2076
As with all cloud services offered through the
AWS Management Console, customers benefit from a single sign-
on with billing information already in place.
2077
Market participants also note that Amazon makes certain
functionality available to its first-party products that it doesn’t
make available to the companies managing the original version of
the open-source software.
2078
For example, AWS services can run
inside Amazon’s Virtual Private Cloud (Amazon VPC) offering,
which allows users to provision an ‘‘isolated section of the AWS
Cloud,’’ but third-party services cannot do so.
2079
While Amazon failed to provide the Subcommittee with financial
data identifying what AWS makes in revenue from individual cloud
offerings, many marketplace participants believe that AWS makes
more from managed versions of open-source software than the
third-party vendors and managers of the software. In 2019, The
New York Times reported that the Chief Executive of MariaDB, an
open-source relational database company, estimated that ‘‘Amazon
made five times more revenue from running MariaDB software
than his company generated from all of its businesses.’’
2080
Market
participants suggest this multiple of difference in income is likely
for other AWS products based on open-source projects.
2081
D. Apple
1. Overview
Apple was incorporated in 1977 and is headquartered in
Cupertino, California.
2082
Apple was an early pioneer in designing
and marketing mass-produced personal computers.
2083
Today, the
company ‘‘designs, manufacturers, and markets smartphones, per-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00283 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
278
2084
Apple, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 1 (Sept. 28, 2019), https://s2.q4cdn.com/
470004039/files/doclfinancials/2019/ar/l10-K-2019-(As-Filed).pdf.
2085
Id. at 1–2.
2086
See Apple, Apple: Distinctive Products with a Seamless, Integrated User Experience 1
(July 13, 2020) (unpublished white paper) (on file with Comm.).
2087
Are Domestic Investors Missing Out?, S
WELL
, (June 22, 2018), https://swellasset.com.au/
2018/06/domestic-investors-missing/.
2088
Apple, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 19 (Sept. 28, 2019), https://s2.q4cdn.com/
470004039/files/doclfinancials/2019/ar/l10-K-2019-(As-Filed).pdf.
2089
Id. at 17–19; see also Apple’s 1 Crazy Number Key to $800 Billion in Stock Growth,
F
ORBES
(July 13, 2020), https://www.forbes.com/sites/greatspeculations/2020/07/13/how-did-
apple-add-800-billion-in-value-over-3-years/#5b9250df20f8.
2090
Id. at 21, 29.
sonal computers, tablets, wearables, and accessories, and sells a va-
riety of related services.’’
2084
Apple’s hardware products include
the iPhone, iPad, Mac, Apple TV, and AirPods; its Services busi-
ness segment includes the App Store, iCloud, AppleCare, Apple Ar-
cade, Apple Music, Apple TV+, and other services and software ap-
plications.
2085
Apple tightly integrates its services and software ap-
plications with its products to ensure a seamless experience for
consumers.
2086
Apple’s Ecosystem: Hardware, Software Infrastructure,
Apple & Third-Party Apps
2087
Apple reports financial information for two business categories:
Products and Services.
2088
For Fiscal Year 2019, Apple reported
total revenue of approximately $260 billion, down 2 percent from
2018, but up nearly 13.5 percent from 2017.
2089
Apple’s margins to-
taled 37.8 percent, with profits of $98.3 billion.
2090
As of September
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00284 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 24 here 11701.024
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
279
2091
Jessica Bursztynsky, Apple Becomes First U.S. Company to Reach a $2 Trillion Market
Cap, CNBC (Aug. 19, 2020), https://www.cnbc.com/2020/08/19/apple-reaches-2-trillion-mar-
ket-cap.html.
2092
Kif Leswing, Apple’s $2 Trillion Value Is Proof that Tim Cook’s Services Plan Worked,
CNBC (Aug. 19, 2020), https://www.cnbc.com/2020/08/19/apples-2-trillion-value-proof-that-
tim-cooks-services-plan-worked.html.
2093
See S. O’Dea, Manufacturers’ Market Share of Smartphone Sales in the United States
from 2016 to 2020, S
TATISTA
(Sept. 3, 2020), https://www.statista.com/statistics/620805/
smartphone-sales-market-share-in-the-us-by-vendor/; S. O’Dea, Manufacturers’ Market Share of
Smartphone Subscribers in the United States from 2013 and 2019, by Month*, S
TATISTA
(June
9, 2020), https://www.statista.com/statistics/273697/market-share-held-by-the-leading-smart
phone-manufacturers-oem-in-the-us/; US Smartphone Market Share: By Quarter, C
OUNTERPOINT
R
SCH
. (Aug. 17, 2020), https://www.counterpointresearch.com/us-market-smartphone-share/; S.
O’Dea, Share of Smartphone Users that Use an Apple iPhone in the United States from 2014
to 2021, S
TATISTA
(Sept. 10, 2020), https://www.statista.com/statistics/236550/percentage-of-us-
population-that-own-a-iphone-smartphone/.
2094
S. O’Dea, Share of Smartphone Users that Use an Apple iPhone in the United States from
2014 to 2021, S
TATISTA
(Sept. 10, 2020), https://www.statista.com/statistics/236550/percentage-
of-us-population-that-own-a-iphone-smartphone/.
2095
See S. O’Dea, Subscriber Share Held by Smartphone Operating Systems in the United
States from 2012 to 2020, S
TATISTA
(Aug. 17, 2020), https://www.statista.com/statistics/
266572/market-share-held-by-smartphone-platforms-in-the-united-states/; Mobile Operating Sys-
tem Market Share United States of America Aug. 2019–Aug. 2020, G
LOBAL
S
TATS
(on file with
Comm.).
2096
See Global Smartphone Market Share: By Quarter, C
OUNTERPOINT
R
SCH
., (Aug. 18, 2020),
https://www.counterpointresearch.com/global-smartphone-share/; Mobile Operating System
Market Share Worldwide Aug. 2019–Aug. 2020, G
LOBAL
S
TATS
(on file with Comm.).
2097
Malcolm Owen, How Apple Has Hit 2 Billion iOS Devices Sold, and When It Will Hit
2 Billion iPhones, A
PPLE
I
NSIDER
(Sept. 13, 2018), https://appleinsider.com/articles/18/09/13/
how-apple-has-hit-2-billion-ios-devices-sold-and-when-it-will-hit-2-billion-iphones.
2098
See Letter from Kyle Andeer, Vice President Legal & Chief Compliance Officer, Apple,
Inc., to Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Doug Collins, Ranking
Member, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust,
Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James Sensen-
brenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.
Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with Comm.); Letter from Kyle Andeer, Vice
President, Corp. Law & Chief Compliance Officer, Apple, Inc., to Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair,
H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Jim Jordan, Ranking Member, H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.
Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James Sensenbrenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Anti-
trust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Sept. 21, 2020) (on
file with Comm.).
2020, Apple is the most valuable public company in the world and,
in August 2020, became the first publicly traded U.S. firm to be
valued at $2 trillion.
2091
Apple’s stock rose by 60 percent in the
first 8 months of 2020.
2092
Apple is the leading smartphone vendor in the U.S., accounting
for approximately 45 percent of the domestic market,
2093
with more
than 100 million iPhone users nationwide.
2094
Apple’s iOS is also
one of two dominant mobile operating systems—the other operating
system, Android, is discussed elsewhere in this Report. iOS runs on
more than half of U.S. smartphones and tablets.
2095
Globally,
Apple accounts for less than 20 percent of the smartphone market,
and roughly 25 percent of smartphones and tablets run on iOS
worldwide.
2096
In 2018, Apple sold its two-billionth iOS device and
is projected to sell its two-billionth iPhone by 2021.
2097
Apple also owns and operates the App Store for iOS devices.
Launched in 2008, Apple highlights that the App Store allows app
developers to reach consumers in 155 countries, and that more
than 27 million app developers have published millions of apps in
the App Store. Apple credits the App Store with creating 1.5 mil-
lion jobs in the United States and more than $120 billion in world-
wide revenue for app developers.
2098
According to Apple, the App
Store ecosystem, including direct sales of apps, sales of goods and
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00285 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
280
2099
Letter from Kyle Andeer, Vice President, Corp. Law & Chief Compliance Officer, Apple,
Inc., to Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Jim Jordan, Ranking
Member, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust,
Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James Sensen-
brenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.
Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Sept. 21, 2020) (on file with Comm.) (citing J
ONATHAN
B
ORCK ET
AL
., A
NALYSIS
G
RP
., H
OW
L
ARGE
I
S THE
A
PPLE
A
PP
S
TORE
E
COSYSTEM
: A G
LOBAL
P
ERSPECTIVE
FOR
2019, at 4 (2020), https://www.apple.com/newsroom/pdfs/app-store-study-2019.pdf).
2100
See Celia Kang et al., Antitrust Troubles Snowball for Tech Giants as Lawmakers Join
In, N.Y. T
IMES
(June 3, 2019), https://www.nytimes.com/2019/06/03/technology/facebook-ftc-
antitrust.html; Brent Kendall & John McKinnon, Congress, Enforcement Agencies Target Tech,
W
ALL
S
T
. J. (June 3, 2019), https://www.wsj.com/articles/ftc-to-examine-how-facebook-s-prac-
tices-affect-digital-competition-11559576731.
2101
See, e.g., Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Opens Investigation into
Apple Practices Regarding Apple Pay (June 16, 2020), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/
presscorner/detail/en/ipl20l1075; Foo Yun Chee, Apple in Dutch Antitrust Spotlight for Al-
legedly Promoting Own Apps, R
EUTERS
(Apr. 11, 2019), https://www.reuters.com/article/us-
apple-antitrust-netherlands/apple-in-dutch-antitrust-spotlight-for-allegedly-promoting-own-apps-
idUSKCN1RN215; Italy Antitrust Opens Inquiry into Google, Apple, Dropbox on Cloud Com-
puting, R
EUTERS
(Sept. 7, 2020), https://www.reuters.com/article/us-google-italy-antitrust/italy-
antitrust-opens-inquiry-into-google-apple-dropbox-on-cloud-computing-idUSKBN25Y0YM; Tim
Hardwick, Apple and Amazon Under Investigation by Italian Watchdog for Alleged Price Fixing,
A
PPLE
I
NSIDER
(July 22, 2020), https://www.macrumors.com/2020/07/22/apple-amazon-italy-
alleged-price-fixing/.
2102
See, e.g., Nick Statt, Epic Games Is Suing Apple, V
ERGE
(Aug. 13, 2020), https://www
.theverge.com/2020/8/13/21367963/epic-fortnite-legal-complaint-apple-ios-app-store-removal-in-
junctive-relief; Reed Albergotti, Apple Suppressed Competitors in Its App Store—Until It Got
Caught, a Lawsuit Alleges, W
ASH
. P
OST
(Dec. 20, 2019), https://www.washingtonpost
.com/technology/2019/12/20/apple-suppressed-competitors-its-app-store-until-it-got-caught-law-
suit-alleges/; Bob Van Voris & Peter Blumberg, Apple App Developers Jump on Silicon Valley
Antitrust Bandwagon, B
LOOMBERG
(June 4, 2019), https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/
2019-06-04/apple-inc-sued-by-app-developers-claiming-antitrust-violations; David G. Savage &
Suhauna Hussain, Supreme Court Rules Apple Can Face Antitrust Suits from iPhone Owners
over App Store Sales, L.A. T
IMES
(May 13, 2019), https://www.latimes.com/politics/la-na-pol-
supreme-court-apple-smart-phone-20190513-story.html.
2103
See Complaint, United States v. Apple, Inc., 952 F. Supp. 2d 638 (S.D.N.Y. 2013) (No.12–
cv–2826).
2104
See United States v. Apple, Inc., 952 F. Supp. 2d 638 (S.D.N.Y. 2013), aff’d, 791 F.3d 209
(2d Cir. 2015); Dawn Chmielewski, Apple to Pay $450 Million E-Book Settlement After Supreme
Court Waves Off Case, V
OX
: R
ECODE
(Mar. 7, 2016), https://www.vox.com/2016/3/7/11586748/
apple-to-pay-450-million-e-book-settlement-after-supreme-court-waves; see also Aug. 27, 2013 Hr’g
Tr. at 17:1–6, United States v. Apple, Inc., 952 F. Supp. 2d 638 (S.D.N.Y. 2013) (No. 12–cv–2826)
(‘‘The record at trial demonstrated a blatant and aggressive disregard at Apple for the require-
ments of the law. Apple executives used their considerable skills to orchestrate a price-fixing
scheme that significantly raised the prices of E-books. This conduct included Apple lawyers and
its highest level executives.’’); Philip Elmer-Dewitt, ‘‘I’d Do It Again,’’ Says the Man at the Center
of Apple’s E-book Case, F
ORTUNE
(Dec. 2, 2014), https://fortune.com/2014/12/02/id-do-it-
again-says-the-man-at-the-center-of-apples-e-book-case/.
services inside of apps, and in-app advertising, facilitated more
than $138 billion in economic activity in the U.S. last year.
2099
In addition to the Subcommittee’s investigation of Apple’s market
power and conduct, federal antitrust authorities are investigating
the company for potential violations of the U.S. antitrust laws. In
June 2019, The New York Times and The Wall Street Journal re-
ported that the Justice Department had opened investigations into
potential violations of the antitrust laws by Apple.
2100
Apple is also
under investigation by multiple international competition authori-
ties for antitrust violations and anticompetitive practices,
2101
in ad-
dition to facing private antitrust lawsuits in the U.S.
2102
Previously, the Justice Department and attorneys general of 33
states sued Apple for orchestrating a conspiracy to fix prices in the
eBooks market in 2012.
2103
Apple was found to have violated state
and federal antitrust laws and was forced to pay $450 mil-
lion.
2104
In 2010, Apple settled an antitrust complaint with the De-
partment of Justice alleging that it had conspired with several
other technology companies to eliminate competition for employees
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00286 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
281
2105
Press Release, U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Department Requires Six High Tech Companies to
Stop Entering into Anticompetitive Employee Solicitation Agreements (Sept. 24, 2010), https://
www.justice.gov/opa/pr/justice-department-requires-six-high-tech-companies-stop-entering-anti-
competitive-employee.
2106
Dawn Chmielewski, Silicon Valley Companies Agree to Pay $415 Million to Settle ‘‘No
Poaching’’ Suit, V
OX
: R
ECODE
(Jan. 15, 2015), https://www.vox.com/2015/1/15/11557814/
silicon-valley-companies-agree-to-pay-415-million-to-settle-no.
2107
See Stigler Report at 78 (‘‘[T]he evidence thus far does suggest that current digital plat-
forms face very little threat of entry .... [T]he key players in this industry remained the same
over the last two technology waves, staying dominant through the shift to mobile and the rise
of AI. In the past, dominant businesses found it difficult to navigate innovation or disruption
waves. By contrast, Facebook, Google, Amazon, Apple, and even Microsoft were able to ride
these waves without significant impact on market share or profit margins. This indirect evi-
dence corroborates the argument that these companies are facing few competitive threats.’’).
2108
See supra Section IV.
2109
See S. O’Dea, Subscriber Share Held by Smartphone Operating Systems in the United
States from 2012 to 2020, S
TATISTA
(Aug. 17, 2020), https://www.statista.com/statistics/
266572/market-share-held-by-smartphone-platforms-in-the-united-states/; Mobile Operating Sys-
tem Market Share United States of America Aug. 2019–Aug. 2020, G
LOBAL
S
TATS
(on file with
Comm.); Jason Cipriani, iPad Turns 10: Why Did It Take a Decade for Apple’s Tablet to Get
Its Own Operating System, ZDN
ET
(Jan. 24, 2020), https://www.zdnet.com/article/a-decade-old-
device-why-did-it-take-nine-years-for-the-ipad-to-get-its-own-operating-system/.
2110
See supra Section IV.
2111
CEO Hearing at 80 (statement of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple, Inc.) (responding to a question
about whether Apple alone determines whether apps are admitted to the App Store, Mr. Cook
replied, ‘‘If it’s a native app, yes, sir. If it’s a web app, no.’’).
2112
See supra Section IV.
2113
Owen Williams, Apple Is Trying to Kill Web Technology, O
NE
Z
ERO
(Nov. 7, 2019), https://
onezero.medium.com/apple-is-trying-to-kill-web-technology-a274237c174d.
through non-solicitation agreements.
2105
It later entered into a
$415 million joint settlement agreement in a class-action lawsuit
filed by affected employees.
2106
2. iOS and the App Store
(a) Market Power. Apple has significant and durable market
power in the market for mobile operating systems and mobile app
stores, both of which are highly concentrated.
2107
Apple’s iOS mo-
bile operating system is one of two dominant mobile operating sys-
tems, along with Google’s Android, in the U.S. and globally.
2108
Apple installs iOS on all Apple mobile devices and does not license
iOS to other mobile device manufacturers. More than half of mobile
devices in the U.S. run on iOS or iPadOS, an iOS derivation for
tablets introduced in 2019.
2109
Apple’s market power is durable due
to high switching costs, ecosystem lock-in, and brand loyalty. It is
unlikely that there will be successful market entry to contest the
dominance of iOS and Android.
As a result, Apple’s control over iOS provides it with gatekeeper
power over software distribution on iOS devices. Consequently, it
has a dominant position in the mobile app store market and mo-
nopoly power over distribution of software applications on iOS de-
vices.
2110
Apple’s App Store is the only method to distribute software appli-
cations on iOS devices.
2111
It does not permit installation of alter-
native app stores on iOS devices, nor does it permit apps to be
sideloaded. As discussed earlier in this Report, consumers have a
strong preference for native apps to web apps,
2112
and Apple has
acknowledged key differences between them. Developers have ex-
plained that Apple actively undermines the open web’s progress on
iOS ‘‘to push developers toward building native apps on iOS rather
than using web technologies.’’
2113
As a result, Apple’s position as
the sole app store on iOS devices is unassailable. Apple fully con-
trols how software can be installed on iOS devices, and CEO Tim
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00287 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
282
2114
CEO Hearing at 397 (response to Questions for the Record of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple,
Inc.).
2115
Phillip Shoemaker, Apple v. Everybody, M
EDIUM
(Mar. 29, 2019), https://medium.com/
@phillipshoemaker/apple-v-everybody-5903039e3be.
2116
Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJC–APPLE–000008 (Oct. 14,
2019) (on file with Comm.).
2117
See CEO Hearing at 27, 81 (statement of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple, Inc.); see also Submis-
sion from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJC–APPLE–000012 to –000013 (Oct. 14, 2019)
(on file with Comm.).
2118
Anita Balakrishnan, Tim Cook: Goal Is to Double Apple’s Services Revenue by 2020,
CNBC (Jan. 31, 2017), https://www.cnbc.com/2017/01/31/tim-cook-on-apple-earnings-call-dou-
ble-services-revenue-by-2020.html.
2119
See Apple (AAPL) Q3 2020 Earnings Call Transcript, M
OTLEY
F
OOL
(July 31, 2020),
https://www.fool.com/earnings/call-transcripts/2020/07/31/apple-aapl-q3-2020-earnings-call-
transcript.aspx.
2120
Apple, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 19 (Sept. 28, 2019), https://s2.q4cdn.com/
470004039/files/doclfinancials/2019/ar/l10-K-2019-(As-Filed).pdf.
2121
Id. at 21; Apple, Inc., Quarterly Report (Form 10–Q) 28 (June 27, 2020), https://
s2.q4cdn.com/470004039/files/doclfinancials/2020/q3/l10-Q-Q3-2020-(As-Filed).pdf.
Cook has explained that the company has no plan to permit an al-
ternative app store.
2114
The former director of the app review team
for the App Store observed that Apple is ‘‘not subject to any mean-
ingful competitive constraint from alternative distribution chan-
nels.’’
2115
In response to these concerns, Apple has not produced any evi-
dence that the App Store is not the sole means of distributing apps
on iOS devices and that it does not exert monopoly power over app
distribution. Apple says it does not create data—nor is it aware of
third-party data—that tracks market share in the app distribution
market.
2116
Apple claims the App Store competes in a larger soft-
ware distribution market that includes other mobile app stores as
well as the open internet, personal computers, gaming consoles,
smart TVs, and online and brick-and-mortar retail stores.
2117
While consumers can access software and developers can distribute
software through those platforms, none of those platforms permit
consumers to access apps on an iOS device or developers to dis-
tribute apps to iOS devices.
Apple’s monopoly power over software distribution on iOS de-
vices appears to allow it to generate supranormal profits from the
App Store and its Services business. Apple CEO Tim Cook set a
goal in 2017 to rapidly double the size of the Services business by
the end of 2020.
2118
Apple met this goal by July 2020, six months
ahead of schedule.
2119
The Services business accounted for nearly
18 percent of total revenue in Fiscal Year 2019, about $46.2 billion.
Services grew faster than Products in recent years, increasing by
more than 41 percent since 2017.
2120
The Services category is also
Apple’s highest margin business at 63.7 percent in Fiscal Year
2019 and 67.2 percent for the quarter ending in June 2020.
2121
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00288 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
283
2122
Prepared by the Subcommittee based on Apple, Inc., Annual Reports (Form 10–K) (2017–
2019).
2123
See, e.g., Kif Leswing, Apple’s $2 Trillion Value Is Proof that Tim Cook’s Services Plan
Worked, CNBC (Aug. 19, 2020), https://www.cnbc.com/2020/08/19/apples-2-trillion-value-
proof-that-tim-cooks-services-plan-worked.html; Anne Sraders, As Apple Stock Tops $500, Bulls
Cite These Key Reasons It Could Still Go Higher, F
ORTUNE
(Aug. 24, 2020), https://fortune.com/
2020/08/24/apple-stock-tops-500-can-it-go-higher/.
2124
Apple, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 22, 26 (Sept. 29, 2018), https://www.sec.gov/
Archives/edgar/data/320193/000032019318000145/a10-k20189292018.htm; Apple, Inc., An-
nual Report (Form 10–K) 22, 26 (Sept. 30, 2017), https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/
320193/000032019317000070/a10-k20179302017.htm.
2125
Apple, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 19 (Sept. 28, 2019), https://s2.q4cdn.com/
470004039/files/doclfinancials/2019/ar/l10-K-2019-(As-Filed).pdf; Apple, Inc., Annual Re-
port (Form 10–K) 25 (Sept. 29, 2018), https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/320193/
000032019318000145/a10-k20189292018.htm; Apple, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10–K) 25 (Sept.
30, 2017), https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/320193/000032019317000070/a10-
k20179302017.htm. AppleCare is Apple’s extended warranty product for Apple devices. See
Jason Cross, AppleCare+: Everything You Need to Know About Apple’s Extended Warranty Pro-
gram, M
AC
W
ORLD
(Sept. 16, 2020), https://www.macworld.com/article/3227045/applecare-war-
ranty-faq.html. In addition to the markets discussed in this Section, the Committee sought infor-
mation and continues to investigate competition and conduct in the resale and repair markets
for Apple products.
2126
Lauren Feiner, Apple Buys a Company Every Few Weeks, Says CEO Tim Cook, CNBC
(May 6, 2019), https://www.cnbc.com/2019/05/06/apple-buys-a-company-every-few-weeks-says-
ceo-tim-cook.html.
Annual Revenue by Segment
2122
Industry observers credit Apple’s successful focus on growing the
Services business for its rising valuation and long-term future.
2123
Apple has attributed the growth of Services as a driver of the firm’s
profits from sales and an important factor supporting Apple’s over-
all margins as hardware sales slowed or declined.
2124
The company
has consistently credited the App Store, licensing sales, and
AppleCare for the success of Services.
2125
(b) Merger Activity. In 2019, Apple CEO Tim Cook told CNBC
that Apple buys a new company every two-to-three weeks, focusing
on acquiring ‘‘talent and intellectual property.’’
2126
In July 2020,
Mr. Cook explained that Apple’s ‘‘approach on acquisitions has
been to buy companies where we have challenges, and IP, and then
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00289 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 25 here 11701.025
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
284
2127
Kif Leswing, Tim Cook Says Apple Buys Innovation, not Competitors, CNBC (July 31,
2020), https://www.cnbc.com/2020/07/31/tim-cook-contrasts-apple-ma-with-other-big-tech.html.
2128
Apple, Apple: Distinctive Products with a Seamless, Integrated User Experience 2 (July
13, 2020) (unpublished white paper) (on file with Comm.).
2129
See Jordan Novet, Apple Buys an A.I. Start-up that Came from Microsoft Co-Founder
Paul Allen’s Research Lab, CNBC (Jan. 15, 2020), https://www.cnbc.com/2020/01/15/apple-ac-
quires-xnor-ai-startup-that-spun-out-of-allen-institute.html; Mark Gurman, Apple Acquires AI
Startup to Better Understand Natural Language, B
LOOMBERG
(Apr. 3, 2020), https://
www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2020-04-03/apple-acquires-ai-startup-to-better-understand-
natural-language; Kif Leswing, Apple Buys Virtual Reality Company NextVR, CNBC (May 14,
2020), https://www.cnbc.com/2020/05/14/apple-buys-virtual-reality-company-nextvr.html; Kif
Leswing, Apple Buys Fleetsmith, a Company Making It Easier to Deploy iPhones and Macs at
Workplaces, CNBC (June 24, 2020), https://www.cnbc.com/2020/06/24/apple-acquires-device-
management-company-fleetsmith.html; Jessica Bursztynsky, Apple Buys Popular Weather App
Dark Sky and Plans to Shut Down Android Versions, CNBC (Mar. 31, 2020), https://
www.cnbc.com/2020/03/31/apple-buys-popular-weather-app-dark-sky.html; Mark Gurman,
Apple Buys Startup to Turn iPhones into Payment Terminals, B
LOOMBERG
(July 31, 2020),
https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2020-08-01/apple-buys-startup-to-turn-iphones-into-
payment-terminals.
2130
Press Release, Apple, Apple to Acquire the Majority of Intel’s Smartphone Modem Busi-
ness (July 25, 2019), https://www.apple.com/newsroom/2019/07/apple-to-acquire-the-majority-
of-intels-smartphone-modem-business/.
2131
Anita Balakrishnan, Apple Buys Texture, a Digital Magazine Subscription Service, CNBC
(Mar. 12, 2018), https://www.cnbc.com/2018/03/12/apple-buys-texture-a-digital-magazine-sub-
scription-service.html.
2132
Billy Steele, Apple’s $3 Billion Purchase of Beats Has Already Paid Off, E
NGADGET
(May
28, 2019), https://www.engadget.com/2019-05-28-apple-beats-five-years-later.html.
2133
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 62.
2134
Press Release, Apple, Apple Acquires Shazam, Offering More Ways to Discover and Enjoy
Music (Sept. 24, 2018), https://www.apple.com/newsroom/2018/09/apple-acquires-shazam-of-
fering-more-ways-to-discover-and-enjoy-music/; Mark Gurman, Apple Buys Startup that Creates
Radio-Like Stations for Podcasts, B
LOOMBERG
(Sept. 24, 2020), https://www.bloomberg.com/
news/articles/2020-09-24/apple-buys-startup-that-creates-radio-like-stations-for-podcasts.
make them a feature of the phone.’’
2127
An Apple submission to the
Subcommittee explains that it:
[H]as not embarked on a strategy of acquiring nascent competitors in service of
its growth and market position. Instead, Apple’s acquisitions generally are
meant to complement its product business by accelerating innovation and build-
ing out new features and technologies for Apple’s hardware and software offer-
ings.
2128
In 2020, Apple continued acquiring small firms, including artifi-
cial intelligence and virtual reality startups, an enterprise software
maker, a contactless payment startup, and a weather application,
among others.
2129
One of Apple’s largest transactions occurred in
2019 when it paid $1 billion to acquire Intel’s smartphone modem
business.
2130
Apple has also recently acquired software companies to create a
foundation from which it could launch new apps. For example,
after purchasing the digital magazine subscription service Texture
in 2018, Apple integrated most of Texture’s functionality into its
own Apple News+ service, which debuted the following
year.
2131
Similarly, one of Apple’s largest purchases to date—its $3
billion acquisition of Beats Electronics in 2014—was instrumental
to the 2015 launch of Apple Music.
2132
Apple sought to grow Apple
Music quickly after its introduction. Apple pre-installed the service
on iPhones and made it the only music service accessible through
Siri, Apple’s virtual assistant. Apple also offered Apple Music with
a free month trial period and made it available on Android devices.
The strategy saw Apple gain 10 million paying subscribers within
six months.
2133
Apple supplemented its music services business in
2018 by acquiring the music recognition app Shazam, and most re-
cently, by acquiring podcast app Scout FM in 2020.
2134
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00290 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
285
2135
Chris Gayomali, Swell Shuts Down Following Apple Acquisition, F
AST
C
O
. (July 29,
2014), https://www.fastcompany.com/3033698/swell-shuts-down-following-apple-acquisition;
Andrew Nusca, Apple Maps vs. Google Maps Heats Up as Apple Shuts Down HopStop, F
ORTUNE
(Sept. 12, 2015), https://fortune.com/2015/09/12/hopstop-apple-shutdown/.
2136
Hannah Klein, The Dark Sky Android App is Officially Kaput, S
LATE
(Aug. 4, 2020),
https://slate.com/technology/2020/08/dark-sky-app-android-shuts-down.html.
2137
Jared Newman, Apple’s Dark Sky Acquisition Could Be Bad News for Indie Weather Apps,
F
AST
C
O
. (Apr. 2, 2020), https://www.fastcompany.com/90485131/apples-dark-sky-acquisition-
could-be-bad-news-for-indie-weather-apps. But see CEO Hearing at 403 (response to Questions
for the Record of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple, Inc.) (noting Dark Sky will ‘‘continue to make its API
available to Dark Sky’s existing customers until the end of 2021’’).
2138
App Store: Dedicated to the Best Store Experience for Everyone, A
PPLE
, https://
www.apple.com/ca/ios/app-store/principles-practices/ (last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
2139
Id.
2140
See Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 584–85 (response to Questions for the
Record of Kyle Andeer, Vice President, Corp. Law, Apple, Inc.); Submission from ProtonMail,
to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Aug. 22, 2020) (on file with Comm.); Interview with Source
143 (Aug. 27, 2020).
2141
See, e.g., Sara Morrison, Apple’s Fortnite Ban, Explained, V
OX
: R
ECODE
(Sept. 8, 2020),
https://www.vox.com/recode/2020/8/20/21373780/fortnite-epic-apple-lawsuit-app-store-anti-
trust; Nick Statt, Apple Doubles Down on Controversial Decision to Reject Email App Hey,
V
ERGE
(June 18, 2020), https://www.theverge.com/2020/6/18/21296180/apple-hey-email-app-
basecamp-rejection-response-controversy-antitrust-regulation.
2142
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 585 (response to Questions for the Record
of Kyle Andeer, Vice President, Corp. Law, Apple, Inc.); see also Mark Gurman, Apple Defends
Continued
It is common for Apple to integrate apps it purchases into its
own pre-existing apps or into the iOS mobile operating system. Ex-
amples of this include the 2014 acquisition of Swell, a podcast app,
and the 2013 acquisition of HopStop, a transit navigation app.
2135
Apple has followed a similar strategy for integrating the Dark
Sky weather app. Apple shut down Dark Sky’s Android app in Au-
gust 2020 and plans to integrate the app’s features with the
iPhone’s Weather widget on iOS 14.
2136
In addition to its app,
Dark Sky supplied data to independent weather apps, like Carrot,
Weather Line, and Partly Sunny. As a result of Apple’s takeover
of Dark Sky, independent weather apps will lose access to the inex-
pensive, hyper-local weather data that Dark Sky supplied, leading
some weather apps to shut down and others to rely on higher-
priced suppliers for forecast data.
2137
(c) Conduct
(i) Commissions and In-App Purchases. The Committee sought
information regarding Apple’s policy of collecting commissions from
apps sold through the App Store and purchases made in iOS apps.
Apple charges a 30 percent commission on paid apps—those that
charge a fee for users to download—downloaded from the App
Store. It also takes a 30 percent fee for in-app purchases (IAP) of
‘‘digital goods and services.’’
2138
For app subscriptions, Apple
charges a 30 percent commission for the first year and a 15 percent
commission for subsequent years.
2139
Apps are not permitted to
communicate with iOS users that the app may be available for pur-
chase at a lower price outside the App Store, provide links outside
of the app that may lead users to find alternative subscription and
payment methods, or offer their own payment processing mecha-
nism in the app to avoid using Apple’s IAP.
2140
Apps that violate
Apple’s policies can be removed from the App Store, losing access
to the only means of distributing apps to consumers with iOS de-
vices.
2141
Apple describes its policies as standard industry practice and
says that other app stores charge the same fees.
2142
In 2020, Apple
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00291 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
286
App Store Revenue Take Ahead of Antitrust Hearing, B
LOOMBERG
(July 22, 2020), https://
www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2020-07-22/apple-defends-app-store-revenue-cut-ahead-of-
antitrust-hearing; David Pierce & Emily Birnbaum, Apple Defends Its App Store Tax Ahead of
Antitrust Hearings, P
ROTOCOL
(July 22, 2020), https://www.protocol.com/apple-app-store-com-
mission-study.
2143
See J
ONATHAN
B
ORCK ET AL
., A
NALYSIS
G
RP
., A
PPLE
S
A
PP
S
TORE AND
O
THER
D
IGITAL
M
ARKETPLACES
: A C
OMPARISON OF
C
OMMISSION
R
ATES
2, 5–6 (2020), https://www
.analysisgroup.com/globalassets/insights/publishing/appleslapplstorelandlotherldigital
lmarketplaceslalcomparisonloflcommissionlrates.pdf.
2144
See CEO Hearing at 150 (statement of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple, Inc.); Letter from Kyle
Andeer, Vice President, Corp. Law & Chief Compliance Officer, Apple, Inc., to Hon. Jerrold Nad-
ler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Jim Jordan, Ranking Member, H. Comm. on the
Judiciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law
of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James Sensenbrenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm.
on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Sept. 21, 2020)
(on file with Comm.).
2145
See J
ONATHAN
B
ORCK ET AL
., A
NALYSIS
G
RP
., A
PPLE
S
A
PP
S
TORE AND
O
THER
D
IGITAL
M
ARKETPLACES
: A C
OMPARISON OF
C
OMMISSION
R
ATES
4 n.5, app. A1 at A–3 (2020), https://
www.analysisgroup.com/globalassets/insights/publishing/appleslapplstorelandlotherl
digitallmarketplaceslalcomparisonlofl commissionlrates.pdf.
2146
See, e.g., Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 68 (statement of Kyle Andeer, Vice
President, Corp. Law, Apple, Inc.); Letter from Timothy Powderly, Apple, Inc., to Hon. David
N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on
the Judiciary & Hon. F. James Sensenbrenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Com-
mercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (July 15, 2019).
2147
App Store Review Guidelines 3.1.3(e): Goods and Services Outside of the App, A
PPLE
,
https://developer.apple.com/app-store/review/guidelines/#goods-and-services-outside-of-the-app
(last visited Sept. 27, 2020).
2148
See, e.g., Sarah Perez & Anthony Ha, Apple Revises App Store Rules to Permit Game
Streaming Apps, Clarify In-App Purchases and More, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Sept. 11, 2020), https://
techcrunch.com/2020/09/11/apple-revises-app-store-rules-to-permit-game-streaming-apps-clarify
-in-app-purchases-and-more/; Phillip Shoemaker, Apple v. Everybody, M
EDIUM
(Mar. 29, 2019),
https://medium.com/@phillipshoemaker/apple-v-everybody-5903039e3be.
2149
App Store Review Guidelines 3.1.3(a): ‘‘Reader’’ Apps, A
PPLE
, https://developer
.apple.com/app-store/review/guidelines/#reader-apps (last visited Sept. 27, 2020).
2150
CEO Hearing at 402 (response to Questions for the Record of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple,
Inc.).
funded a study that concluded that other software distribution
platforms run by Google, Amazon, Samsung, Microsoft, and others
charge identical or similar commissions on software downloads and
transactions, and that commissions are common in other digital
markets.
2143
Apple also highlighted that its commissions are lower
than the cost of software distribution by brick-and-mortar retailers,
which dominated the marketplace prior to the introduction of the
App Store.
2144
The Apple-commissioned study explained that Apple
funds the App Store through a $99 annual fee it charges to devel-
opers and $299 for developers building enterprise apps, as well as
the commission and fees collected on apps and in-app pur-
chases.
2145
Apple also noted that 84 percent of all apps distributed through
the App Store pay no commissions or fees.
2146
Apple does not take
a commission on purchases from apps like Uber or Etsy that sell
‘‘physical goods or services that will be consumed outside the
app.’’
2147
Apple also makes some exceptions to its rules and may
change or update its rules.
2148
For example, Apple has an excep-
tion for ‘‘Reader’’ apps such as Netflix and Kindle that permit users
to access content purchased outside the app, but do not allow for
in-app subscriptions or purchases.
2149
Apple also makes exceptions
for ‘‘third-party premium video apps’’ that integrate with Apple TV
and other Apple services.
2150
Mr. Cook explained, ‘‘[t]oday, there
are over 130 apps that participate in this program,’’ and ‘‘[t]he re-
duced 15 percent commission is available to all developers offering
premium video content on the same terms as Amazon Prime Video,
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00292 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
287
2151
Id.
2152
Nick Statt, Apple Now Lets Some Video Streaming Apps Bypass the App Store Cut, V
ERGE
(Apr. 1, 2020), https://www.theverge.com/2020/4/1/21203630/apple-amazon-prime-video-ios-
app-store-cut-exempt-program-deal. See also Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judici-
ary, HJC–APPLE–015111 (Nov. 1, 2016) (on file with Comm.) (showing details of negotiations
between Eddy Cue, Senior Vice President, Internet Software and Services, Apple, Inc., and Jeff
Bezos, CEO, Amazon.com, Inc.).
2153
See Submission from ProtonMail, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 11–12 (Aug. 22, 2020)
(on file with Comm.).
2154
See id. Apple has pointed to these as benchmarks for the App store. See J
ONATHAN
B
ORCK ET AL
., A
NALYSIS
G
RP
., A
PPLE
S
A
PP
S
TORE AND
O
THER
D
IGITAL
M
ARKETPLACES
: A C
OM
-
PARISON OF
C
OMMISSION
R
ATES
4–6 (2020), https://www.analysisgroup.com/globalassets/
insights/publishing/appleslapplstorelandlotherldigitallmarketplaceslalcomparisonl
oflcommissionlrates.pdf.
2155
See Submission from ProtonMail, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Aug. 22, 2020) (on
file with Comm.).
2156
See CEO Hearing at 151 (statement of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple, Inc.); Letter from Kyle
Andeer, Vice President, Corp. Law & Chief Compliance Officer, Apple, Inc., to Hon. Jerrold Nad-
ler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Jim Jordan, Ranking Member, H. Comm. on the
Judiciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law
of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James Sensenbrenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm.
on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Sept. 21, 2020)
(on file with Comm.).
with the same qualification criteria.’’
2151
Amazon Prime Video,
Altice One, and Canal+ have been publicly confirmed as partici-
pants.
2152
During the investigation, the Subcommittee received evidence
from app developers regarding Apple’s commissions and fees for
IAPs. ProtonMail, a secure email provider, explained that Apple’s
justification of its 30 percent commission overlooks the dynamics of
the marketplace for distributing software to consumers with iOS
devices—conflating practices that may be unremarkable in com-
petitive markets but abusive in monopoly markets.
2153
For example, personal computer (PC) users can install software
from app stores run by Microsoft, Google, Amazon, and others or
download software directly from the software developer’s website
and bypass app stores altogether. Similarly, Apple’s Mac App Store
is one of many options for Mac users to download software. While
Samsung is a global leader in smartphones, the Samsung Galaxy
Store is one of several app stores available on Samsung’s mobile
devices. Google’s Play Store dominates app distribution on Android
devices and is the most apt comparison to the App Store, but
Google permits some competition via sideloading and alternative
app stores.
2154
In contrast, Apple owns the iOS operating system as well as the
only means to distribute software on iOS devices. Using its role as
an operating system provider, Apple prohibits alternatives to the
App Store and charges fees and commissions for some categories of
apps to reach customers. It responds to attempts to circumvent its
fees and commissions with removal from the App Store.
2155
Be-
cause of this policy, developers have no other option than to play
by Apple’s rules to reach customers who own iOS devices. Owners
of iOS devices have no alternative means to install apps on their
phones. Apple notes that its 30 percent commission has remained
static for most apps for more than a decade.
2156
A group of devel-
opers that filed a lawsuit against Apple challenging this policy
argue that the persistence of Apple’s 30 percent rate over time, ‘‘de-
spite the inevitable accrual of experience and economies of scale,’’
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00293 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
288
2157
Class Action Complaint at 2, Cameron v. Apple, Inc., No. 5:19–cv–3074 (N.D. Cal. June
4, 2019).
2158
See supra Section IV.
2159
See Rob Pegoraro, What Tim Cook Left Out of His Version of App Store History, F
ORBES
(July 29, 2020), https://www.forbes.com/sites/robpegoraro/2020/07/29/what-tim-cook-left-out-
of-his-version-of-app-store-history/.
2160
John Gruber, Parsing Tim Cook’s Opening Statement from Today’s Congressional Anti-
trust Hearing, D
ARING
F
IREBALL
(July 29, 2020), https://daringfireball.net/2020/07/
parsinglcookslopeninglstatement.
2161
See, e.g., Submission from Source 711, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, app. A, at 4–8 (Oct.
15, 2019) (on file with Comm.); Submission from Source 202, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 22–
41 (Oct. 18, 2018); Submission from Source 736, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 6–10 (Oct. 31,
2019) (on file with Comm.).
2162
See Global App Revenue Grew 23% Year-Over-Year Last Quarter to $21.9 Billion,
S
ENSOR
T
OWER
(Oct. 23, 2019), https://sensortower.com/blog/app-revenue-and-downloads-q3-
2019; Prachi Bhardwaj & Shayanne Gal, Despite Android’s Growing Market Share, Apple Users
Continue to Spend Twice as Much Money on Apps as Android Users, B
US
. I
NSIDER
(July 6,
2018), https://www.businessinsider.com/apple-users-spend-twice-apps-vs-android-charts-2018-7.
2163
See Mobile Operating System Loyalty: High and Steady, C
ONSUMER
I
NTEL
. R
SCH
. P
ART
-
NERS
(Mar. 8, 2018), http://files.constantcontact.com/150f9af2201/4bca9a19-a8b0-46bd-95bd-
85740ff3fb5d.pdf; iPhone vs. Android—Cell Phone Brand Loyalty Survey 2019, S
ELL
C
ELL
(Aug.
20, 2019), https://www.sellcell.com/blog/iphone-vs-android-cell-phone-brand-loyalty-survey-
2019/; see also M
ORNINGSTAR
E
QUITY
A
NALYST
R
EPORT
: A
PPLE
, I
NC
. 3 (Aug. 6, 2020) (on file
with Comm.) (‘‘Recent survey data shows that iPhone customers are not even contemplating
switching brands today. In a December 2018 survey by Kantar, 90% of U.S.-based iPhone users
said they planned to remain loyal to future Apple devices.’’); Martin Armstrong, Most iPhone
Users Never Look Back, S
TATISTA
(May 22, 2017), https://www.statista.com/chart/9496/most-
iphone-users-never-look-back/.
2164
See, e.g., Competitors Hearing at 34 (statement of David Heinemeier Hansson, Cofounder
& Chief Tech. Officer, Basecamp); Interview with Source 143 (Aug. 27, 2020); Submission
fromMatch Group, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, MATCH–GRP–00000168 (July 1, 2019) (on
file
indicates there is insufficient competition.
2157
Additionally, as pre-
viously noted, there is little likelihood for new market entry in the
mobile operating system or mobile app store markets to compel
Apple to lower its rates.
2158
Industry observers have also challenged Apple’s implicit claim
that the iPhone was the start of the online software distribution
market. For example, Mac and iOS developer Brent Simmons re-
marked that, ‘‘when the App Store was created, developers were
selling and distributing apps over the web, and it worked wonder-
fully,’’ noting that, he began distributing software over the internet
in the 1990s.
2159
Software designer and technology writer John
Gruber agreed, explaining that, in the mid-1990s, there was ‘‘a
thriving market for software sold directly over a thing called ‘The
Internet,’ ’’ and that Apple’s omission of the fact that ‘‘direct
downloads and sales over the web’’ pre-dated the iPhone by more
than a decade ‘‘is flat-out dishonest.’’
2160
Many developers have stressed that, because Apple dictates that
the App Store is the only way to install software on iOS devices
and requires apps offering ‘‘digital goods and services’’ to imple-
ment the IAP mechanism, Apple has illegally tied IAP to the App
Store.
2161
Consumers with iOS devices account for a disproportion-
ately high amount of spending on apps—spending twice as much
as Android users.
2162
Further, iOS users seldom switch to An-
droid.
2163
Thus, developers cannot abandon the App Store—it is
where the highest value customers are and will remain. As a re-
sult, developers say that Apple abuses control over its valuable
user base by prohibiting alternative payment processing options to
compete with Apple’s IAP mechanism.
Developers further argue that Apple’s 30 percent commission
from IAP is a ‘‘payment processing’’ fee and not a distribution
fee.
2164
In a submission to the Committee, Match Group said,
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00294 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
289
Continued
with Comm.); Submission from Source 482, to H. Comm. on Judiciary, 9 (Oct. 15, 2019) (on file
with Comm.).
2165
Submission from Match Group, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, MATCH–GRP–00000238
(Nov. 1, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
2166
See Submission from ProtonMail, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 11 (Aug. 22, 2020) (on
file with Comm.); Submission from Spotify, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, app. A, at 7–8 (Oct.
15, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
2167
See Apple Developer Program, How the Program Works, A
PPLE
, https://developer
.apple.com/programs/how-it-works/ (last visited Sept. 27, 2020) (‘‘If you’re new to development
on Apple Platforms, you can get started with our tools and resources for free. If you’re ready
to build more advanced capabilities and distribute your apps on the App Store, enroll in the
Apple Developer Program. The cost is 99 USD per membership year.’’).
2168
Letter from Kyle Andeer, Vice President, Corp. Law & Chief Compliance Officer, Apple,
Inc. to Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Doug Collins, Ranking
Member, H. Comm on the Judiciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust,
Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James Sensen-
brenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.
Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Feb. 17, 2020), https://docs.house.gov/meetings/JU/JU05/
20200117/110386/HHRG-116-JU05-20200117-SD004.pdf; see also Letter from Kyle Andeer,
Vice President, Corp. Law & Chief Compliance Officer, Apple, Inc., to Hon. Jerrold Nadler,
Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Jim Jordan, Ranking Member, H. Comm. on the Judici-
ary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the
H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James Sensenbrenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on
Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Sept. 21, 2020)
(on file with Comm.).
2169
Apple, Apple: Distinctive Products with a Seamless, Integrated User Experience 14 (July
13, 2020) (unpublished white paper) (on file with Comm.); see also Letter from Kyle Andeer, Vice
President, Corp. Law & Chief Compliance Officer, Apple, Inc., to Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair,
H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Jim Jordan, Ranking Member, H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.
Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James Sensenbrenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Anti-
trust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Sept. 21, 2020) (on
file with Comm.).
2170
See J
ONATHAN
B
ORCK ET AL
., A
NALYSIS
G
RP
., A
PPLE
S
A
PP
S
TORE AND
O
THER
D
IGITAL
M
ARKETPLACES
: A C
OMPARISON OF
C
OMMISSION
R
ATES
2–3 (2020), https://www.analysis
group.com/globalassets/insights/publishing/appleslapplstorelandlotherldigitall
Continued
‘‘Apple distorts competition in payment processing by making ac-
cess to its App Store conditional on the use of IAP for in-app pur-
chases, thus excluding alternative payment processors. IAP eventu-
ally becomes the vessel through which Apple extracts its extraor-
dinary commissions.’’
2165
Two app developers that offer services
that compete with Apple explained that IAP is a payment proc-
essing fee and not a distribution fee. Both pointed out that Apple
does not charge apps for distribution, evidenced by the fact that
Apple admits to distributing most apps for free. Instead, Apple gen-
erates revenue by adding a 30 percent processing fee on trans-
actions in the App Store and using IAP.
2166
Apple’s Developer Pro-
gram website explains that Apple does charge for distribution—it
requires enrollment in the Apple Developer Program and payment
of a $99 fee to distribute apps on the App Store.
2167
Apple responded that its ‘‘commission is not a payment proc-
essing fee’’ and that it ‘‘reflects the value of the App Store as a
channel for the distribution of developers’ apps and the cost of
many services’’ it incurs to maintain the App Store.
2168
It said that
‘‘[t]he commission also enables Apple to realize a return on its in-
vestment in the App Store and in Apple’s intellectual property, and
to fund future App Store innovation.’’
2169
Similarly, a study com-
missioned by Apple in 2020 explained that the annual fees paid by
developers, commissions, and charges for in-app purchases fund in-
vestments in the App Store ecosystem, such as app review, devel-
oper tools, marketing, search functionality, application program
interfaces, and software development kits.
2170
Apple has also ar-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00295 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
290
marketplaceslal comparisonloflcommissionlrates.pdf; see also Letter from Kyle Andeer,
Vice President, Corp. Law & Chief Compliance Officer, Apple, Inc. to Hon. Jerrold Nadler,
Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Doug Collins, Ranking Member, H. Comm on the Judi-
ciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of
the H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James Sensenbrenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm.
on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Feb. 17, 2020),
https://docs.house.gov/meetings/JU/JU05/20200117/110386/HHRG-116-JU05-20200117-
SD004.pdf.
2171
Kif Leswing, Apple Sued by Fortnite Maker After Kicking the Game out of the App Store
for Payment Policy Violations, CNBC (Aug. 13, 2020), https://www.cnbc.com/2020/08/13/
apple-kicks-fortnite-out-of-app-store-for-challenging-payment-rules.html.
2172
Peter Cohen, ‘‘App Store’’ Will Distribute iPhone Software, M
ACWORLD
(Mar. 6, 2008),
https://www.macworld.com/article/1132402/appstore.html.
2173
Daniel Eran Dilger, Inside Apple’s Shareholder Meeting and Q&A with Tim Cook, A
PPLE
I
NSIDER
(Feb. 23, 2011), https://appleinsider.com/articles/11/02/23/timlcooklpresides
loverlannuallapplelshareholderlmeeting.
2174
Eric J. Savitz, App Stores Could Be Ripe for Regulation. Here’s Who Benefits if Commis-
sions Fall, B
ARRONS
(July 25, 2019), https://www.barrons.com/articles/news-updates-
51599747657.
2175
Kif Leswing, Apple’s App Store Had Gross Sales Around $50 Billion Last Year, but
Growth Is Slowing, CNBC (Jan. 8, 2020), https://www.cnbc.com/2020/01/07/apple-app-store-
had-estimated-gross-sales-of-50-billion-in-2019.html.
2176
Mark Gurman, Apple’s New Services Off to a Slow Start in First Year, B
LOOMBERG
(July
28, 2020), https://www.bloombergquint.com/business/apple-s-new-services-off-to-a-slow-start-in-
first-year.
2177
See Letter from Kyle Andeer, Vice President, Corp. Law & Chief Compliance Officer,
Apple, Inc., to Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Jim Jordan, Rank-
ing Member, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Anti-
trust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James Sensen-
brenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.
gued that its App Store Developer Guidelines—including its re-
quirement to use Apple’s in-app purchase mechanism—is ‘‘designed
to keep the store safe for our users.’’
2171
Apple’s rationale for its commissions and fees has evolved over
time. Its recent explanations of the basis for its 30 percent commis-
sion differs significantly from its explanation of its fee and revenue
expectations in the early years of the App Store. Prior to the App
Store’s debut in 2008, Apple’s then-CEO Steve Jobs explained, ‘‘We
don’t intend to make any money off the App Store .... We’re basi-
cally giving all the money to the developers and the 30 percent that
pays for running the store, that’ll be great.’’
2172
In 2011, Apple’s
Chief Financial Officer Peter Oppenheimer explained to Apple’s
shareholders that Apple runs the App Store ‘‘just a little over break
even.’’
2173
Apple’s financial reports indicate that the App Store is faring far
better than the modest business Apple originally contemplated. Ac-
cording to a 2019 market analysis, Apple’s net revenue from the
App Store is projected to be $17.4 billion for Fiscal Year
2020.
2174
CNBC estimated the App Store had total sales of nearly
$50 billion in 2019, generating ‘‘about $15 billion in revenue for
Apple.’’ With $50 billion in annual sales, CNBC explained, ‘‘the
App Store alone would be no. 64 on the Fortune 500, ahead of Cisco
and behind Morgan Stanley.’’
2175
An analytics firm concluded that
Apple likely made $15.5 billion from the App Store in 2018, and
estimated $18.8 billion for 2022. Bloomberg reported that analysts
forecasting Apple’s third-quarter 2020 performance predicted
growth from Services ‘‘up 15% from a year earlier,’’ and that
growth would largely be attributable to the App Store and licens-
ing, not new services.
2176
In addition to Apple’s commissions and
fees for IAP, App Store revenue also includes $2.67 billion Apple
would make through the $99 annual fee paid by Apple’s 27 million
iOS developers.
2177
Apple also reportedly made $9 billion in 2018
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00296 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
291
Continued
Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Sept. 21, 2020) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘[T]here are more than 1.8
million apps on the App Store, and a thriving community of more than 27 million iOS devel-
opers.’’); Developer Support, Purchase and Activation, A
PPLE
, https://developer.apple.com/sup-
port/purchase-activation/ (last visited Sept. 27, 2020) (‘‘The Apple Developer Program annual
fee is $99 USD and the Apple Developer Enterprise Program annual fee is $299 USD.’’).
2178
See Lisa Marie Segarra, Google to Pay Apple $12 Billion to Remain Safari’s Default
Search Engine in 2019: Report, F
ORTUNE
(Sept. 29, 2018), https://fortune.com/2018/09/29/
google-apple-safari-search-engine/.
2179
See Mark Gurman, Apple’s New Services Off to a Slow Start in First Year, B
LOOMBERG
(July 28, 2020), https://www.bloombergquint.com/business/apple-s-new-services-off-to-a-slow-
start-in-first-year.
2180
Interview with Source 143 (Aug. 27, 2020).
2181
Dr. Carl Shapiro of the University of California, Berkeley—the former top economist for
the Justice Department’s Antitrust Division during the Obama Administration—has noted that
persistently high corporate profits that are not eroded by competitive forces over time are an
indicator of market power. Such profits also suggest the rise of incumbency rents, or the earning
of excess profits ‘‘by firms whose positions are protected by high barriers to entry.’’ Carl Shapiro,
Antitrust in a Time of Populism, 61 I
NT
L
J. I
NDUS
. O
RG
. 714, 733–37 (2018), https://faculty
.haas.berkeley.edu/shapiro/antitrustpopulism.pdf.
2182
Submission from ProtonMail, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 13 (Aug. 22, 2020) (on file
with Comm.).
2183
Competitors Hearing at 33 (statement of David Heinemeier Hansson, Cofounder & Chief
Tech. Officer, Basecamp); see also Interview with Source 88 (May 12, 2020).
2184
Competitors Hearing at 33 (statement of David Heinemeier Hansson, Cofounder & Chief
Tech. Officer, Basecamp); see also Interview with Source 873 (May 12, 2020).
and $12 billion in 2019 to set Google as the default search engine
on the Safari browser.
2178
Revenue from setting Google as Safari’s
default search engine is attributed to Apple’s Services business,
which is the business unit that includes the App Store.
2179
In an interview with the Subcommittee, Phillip Shoemaker, Ap-
ple’s former Senior Director of App Store Review, estimated that
Apple’s costs for running the App Store are less than $100 million.
Other analysts estimate that the App Store has significantly higher
profits. A gaming developer explained that the fees it pays Apple
add up to millions of dollars—and for some developers, those fees
are in the tens or hundreds of millions of dollars—far in excess of
the developer’s estimate of Apple’s costs of reviewing and hosting
those apps.
2180
Although only estimates, these figures indicate
that, as the mobile app economy has grown, Apple’s monopoly
power over app distribution on iPhones permits the App Store to
generate supra-normal profits. These profits are derived by extract-
ing rents from developers, who either pass on price increases to
consumers or reduce investments in innovative new services. Ap-
ple’s ban on rival app stores and alternative payment processing
locks out competition, boosting Apple’s profits from a captured eco-
system of developers and consumers.
2181
To address this concern without compromising the security or
quality of the App Store, some developers argue in favor of allow-
ing third-party payment processors like PayPal, Square, and Stripe
to compete in the App Store. They explain that the most likely
competitors are already trusted and widely used for e-commerce
transactions.
2182
David Heinemeier Hansson, Cofounder and CTO
of Basecamp, testified at the Subcommittee’s fifth hearing that Ap-
ple’s market power allows it to keep fees ‘‘exorbitantly high.’’
2183
By comparison, he noted that other markets, such as credit card
processes, are ‘‘only able to sustain a two percent fee for mer-
chants. Apple, along with Google, has been able to charge an out-
rageous 30 percent for years on end.’’
2184
Several other firms ob-
served that Apple’s control over app distribution allows it to extract
high fees on a minority of apps, and that competition for processing
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00297 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
292
2185
See, e.g., Competitors Hearing at 33 (statement of David Heinemeier Hansson, Cofounder
& Chief Tech. Officer, Basecamp); Submission from Source 202, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
15 (Oct. 18, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
2186
Rob Pegoraro, What Tim Cook Left Out of His Version of App Store History, F
ORBES
(July
29, 2020), https://www.forbes.com/sites/robpegoraro/2020/07/29/what-tim-cook-left-out-of-his-
version-of-app-store-history/.
2187
Submission of Match Group, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 6 (Oct. 31, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
2188
See Andrew Webster, Epic Offers New Direct Payment in Fortnite on iOS and Android
to Get Around App Store Fees, V
ERGE
(Aug. 13, 2020), https://www.theverge.com/2020/8/13/
21366259/epic-fortnite-vbucks-mega-drop-discount-iphone-android.
2189
Nick Statt, Apple Just Kicked Fortnite off the App Store, V
ERGE
(Aug. 13, 2020), https://
www.theverge.com/2020/8/13/21366438/apple-fortnite-ios-app-store-violations-epic-payments.
2190
App Store Developer Guidelines 3.1.1: In-App Purchase, A
PPLE
, https://developer
.apple.com/app-store/review/guidelines/#in-app-purchase (last visited Sept. 27, 2020).
2191
App Store Developer Guidelines 3.1.3: Other Purchase Methods, A
PPLE
, https://developer
.apple.com/app-store/review/guidelines/#other-purchase-methods (last visited Sept. 27, 2020).
2192
Submission from ProtonMail, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Aug. 22, 2020) (on file
with Comm.).
2193
Interview with Source 143 (Aug. 27, 2020).
payments would drive prices down. For example, developers ex-
plain that payment processing typically costs less than five percent
of the transaction value.
2185
Before the App Store, one developer
reportedly explained that ‘‘[w]e typically paid about 5%—not 30%—
to a payment processor,’’ and it ‘‘worked just as well for small de-
velopers as for large.’’
2186
Other developers have noted that alternative payment processing
providers charge significantly lower rates than Apple’s fee for IAP.
Match Group estimates that Apple’s expenses related to payment
processing ‘‘justify charging no more than 3.65% of revenue.’’
2187
Some app developers would prefer to implement in-house payment
processing. In August 2020, Epic Games introduced a direct pay-
ment option in its Fortnite app, allowing gamers to elect to use Ap-
ple’s IAP or pay Epic directly. Epic’s payment processing option
charged consumers 10 percent—a 20 percent discount from pur-
chases using IAP.
2188
In response, Apple disabled updates for
Fortnite for violating the App Store Guidelines.
2189
Developers have also detailed that Apple attempts to lock in its
fees by preventing apps from communicating with customers about
alternatives. Under the App Store Guidelines, apps may not pro-
vide any information ‘‘that direct[s] customers to purchasing mech-
anisms other than in-app purchase.’’
2190
They also cannot commu-
nicate with iOS app customers about purchasing methods other
than IAP.
2191
In an interview with the Subcommittee, one developer that offers
a ‘‘freemium’’ app—a popular business model where the app is
available for free but users can purchase upgrades—recalled that
it sent an email to customers with iOS devices with information
about how to upgrade to a paid subscription, including a link to the
service’s website where customers could upgrade their subscription.
Apple responded by threatening to remove the app from the App
Store and blocked its updates, including security patches.
2192
A
game developer described Apple’s rules as reaching outside the App
Store itself to police the communications that an app can have with
its own customers, including communications intended to improve
customer experience and offer discounts.
2193
In his questions for the record for the Subcommittee’s second
hearing, Representative W. Gregory Steube (R–FL) asked Apple
about banning communications to customers by app providers.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00298 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
293
2194
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 585 (response to Questions for the Record
of Kyle Andeer, Vice President, Corp. Law, Apple, Inc.).
2195
Id. at 584.
2196
Id. at 584–85.
2197
Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Opens Investigations into Apple’s
App Store Rules (June 16, 2020), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/ipl
20l1073.
2198
See, e.g., Jeremy Howitz, Apple’s Antitrust Woes Stem from Its Obsessions with Control
and Money, V
ENTURE
B
EAT
(Aug. 7, 2020), https://venturebeat.com/2020/08/07/apples-anti-
trust-woes-stem-from-its-obsessions-with-control-and-money/ (‘‘Apple might act like it’s too large
to care about money, but the company has recently sniped at developers who have succeeded
on iOS without paying Apple anything, while doing as much as possible to push other devel-
opers—and users—into coughing up recurring subscription fees for both apps and games.’’).
2199
See, e.g., Nilay Patel, Apple Approves Hey Email App, but the Fight’s Not Over, V
ERGE
(June 22, 2020), https://www.theverge.com/2020/6/22/21298552/apple-hey-email-app-ap-
proval-rules-basecamp-launch; Rob Pegoraro, Apple to Basecamp’s Hey: Expect to Pay Us If You
Want to Sell Privacy, F
ORBES
(June 17, 2020), https://www.forbes.com/sites/robpegoraro/2020/
06/17/apple-to-basecamps-hey-expect-to-pay-us-if-you-want-to-sell-privacy/.
2200
Chaim Gartenberg, Hey Opens Its Email Service to Everyone as Apple Approves Its App
for Good, V
ERGE
(June 25, 2020), https://www.theverge.com/2020/6/25/21302931/hey-email-
service-public-launch-apple-approves-app-fight-policy-price.
2201
Apple v. Hey, H
EY
, https://hey.com/apple/ (last visited Sept. 27, 2020).
2202
See Sean Hollister, WordPress Founder Claims Apple Cut Off Updates to His Completely
Free App Because It Wants 30 Percent, V
ERGE
(Aug. 21, 2020), https://www.theverge.com/2020/
8/21/21396316/apple-wordpress-in-app-purchase-tax-update-store; Sean Hollister, Apple Apolo-
gizes to WordPress, Won’t Force the Free App to Add Purchases After All, V
ERGE
(Aug. 23, 2020),
https://www.theverge.com/2020/8/22/21397424/apple-wordpress-apology-iap-free-ios-app.
Apple responded that its restrictions on communications between
apps and customers are to ensure Apple can collect commissions
and ‘‘prevent free-riding.’’
2194
Apple explained that it restricts de-
velopers from using the iOS ecosystem to ‘‘direct customers they
have acquired through Apple to purchase content elsewhere for the
purpose of avoiding Apple’s rightful commission.’’
2195
The company
described its policy as a prohibition ‘‘on developers promoting, via
the App Store, transactions outside the App Store,’’ and said Ap-
ple’s policies were no different than most other retailers.
2196
In June 2020, the European Commission announced that it had
opened a formal antitrust investigation of Apple’s App Store rules
and conduct, including ‘‘the mandatory use of Apple’s own propri-
etary in-app purchase system and restrictions on the availability of
developers to inform iPhone and iPad users of alternative cheaper
purchasing possibilities outside of apps.’’
2197
As Apple has emphasized growing its Services business, app de-
velopers and technology writers have observed Apple is increas-
ingly insistent that apps implement IAP—cutting Apple in on rev-
enue from more developers—and threatening apps that do not com-
ply with expulsion from the App Store.
2198
In June 2020, HEY, an
email app developed by Basecamp, was approved by the App Store
and then abruptly told it would have to implement Apple in-app
purchasing or face removal from the platform.
2199
While HEY’s app
updates were eventually allowed, Apple did force it to create a free
trial option for iOS customers.
2200
Basecamp Cofounder and CTO
David Heinemeier Hansson observed that Apple threatened and
abused small app developers for years, and that the conflict with
HEY amounted to a ‘‘shakedown.’’
2201
In August 2020, Apple de-
nied WordPress the ability to update its app unless it implemented
IAP, even though the WordPress app does not sell anything. Apple
ultimately backed off its demands only after the issue received neg-
ative attention on social media.
2202
ProtonMail told the Sub-
committee that its privacy-focused email app competes with Apple’s
email app, and after being in the App Store for two years, Apple
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00299 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
294
2203
Submission from ProtonMail, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Aug. 22, 2020) (on file
with Comm.).
2204
See Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJC–APPLE–014701 to
–014702 (Nov. 23, 2010) (on file with Comm.).
2205
Patrick McGee & Javier Espinoza, Apple Conflict with Developers Escalates Ahead of
Worldwide Conference, F
IN
. T
IMES
(June 22, 2020), https://www.ft.com/content/733ae8d4-e516-
4418-9998-30414c368c6f.
2206
See Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 89, 92–93.
2207
Jack Nicas & David McCabe, Their Business Went Virtual. Then Apple Wanted a Cut,
N.Y. T
IMES
(July 28, 2020), https://www.nytimes.com/2020/07/28/technology/apple-app-store-
airbnb-classpass.html.
2208
See, e.g., Interview with Airbnb; Interview with Source 147 (Sept. 10, 2020).
2209
See Interviews with Airbnb.
demanded the ProtonMail implement IAP or be removed from the
App Store. ProtonMail complied to avoid damage to its busi-
ness.
2203
Internal Apple communications reviewed by the Subcommittee
indicate that Apple has leveraged its power over the App Store to
require developers to implement IAP or risk being thrown out of
the App Store.
2204
Apple’s then-CEO Steve Jobs once explained,
‘‘there will be some roadkill because of it. I don’t feel guilty’’ when
confronted with developer complaints about Apple’s commission
and requirement to use IAP.
2205
The Netherlands Authority for
Consumers and Markets has noted that some app developers at-
tribute Apple’s inconsistent application of its rules to inattention to
apps that are infrequently updated, and that Apple likely focuses
on requiring IAP for high revenue-generating apps.
2206
In response to the COVID–19 pandemic, some businesses moved
physical events online, often booking through an app and holding
the event through a video chat application. Educators have also
shifted resources online, including through apps. The New York
Times reported that Apple demanded a 30 percent commission from
these virtual class offerings. As a result, one company stopped of-
fering virtual classes to users of its iOS app. The Times reported
that Apple threatened Airbnb that it would remove its app from
the App Store if Airbnb did not comply with Apple’s demand for a
share of its revenues.
2207
In interviews with the Subcommittee, multiple app developers
confirmed The New York Times’s reporting.
2208
Airbnb spoke with
the Subcommittee and described conversations with the App Store
team in which Apple said it had observed an uptick in the number
of apps offering virtual classes in lieu of in-person classes due to
the COVID–19 pandemic. As a result, Apple began canvassing the
App Store to require that app developers implement IAP, entitling
Apple to take 30 percent of in-app sales. Airbnb explained that Ap-
ple’s commission, plus compliance with Apple’s pricing tiers for in-
app purchases, would ultimately result in a 50–60 percent price in-
crease for consumers.
2209
Technology industry observers have reported similar conduct. On
June 17, 2020, Ben Thompson, a prominent business analyst, wrote
that app developers told him that Apple was demanding 30 percent
commissions from businesses that have had to change their busi-
ness models from live, in-person events to virtual events as a result
of the COVID–19 pandemic. Mr. Thompson quoted one developer
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00300 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
295
2210
See Ben Thompson, Xscale and ARM in the Cloud, Hey Versus Apple, Apple’s IAP Cam-
paign, S
TRATECHERY
(June 17, 2020), https://stratechery.com/2020/xscale-and-arm-in-the-
cloud-hey-versus-apple-apples-iap-campaign/.
2211
CEO Hearing at 150 (statement of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple, Inc.).
2212
Jack Nicas & David McCabe, Their Business Went Virtual. Then Apple Wanted a Cut,
N.Y. T
IMES
(July 28, 2020), https://www.nytimes.com/2020/07/28/technology/apple-app-store-
airbnb-classpass.html.
2213
Interview with Airbnb (Aug. 31, 2020).
2214
Submission from Match Group, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
MATCHlGRPl00000236, MATCHlGRPl00000238 (Oct. 23, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
2215
Submission from ProtonMail, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 6 (Aug. 22, 2020) (on file
with Comm.); see also Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 91.
2216
Interview with Source 143 (Aug. 27, 2020).
2217
Complaint at 3, Epic Games, Inc. v. Apple, Inc., 4:20–cv–05640 (N.D. Cal. Aug. 13, 2020),
https://cdn2.unrealengine.com/apple-complaint-734589783.pdf.
who explained that Apple was taking advantage of small busi-
nesses in the midst of the ongoing public health crisis.
2210
At the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Chair Jerrold Nadler (D–
NY) asked Mr. Cook about the allegations that Apple was can-
vassing the App Store to extract commissions from businesses that
have been forced to change their business model in order to survive
during the pandemic. Mr. Cook responded that Apple ‘‘would never
take advantage’’ of the pandemic, but justified the conduct, explain-
ing that the app developers were now offering what Apple defined
as a ‘‘digital service’’ and Apple was entitled to commissions.
2211
Responding to The New York Times’s reporting on the matter,
Apple defended its conduct, explaining that, ‘‘[t]o ensure every de-
veloper can create and grow a successful business, Apple maintains
a clear, consistent set of guidelines that apply equally to every-
one.’’
2212
App developers affected by these changes said that, after Apple’s
conduct became public, it created an exception to its policies until
the end of 2020. However, on January 1, 2021, those businesses
will be required to implement IAP or remove the ability to book
virtual classes from their apps.
2213
Developers have submitted evidence that Apple’s commissions
and fees, combined with the lack of competitive alternatives to the
App Store and IAP, harm competition and consumers. For instance,
Match Group called Apple’s fee for IAP ‘‘unreasonable,’’ saying that
it leads to higher prices for consumers and ‘‘an inferior user experi-
ence and a reduction of innovation.’’
2214
One developer that offers an app that directly competes with
Apple told the Subcommittee it was forced to raise prices to pay
Apple’s commission. As a result, it was less competitive, and fewer
iOS users purchased its service. The company said that, because
apps often have small margins, they cannot absorb Apple’s fees, so
the price consumers pay for its app is more than 25 percent higher
than it would otherwise be.
2215
Small developers described Apple’s
30 percent cut as ‘‘onerous.’’
2216
Epic Games, which recently filed
an antitrust complaint against Apple, has told a federal court that
Apple’s fees and commissions force developers ‘‘to increase the
prices they charge in order to pay Apple’s app tax. There is no
method app developers can use to avoid this tax.’’
2217
Mac and iOS
app developer Brent Simmons explained that Apple’s fees reduce
innovation and lead to fewer apps in the marketplace, observing:
[T]he more money Apple takes from developers, the fewer resources developers
have. When developers have to cut costs, they stop updating apps, skimp on cus-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00301 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
296
2218
Brent Simmons, I Got Teed Off and Went on a Long Rant About This Opinion Piece on
the App Store, I
NESSENTIAL
(July 28, 2020), https://inessential.com/2020/07/28/untrue.
2219
Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJC–APPLE–014816 to –014818
(Feb. 6, 2011) (on file with Comm.).
2220
See Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n Report at 223, 225 (2019); see also Ben
Thompson, Antitrust, the App Store, and Apple, S
TRATECHERY
(Nov. 27, 2018), https://www.
stratechery.com/2018/antitrust-the-app-store-and-apple (‘‘Apple makes a huge amount of money,
with massive profit margins, by virtue of its monopolistic control of the App Store. It doesn’t
make the games or the productivity applications or the digital content, it simply skims off 30%,
and not because its purchasing experience is better, but because it is the only choice.’’).
2221
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 91.
2222
See id. at 7.
2223
Id. at 89.
tomer support, put off hiring a graphic designer, etc. They decide not to make
apps at all that they might have made were it easier to be profitable.
2218
In Apple’s internal documents and communications, the com-
pany’s senior executives previously acknowledged that the IAP re-
quirement would stifle competition and limit the apps available to
Apple’s customers. For example, in an email conversation with
other senior leaders at Apple about whether to require IAP for e-
Book purchases, then-CEO Steve Jobs concluded, ‘‘I think this is all
pretty simple—iBooks is going to be the only bookstore on iOS de-
vices. We need to hold our heads high. One can read books bought
elsewhere, just not buy/rent/subscribe from iOS without paying us,
which we acknowledge is prohibitive for many things.’’
2219
International competition authorities have also examined the
competitive effects of Apple’s App Store commissions and fees. The
Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) ob-
served that Apple’s control over app distribution on iOS devices
gives it leverage to extract commissions from apps, reducing the
revenue that app providers like media businesses can invest in con-
tent.
2220
The Netherlands Authority for Consumers and Markets,
which completed a comprehensive study of mobile app stores in
2019, noted that developers have increased prices to account for
commissions and fees.
2221
The study also remarked that Apple’s 30
percent commission on in-app purchases may distort competition
because Apple’s requirement to use IAP often applies to apps com-
peting directly against Apple’s apps. As a result, app developers
with small margins cannot simply absorb the cost of Apple’s com-
mission, so they increase their price, which gives Apple’s competing
service an advantage.
2222
Developers cited in the study ‘‘mentioned
that it is highly unlikely that it is a coincidence that these digital
services that are required to use IAP face competition from Apple’s
own apps, or possibly will do so in the future.’’
2223
(ii) Pre-Installed Apps, Default Settings, Private App Program-
ming Interfaces (APIs), and Device Functionality. In addition to in-
vestigating whether Apple abuses its monopoly power over app dis-
tribution to leverage high commissions and fees from app devel-
opers, the Subcommittee also examined whether Apple abuses its
role as the owner of iOS and the App Store to preference its own
apps or harm rivals. The Committee requested information regard-
ing Apple’s practice of locking-in Apple’s apps as defaults on the
iPhone, and Subcommittee Chair David N. Cicilline (D–RI) re-
quested information from Apple regarding its practice of pre-in-
stalling its own apps on the iPhone. Subcommittee Chair Cicilline
also asked whether Apple’s policy of reserving certain application
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00302 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
297
2224
See, e.g., Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 36 (‘‘[C]onsumers in digital markets
display strong preferences for default options and loyalty to brands they know.’’); Stigler Report
at 8; id. at 41 (‘‘Consumers do not replace the default apps on their phones . . . and take other
actions that may look like poor decisions if those consumers like to choose among options and
experience competition.’’).
2225
J
OHN
B
ERGMAYER
, P
UB
. K
NOWLEDGE
, T
ENDING THE
G
ARDEN
: H
OW TO
E
NSURE
T
HAT
A
PP
S
TORES
P
UT
U
SERS
F
IRST
19 (2020), https://www.publicknowledge.org/wp-content/uploads/
2020/06/TendinglthelGarden.pdf.
2226
See Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJC–APPLE–011035 to
–011036 (Mar. 12, 2019) (on file with Comm.) (noting that Apple pre-loading software products
onto iOS devices ‘‘would clearly be even more problematic’’ than ‘‘Apple releasing its apps via
the App Store’’).
2227
CEO Hearing at 395 (response to Questions for the Record of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple,
Inc.).
2228
Id. at 396.
2229
Id.
2230
Id. See also Press Release, Apple, Apple Reveals New Developer Technologies to Foster
the Next Generation of Apps (June 22, 2020), https://www.apple.com/newsroom/2020/06/
apple-reveals-new-developer-technologies-to-foster-the-next-generation-of-apps/ (‘‘Email and
browser app developers can offer their apps as default options, selectable by users.’’).
2231
CEO Hearing at 397 (response to Questions for the Record of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple,
Inc.).
2232
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 5, 15, 85–86.
2233
Id. at 84 (citing Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Fines Google Ö4.34
Billion for Illegal Practices Regarding Android Mobile Devices to Strengthen Dominance of
Google’s Search Engine (July 18, 2018), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/
en/ipl18l4581).
2234
Id.
programming interfaces (APIs) and access to certain device
functionalities for its apps gives Apple’s services a competitive ad-
vantage.
It is widely understood that consumers usually do not change de-
fault options.
2224
This is the case ‘‘even if they can freely change
them or choose a competitive alternative.’’
2225
The Subcommittee
reviewed communications between Apple employees that dem-
onstrate an internal understanding that pre-loading apps could be
advantageous when competing against third-party apps.
2226
Apple pre-installs about 40 Apple apps into current iPhone mod-
els.
2227
Several of these apps are set as defaults and are ‘‘operating
system apps’’ that are ‘‘integrated into the phone’s core operating
system and part of the combined experience of iOS and
iPhone.’’
2228
According to Apple, users can delete most of these pre-
installed apps.
2229
Apple does not pre-install any third-party apps,
and until the September 2020 release of iOS 14, it did not allow
consumers to select third-party web browsers or email apps as de-
faults.
2230
Apple says that it is making ‘‘more than 250,000 APIs
available to developers in iOS 14.’’
2231
The Netherlands Authority for Consumers and Markets report on
mobile app stores observed that app providers believe they ‘‘have
a strong disadvantage’’ when competing with Apple’s apps due to
the fact that those services are often pre-installed on iOS de-
vices.
2232
The study also noted that ‘‘pre-installation of apps can
create a so-called status-quo bias. Consumers are more likely to use
the apps that are pre-installed on their smartphones.’’
2233
Con-
sumers will download apps that compete with pre-installed apps
only when there is a noted quality difference, and even then, lower-
quality pre-installed apps will still enjoy an advantage over third-
party apps.
2234
The European Commission’s 2019 report on com-
petition in digital markets explained that privileging access to APIs
can provide an advantage to those with greater access over those
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00303 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
298
2235
Eur. Comm’n Competition Report at 34.
2236
J
OHN
B
ERGMAYER
, P
UB
. K
NOWLEDGE
, T
ENDING THE
G
ARDEN
: H
OW TO
E
NSURE
T
HAT
A
PP
S
TORES
P
UT
U
SERS
F
IRST
20 (2020), https://www.publicknowledge.org/wp-content/uploads/
2020/06/TendinglthelGarden.pdf. See also D
IG
. C
OMPETITION
E
XPERT
P
ANEL
, P
UBLIC
R
E
-
SPONSES TO
C
ALL FOR
E
VIDENCE FROM
O
RGANISATIONS
44 (2018), https://assets
.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachmentldata/file/
785549/DCEPlPubliclresponsesltolcalllforlevidencelfromlorganisations.pdf (BBC re-
sponse) (‘‘Apple’s control of devices and operating system allows it to pre-load and favour its own
services i.e. Apple Podcasts.’’).
2237
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 42; Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at
59.
2238
See Thomas Claburn, Apple Frees a Few Private APIs, Makes Them Public, R
EGISTER
(June 13, 2017), https://www.theregister.com/2017/06/13/applelinchesltowardlopenness/.
2239
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 59–60.
2240
See Press Release, Apple, Apple Reveals New Developer Technologies to Foster the Next
Generation of Apps (June 22, 2020), https://www.apple.com/newsroom/2020/06/apple-reveals-
new-developer-technologies-to-foster-the-next-generation-of-apps/ (‘‘Email and browser app devel-
opers can offer their apps as default options, selectable by users.’’).
2241
Submission from Source 711, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 711–00000080, at 23
(Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
with more innovative products.
2235
Public Knowledge concluded
that Apple’s control of iOS and the App store enables it to advan-
tage its own apps and services by pre-installing them on iOS de-
vices, leading consumers to rely on the pre-installed apps rather
than looking for alternatives in the App Store.
2236
Mobile operating system providers develop APIs to permit apps
to access a device’s features, such as the microphone, camera, or
GPS, or other software programs, and determine what information
on the device apps can access.
2237
Public APIs for iOS are made
available to app developers to ensure apps are integrated with the
device and function as intended. These public APIs also control the
services that are opened via default when users click a link to open
a webpage or an address to open a map application. Private APIs
access functionality that is not publicly released. Apple is per-
mitted to use private APIs on iOS devices, but third-party devel-
opers are not.
2238
Apple’s public APIs default to Apple’s pre-installed applications.
As a result, when an iPhone user clicks on a link, the webpage
opens in the Safari Browser, a song request opens in Apple Music,
and clicking on an address launches Apple Maps.
2239
With some re-
cent exceptions, iPhone users are unable to change this default set-
ting.
2240
However, they are able to send app-specific links from in-
side many popular apps. For example, a person can share a link
to a song in a third-party music streaming app such that it would
open that song in the same app if it is already downloaded on the
recipient’s smartphone. One app developer has argued, however,
that Apple uses its control over iOS to give its own apps and serv-
ices advantages that are not available to competitors. For example,
the developer explained that for years it was barred from inte-
grating with Siri, Apple’s intelligent virtual assistant that is built
into Apple devices. Although Siri can now integrate with the app,
users must explicitly request that Siri launch the third-party app.
Otherwise, it will default to launch Apple’s service.
2241
Like setting advantageous defaults and pre-installing its own
apps, Apple is also able to preference its own services by reserving
access to APIs and certain device functionalities for itself. ACM
and technology reporters have noted both that ‘‘private APIs have
the potential to give Apple apps a competitive advantage,’’ and that
‘‘Apple has for a long time favored its own services through
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00304 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
299
2242
Thomas Claburn, Apple Frees a Few Private APIs, Makes Them Public, R
EGISTER
(June
13, 2017), https://www.theregister.com/2017/06/13/applelinchesltowardlopenness/; see
also Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 82.
2243
Thomas Claburn, Apple Frees a Few Private APIs, Makes Them Public, R
EGISTER
(June
13, 2017), https://www.theregister.com/2017/06/13/applelinchesltowardlopenness/.
2244
Apple Pay Security and Privacy Overview, A
PPLE
, https://support.apple.com/en-us/
HT203027 (last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
2245
Id.
2246
Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Opens Investigation into Apple Prac-
tices Regarding Apple Pay (June 16, 2020), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/
detail/en/ipl20l1075.
2247
CEO Hearing at 395, 397 (response to Questions for the Record of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple,
Inc.).
2248
See D
YNATA
, G
LOBAL
C
ONSUMER
T
RENDS
: COVID–19 E
DITION
, T
HE
N
EW
N
ORMAL
, A
B
REAKTHROUGH FOR
C
ONTACTLESS
P
AYMENTS
2 (2020), http://info.dynata.com/rs/105-ZDT-
791/images/Dynata-Global-Consumer-Trends-COVID-19-The-New-Normal-Breakthrough-for-
Contactless-Payments.pdf; see also Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Opens
Investigation into Apple Practices Regarding Apple Pay (June 16, 2020), https://ec.europa.eu/
commission/presscorner/detail/en/ipl20l1075 (‘‘Executive Vice-President Margrethe
Vestager, in charge of competition policy, said: ‘Mobile payment solutions are rapidly gaining
acceptance among users of mobile devices, facilitating payments both online and in physical
stores. This growth is accelerated by the coronavirus crisis, with increasing online payments and
contactless payments in stores.’ ’’).
APIs.’’
2242
For example, from the release of iOS 4.3 until iOS 8,
‘‘third-party developers had to rely on the UIWebView API to
render web pages in iOS apps, while Apple gave its own apps ac-
cess to a private, faster API,’’ and as a result, ‘‘Google’s mobile
version of Chrome for iOS could not compete with Apple’s mobile
version of Safari in terms of speed.’’
2243
Apple’s mobile payments service, Apple Pay, is an example of an
in-house app that enjoys an advantage due to its ability to access
certain functionalities, such as near-field communication (NFC), on
the iPhone that are off-limits to third-party apps. According to
Apple, ‘‘NFC is an industry-standard, contactless technology’’ that
enables communications between the mobile device and the pay-
ment terminal.
2244
Apple Pay uses the iPhone’s NFC chip to allow
users to make contactless payments at retail outlets that use the
technology.
2245
However, Apple blocks access for third-party apps.
In June 2020, the European Commission opened a formal antitrust
investigation into Apple’s conduct in the mobile payments market,
including ‘‘Apple’s limitation of access to the Near Field Commu-
nication . . . functionality (‘tap and go’) on iPhones for payments in
stores.’’
2246
In response to questions from Subcommittee Chair
David N. Cicilline (D–RI) and Representative Kelly Armstrong (R–
ND) about Apple’s treatment of third-party mobile payment apps
and access to the iPhone’s NFC chip, Apple said that it limits ac-
cess to the NFC chip to protect the security of the iPhone and has
detailed the differences between Apple’s treatment of Apple Pay
and third-party mobile payment apps.
2247
The advantage Apple provides Apple Pay may be heightened dur-
ing the COVID–19 pandemic. During the pandemic, consumers
have accelerated their adoption of contactless payments, with more
than half of global consumers preferring contactless payments over
cash or traditional credit cards.
2248
In April 2020, MasterCard re-
ported a 40 percent rise in contactless payments, with the trend ex-
pected to continue after the pandemic. MasterCard CEO Ajay
Banga explained the trend was driven by shoppers ‘‘looking for a
quick way to get in and out of stores without exchanging cash,
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00305 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
300
2249
Kate Rooney, Contactless Payments Jump 40% as Shoppers Fear Germs on Cash and
Credit Cards, Mastercard Says, CNBC (Apr. 29, 2020), https://www.cnbc.com/2020/04/29/
mastercard-sees-40percent-jump-in-contactless-payments-due-to-coronavirus.html.
2250
Apple Pay, A
PPLE
, https://www.apple.com/apple-pay/ (last visited Sept. 26, 2020).
2251
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 59–60.
2252
See Mark Gurman, Apple’s Default iPhone Apps Give It Growing Edge Over App Store
Rivals, B
LOOMBERG
(Oct. 2, 2019), https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2019-10-02/
iphone-ios-users-can-t-change-default-apps-safari-mail-music; Press Release, Apple, Apple Re-
veals New Developer Technologies to Foster the Next Generation of Apps (June 22, 2020),
https://www.apple.com/newsroom/2020/06/apple-reveals-new-developer-technologies-to-foster-
the-next-generation-of-apps/ (‘‘Email and browser app developers can offer their apps as default
options, selectable by users.’’).
2253
See, e.g., Google Chrome Help, G
OOGLE
, https://support.google.com/chrome/answer/
95417?co=GENIE.Platform%3DAndroid&hl=en-GB (last visited Sept. 26, 2020); Support,
M
OZILLA
, https://support.mozilla.org/en-US/kb/make-firefox-default-browser-android (last vis-
ited Sept. 26, 2020); Support, M
ICROSOFT
, https://support.microsoft.com/en-us/help/4028606/
windows-10-change-your-default-browser (last visited Sept. 26, 2020).
2254
App Store Review Guidelines 2.5.6, A
PPLE
: D
EV
., https://developer.apple.com/app-store/
review/guidelines/#software-requirements (last visited Sept. 26, 2020) (‘‘Apps that browse the
web must use the appropriate WebKit framework and WebKit Javascript.’’).
2255
See Michael Krasnov, Browser Engine Diversity or Internet of Google, E
VERDAY
.
CODES
(Dec. 15, 2019), https://everyday.codes/google/browser-engine-diversity-or-internet-of-google/.
2256
Interview with Source 269 (July 23, 2019) (‘‘Apple prohibits competitors from deploying
their own web browsing engines on its mobile operating system. Web browsing engines provide
the distinctive features of a web browser. Apple forces competitors to base their web browsers
on a reduced version of its own web browser engine, ‘WebKit.’ ’’).
2257
See Owen Williams, Apple Is Trying to Kill Web Technology, O
NE
Z
ERO
(Nov. 7, 2019),
https://onezero.medium.com/apple-is-trying-to-kill-web-technology-a274237c174d.
2258
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 585 (response to Questions for the Record
of Kyle Andeer, Vice President, Corp. Law, Apple, Inc.).
touching terminals, or anything else.’’
2249
Apple itself has capital-
ized on the perception that contactless is the safest way to make
transactions, marketing Apple Pay as ‘‘a safer way to pay that
helps you avoid touching buttons or exchanging cash.’’
2250
Like Apple Pay, Safari is another pre-installed app that enjoys
advantages over rivals. Safari is Apple’s default browser on iOS
and Mac devices. When someone using an Apple device clicks on
a website link, the webpage opens in the Safari browser.
2251
Until
the September 2020 release of iOS 14, Apple did not allow con-
sumers to select a third-party web browser as a default.
2252
This
was unique to iOS. Other mobile device operating systems allow
the user to set a default browser across all applications.
2253
Apple’s policies require alternative browser apps for iOS (iPhone)
to use Apple’s WebKit browser engine. As a result, all competing
web browser companies must rebuild their product to make it
available for iOS users.
2254
Additionally, browser engines are used
in other applications that link to web content, such as email appli-
cations.
2255
Market participants explained to the Subcommittee
that these guidelines cost significant internal resources and create
a hurdle for market entry on iOS. These requirements also make
alternative browsers on iOS less technically distinct from Safari,
limiting product differentiation.
2256
Further, market participants
expressed concern that, because Apple mandates the use of
WebKit, as opposed to allowing options for developers, WebKit has
become slower to innovate and adopt standards.
2257
At the Subcommittee’s second hearing, Chair Cicilline asked
Apple about its policies related to web browser engines. Apple re-
sponded, ‘‘By requiring use of WebKit, Apple can provide security
updates to all our users quickly and accurately, no matter which
browser they decide to download from the App Store.’’
2258
While
market participants agree that Apple’s WebKit mandates would
allow for easier updates to browser apps, there is disagreement
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00306 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
301
2259
See Andy Greenberg, How Safari and iMessage Have Made iPhones Less Secure, W
IRED
(Sept. 9, 2019), https://www.wired.com/story/ios-security-imessage-safari/.
2260
Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 85–86.
2261
Id. at 103.
2262
See Competitors Hearing (statement of Kirsten Daru, Chief Priv. Officer & Gen. Couns.,
Tile, Inc.).
2263
Id. at 41.
2264
See Guilherme Rambo, Apple Revamping Find My Friends & Find My iPhone in Unified
App, Developing Tile-Like Personal Item Tracking, 9
TO
5M
AC
(Apr. 17, 2019), https://
9to5mac.com/2019/04/17/find-my-iphone-revamp/.
2265
Competitors Hearing at 42 (statement of Kirsten Daru, Chief Priv. Officer & Gen. Couns.,
Tile, Inc.).
2266
Id.
2267
Reed Albergotti, Apple Says Recent Changes to Operating System Improve User Privacy,
but Some Lawmakers See Them as an Effort to Edge Out Its Rivals, W
ASH
. P
OST
(Nov. 26, 2019),
https://www.washingtonpost.com/technology/2019/11/26/apple-emphasizes-user-privacy-law-
makers-see-it-an-effort-edge-out-its-rivals/; see also Competitors Hearing at 43 (statement of
Kirsten Daru, Chief Priv. Officer & Gen. Couns., Tile, Inc.).
2268
Competitors Hearing at 87–100 (response to Questions for the Record of Kirsten Daru,
Chief Priv. Officer & Gen. Couns., Tile, Inc.).
2269
Id. at 89; Interview with Kirsten Daru, Vice President & Gen. Couns., Tile, Inc. (July
10, 2020).
about whether WebKit is measurably less secure than other brows-
er engines.
2259
The Netherlands Authority for Consumers and Markets has
noted that app providers have limited access to some APIs ‘‘that
are essential for the functioning of apps. In certain cases, these
functionalities are, however, used by Apple for their own apps,’’
2260
which may limit competitive alternatives to Apple’s products and
services.
2261
In January 2020, Kirsten Daru, Chief Privacy Officer and Gen-
eral Counsel of Tile, offered testimony to the Subcommittee about
this dynamic.
2262
Tile is a company that makes hardware and soft-
ware that helps people find lost items.
2263
Ms. Daru testified that
for years Tile successfully collaborated with Apple. However, re-
ports surfaced in 2019 that Apple planned to launch a hardware
product to compete with Tile.
2264
Ms. Daru said that Apple’s 2019
release of iOS 13 harmed Tile’s service and user experience while
simultaneously introducing a new pre-installed Apple finder app
called Find My.
2265
Changes to iOS 13 made it more difficult for
Tile’s customers to set up the service, requiring several confusing
steps to grant Tile permission to track the phone’s location.
2266
Meanwhile, Apple’s Find My app was pre-installed on iOS devices
and activated by default during iOS installation. Users are unable
to opt out of Find My’s location tracking ‘‘unless they go deep into
Apple’s labyrinthine menu of settings.’’
2267
Tile’s response to the
Subcommittee’s Questions for the Record included detailed location
permission flow comparisons between Tile and Find My.
2268
Tile
explained that, as a result of Apple’s changes to iOS 13, it saw sig-
nificant decreases in users and a steep drop-off in users enabling
the proper settings on iOS devices.
2269
A group of app developers wrote to Apple CEO Tim Cook in 2019
arguing that Apple’s new location notification permission policies
will hurt their businesses and accused Apple of acting
anticompetitively by treating its own services differently:
The developers conclude their email by asserting that Apple’s own apps don’t
have to jump through similar hoops to get access to user location. An Apple app
called Find My for tracking the location of other iPhone users, for example, by-
passes the locating tracking requests that apps from outside developers must go
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00307 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
302
2270
Aaron Tilley, Developers Call Apple Privacy Changes Anti-Competitive, I
NFORMATION
(Aug. 16, 2019), https://www.theinformation.com/articles/developers-call-apple-privacy-changes-
anticompetitive.
2271
Id.
2272
Letter from Kyle Andeer, Vice President, Corp. Law & Chief Compliance Officer, Apple,
Inc., to Hon. Jerrold Nadler, Chair, H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Hon. Doug Collins, Ranking
Member, H. Comm on the Judiciary, Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust,
Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary & Hon. F. James Sensen-
brenner, Ranking Member, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H.
Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Feb. 17, 2020), https://docs.house.gov/meetings/JU/JU05/
20200117/110386/HHRG-116-JU05-20200117-SD004.pdf.
2273
See, id. at 2.
2274
See Ben Lovejoy, Comment: This Week’s Keynote Quietly Tackled Five of Apple’s Antitrust
Issues, 9
TO
5M
AC
(June 24, 2020), https://9to5mac.com/2020/06/24/apples-antitrust-issues-2/.
2275
See Interview with Kirsten Daru, Vice President & Gen. Couns., Tile, Inc. (July 10,
2020); A
PPLE
, F
IND
M
Y
N
ETWORK
A
CCESSORY
S
PECIFICATION
, D
EVELOPER
P
REVIEW
: R
ELEASE
R1,
at 14 (2020), https://images.frandroid.com/wp-content/uploads/2020/06/FindlMyl
networklaccessorylprotocollspecification.pdf (prohibiting ‘‘an accessory that supports the
Find My network accessory protocol’’ from ‘‘operat[ing] simultaneously on the Find My network
and another finder network’’).
2276
Interview with Kirsten Daru, Vice President & Gen. Couns., Tile, Inc. (June 26, 2020).
See Reed Albergotti, Amid Antitrust Scrutiny, Apple Makes Quiet Power Moves over Developers,
W
ASH
. P
OST
(July 24, 2020), https://www.washingtonpost.com/technology/2020/07/24/apple-
find-my-competition/.
2277
See Tripp Mickle, Apple Dominates App Store Search Results, Thwarting Competitors,
W
ALL
S
T
. J. (July 23, 2019), https://www.wsj.com/articles/apple-dominates-app-store-search-
results-thwarting-competitors-11563897221; Jack Nicas & Keith Collins, How Apple’s Apps
Topped Rivals in the App Store It Controls, N.Y. T
IMES
(Sept. 9, 2019), https://www.
nytimes.com/interactive/2019/09/09/technology/apple-app-store-competition.html.
through, the email reads. Instead, Find My gains location access through a proc-
ess that occurs as users install the new operating system.
2270
The app developers—including Tile, Arity, Life360, Happn,
Zenly, Zendrive, and Twenty—explained that this gives Apple prod-
ucts that compete against their apps an advantage. ‘‘Apple says
Find My and other apps are built into iOS and that it doesn’t see
a need to make location-tracking requests from users for the apps
after they install the operating system.’’
2271
Apple also differen-
tiates Find My by pointing out that ‘‘ ‘Find My’ stores user location
data locally on the user’s iPhone, and Apple only transmits the lo-
cation upon the user’s request.’’
2272
In response to the Subcommittee’s questions after its second
hearing, Apple explained that the iOS 13 changes give users more
control over background location tracking by apps. Apple also ex-
plained that turning on location tracking to Apple’s Find My serv-
ice was ‘‘essential’’ for users, and that the disparate treatment be-
tween Find My and Tile was due to the fact that data from Find
My remains on the device, while Tile stores data externally.
2273
Ad-
ditionally, during Apple’s June 2020 World Wide Developers Con-
ference, Apple announced that the Find My app would work with
third-party finder hardware like Tile’s.
2274
However, Apple’s serv-
ice would require companies like Tile to abandon their apps and
the ability to differentiate their service from Apple’s and other com-
petitors.
2275
Apple’s solution would continue to put Tile and other
apps and hardware developers offering finder services at a competi-
tive disadvantage.
2276
(iii) App Search Rankings. In response to extensive reporting on
the subject, the Subcommittee has also examined the competitive
effects of Apple’s search rankings in its App Store. In 2019, The
Wall Street Journal and The New York Times both conducted ex-
tensive investigations and reported that Apple appeared to be fa-
voring its apps in the App Store search results.
2277
The Wall Street
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00308 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
303
2278
Tripp Mickle, Apple Dominates App Store Search Results, Thwarting Competitors, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (July 23, 2019), https://www.wsj.com/articles/apple-dominates-app-store-search-results-
thwarting-competitors-11563897221.
2279
Jack Nicas & Keith Collins, How Apple’s Apps Topped Rivals in the App Store It Controls,
N.Y. T
IMES
(Sept. 9, 2019), https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2019/09/09/technology/
apple-app-store-competition.html.
2280
Tripp Mickle, Apple Dominates App Store Search Results, Thwarting Competitors, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (July 23, 2019), https://www.wsj.com/articles/apple-dominates-app-store-search-results-
thwarting-competitors-11563897221.
2281
Id.
2282
Id.
2283
Id.
2284
Id.
2285
CEO Hearing at 396 (response to Questions for the Record of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple,
Inc.).
Journal explained that ‘‘Apple’s mobile apps routinely appear first
in search results ahead of competitors in its App Store, a powerful
advantage that skirts some of the company’s rules on search
rankings.’’
2278
The New York Times reported that six years of anal-
ysis of App Store search rankings found Apple-owned apps ranked
first for at least 700 common search terms. ‘‘Some searches pro-
duced as many as 14 Apple apps before showing results from ri-
vals,’’ although app developers could pay Apple to place ads at the
top of the search results.
2279
Searches for the app titles of com-
peting apps even resulted in Apple’s apps ranked first.
2280
Apple’s apps ‘‘ranked first in more than 60% of basic searches,
such as for ‘maps’ ’’ and ‘‘Apple apps that generate revenue through
subscriptions or sales, like Music or Books, showed up first in 95%
of searches related to those apps.’’
2281
The Wall Street Journal
noted that growing revenue from its apps is core to Apple’s strategy
of offsetting sluggish hardware sales by increasing revenue from its
Services business.
2282
Rival app developers slipped down the search rankings as Apple
introduced new services in their product categories. For example,
Spotify had long been the top search result for the query ‘‘music,’’
but Apple Music quickly became the top search result shortly after
it joined the App Store in June 2016. By the end of 2018, eight of
Apple’s apps appeared in the first eight search results for ‘‘music,’’
and Spotify had fallen to the 23rd result. Similarly,
Audiobooks.com was the top-ranked result for ‘‘audiobooks’’ for
nearly two years but was overtaken by Apple Books shortly after
Apple began marketing for Books. Audiobooks explained to The
Wall Street Journal that losing the top search ranking to Apple
‘‘triggered a 25% decline in Audiobooks.com’s daily app
downloads.’’
2283
Reporting on App Store search revealed that Apple may also ad-
vantage its apps by holding them to a different standard when they
appear in the App Store search rankings. Apple told The Wall
Street Journal that ‘‘it uses 42 factors to determine where apps
rank,’’ and that the four most important factors are ‘‘downloads,
ratings, relevance, and ‘user behavior,’’’ with user behavior the
most important factor because it measures how often users select
and download an app.
2284
Approximately 40 of Apple’s apps come
preinstalled on iPhones. These apps do not have reviews and con-
sumers cannot rate them. Mr. Cook explained at the Subcommit-
tee’s sixth hearing that Apple’s ‘‘apps that are integrated into the
iPhone are not reviewable by users on the App Store.’’
2285
Apple
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00309 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
304
2286
See Tripp Mickle, Apple Dominates App Store Search Results, Thwarting Competitors,
W
ALL
S
T
. J. (July 23, 2019), https://www.wsj.com/articles/apple-dominates-app-store-search-
results-thwarting-competitors-11563897221.
2287
Id.
2288
Search Results: ‘‘books,’’
I
OS A
PP
S
TORE
(Sept. 17, 2020).
2289
Search Results: ‘‘music,’’ ‘‘news,’’ ‘‘TV,’’ ‘‘podcast,’’
I
OS A
PP
S
TORE
(Sept. 17, 2020).
2290
Tripp Mickle, Apple Dominates App Store Search Results, Thwarting Competitors, W
ALL
S
T
. J. (July 23, 2019), https://www.wsj.com/articles/apple-dominates-app-store-search-results-
thwarting-competitors-11563897221.
2291
Jack Nicas & Keith Collins, How Apple’s Apps Topped Rivals in the App Store It Controls,
N.Y. T
IMES
(Sept. 9, 2019), https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2019/09/09/technology/
apple-app-store-competition.html.
2292
Id.; see also Apple, Apple: Distinctive Products with a Seamless, Integrated User Experi-
ence 23 (July 13, 2020) (unpublished white paper) (on file with Comm.) (‘‘Because many of Ap-
ple’s apps are named after generic topics (such as Music, Maps, and Podcasts), those apps ben-
efit from functional queries that have essentially become navigational.’’).
2293
Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJC–APPLE–008082 to –008086
(Feb. 9, 2018) (on file with Comm.).
2294
Id.
has also said that its search algorithm works the same for all apps,
including its own.
2286
Despite the fact that Apple’s pre-installed apps do not have rat-
ings or reviews—factors that Apple says are most influential in de-
termining app ranking—many of Apple’s pre-installed apps ‘‘still
tend to be ranked first, even when users search for exact titles of
other apps.’’
2287
For example, Apple Books has no reviews or
rankings and appears first in a search for ‘‘books,’’ while competing
apps have tens-of-thousands of customer reviews and ratings of 4.8
or 4.9 stars on Apple’s five-star rating system.
2288
A search by the
Subcommittee of terms ‘‘music,’’ ‘‘news,’’ ‘‘TV,’’ and ‘‘podcast’’ re-
turned Apple Music, News, TV, and Podcasts as top-ranked search
results, although those apps do not have any reviews or rank-
ing.
2289
Despite the lack of reviews or rankings, Apple told The Wall
Street Journal that ‘‘the No. 1 position for Books in a ‘books’ search
is reasonable, since it is an exact name match.’’
2290
Philip Schiller,
Apple’s Senior Vice President, Worldwide Marketing, who oversees
the App Store, and Eddy Cue, Apple’s Senior Vice President Inter-
net and Software Services, said ‘‘there was nothing underhanded
about the algorithm the company had built to display search re-
sults in the store,’’
2291
and that Apple’s apps tend to rank highly
because they are popular and their generic names like Books and
Music closely match common search terms.
2292
It appears that Apple does not apply the same rule to third-party
apps. Documents reviewed by the Subcommittee show that Apple
previously punished non-Apple apps that attempted to ‘‘cheat’’ the
app store rankings. Apple determined that at least one third-party
app had achieved its high search ranking because its name was a
generic name that was also a common search term. Apple’s employ-
ees determined it was cheating to give an app the name of a com-
mon search term.
In February 2018, Apple’s App Store search team noted that an
app named ‘‘Photo Editor—Stylo’’ was the top-ranked result when
users searched the App Store for ‘‘photo editor.’’
2293
In an email
thread with Philip Schiller, Apple’s Senior Vice President, World-
wide Marketing, an Apple employee wrote that, ‘‘[s]ince the app
name matched a broad query term like ‘photo editor’ the developer
was able to game the query with a direct name match.’’
2294
The
Apple employee explained that ‘‘[t]he app has been added to the
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00310 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
305
2295
Id.
2296
Id.
2297
CEO Hearing at 162 (statement of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple, Inc.).
2298
See, e.g., Brian Heater, The Makers of Duet Display and Luna on Life After Apple’s Side-
car, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(June 7, 2019), https://techcrunch.com/2019/06/07/the-makers-of-duet-
display-and-luna-on-life-after-apples-sidecar/.
2299
See J
OHN
B
ERGMAYER
, P
UB
. K
NOWLEDGE
, T
ENDING THE
G
ARDEN
: H
OW TO
E
NSURE THAT
A
PP
S
TORES
P
UT
U
SERS
F
IRST
21, 58 (2020), https://www.publicknowledge.org/wp-content/
uploads/2020/06/Tendinglthe lGarden.pdf.
2300
See, e.g., Reed Albergotti, How Apple Uses Its App Store to Copy the Best Ideas, W
ASH
.
P
OST
(Sept. 5, 2019), https://www.washingtonpost.com/technology/2019/09/05/how-apple-uses-
its-app-store-copy-best-ideas/. See also William Gallagher, Developers Talk About Being
‘‘Sherlocked’’ as Apple Uses Them ‘‘For Market Research,’’ A
PPLE
I
NSIDER
(June 6, 2019), https://
appleinsider.com/articles/19/06/06/developers-talk-about-being-sherlocked-as-apple-uses-them-
for-market-research; John Patrick Pullen, Why These People Are Upset About Apple’s Latest Up-
dates, T
IME
(June 21, 2016), https://time.com/4372515/apple-app-developers-wwdc-sherlock-
sherlocked/; Adi Robertson, Apple Restores Mail App After Developer Tries to Rally ‘‘Sherlocked’’
Victims, V
ERGE
(Feb. 11, 2020), https://www.theverge.com/2020/2/11/21133023/apple-
bluemail-blix-restored-mac-app-store-sherlocking-patent-lawsuit.
Search Penalty Box for rank demotion,’’ and the action was labeled
as complete.
2295
Additional action was slated to disable the initial
boost that new apps are given in the app store if the app name is
an ‘‘exact match to broad queries.’’
2296
Here, Apple punished an
app for the same conduct it said justified Apple’s position atop the
App Store rankings.
Apple’s position as the provider of iOS enables it to designate the
App Store as the sole means for app developers to distribute soft-
ware to iPhone users. Apple’s public statements, including testi-
mony by Mr. Cook that Apple’s apps ‘‘go through the same rules’’
as more than 1.7 million third-party apps, appear to be incon-
sistent with Apple’s actual practices.
2297
In this case, Apple lever-
aged its control of iOS and the App Store to give its own apps pref-
erential treatment, and it applied a different set of rules to third-
party apps, punishing them for the very conduct Apple engaged in.
The Subcommittee did not have access to additional evidence from
Apple to determine how widespread this practice is within the com-
pany.
(iv) Competitively Sensitive Information. In addition to inves-
tigating allegations Apple engages in self-preferencing in the App
Store, the Committee sought information regarding whether Apple
exploits third-party developers that rely on distribution in the App
Store. Developers have alleged that Apple abuses its position as the
provider of iOS and operator of the App Store to collect competi-
tively sensitive information about popular apps and then build
competing apps or integrate the popular app’s functionality into
iOS.
2298
The practice is known as ‘‘Sherlocking.’’ The antitrust laws
do not protect app developers from competition, and platforms
should continue to innovate and improve their products and serv-
ices. However, Sherlocking can be anticompetitive in some in-
stances.
2299
Some app developers have complained that Apple leverages its
control of iOS and the App Store to glean business intelligence that
enables it to better compete against third-party apps.
2300
For ex-
ample, after a stress relief app called Breathe was Sherlocked in
2016, the app’s developers said that Apple used third-party devel-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00311 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
306
2301
John Patrick Pullen, Why These People Are Upset About Apple’s Latest Updates, T
IME
(June 21, 2016), https://time.com/4372515/apple-app-developers-wwdc-sherlock-sherlocked/.
2302
Reed Albergotti, How Apple Uses Its App Store to Copy the Best Ideas, W
ASH
. P
OST
(Sept.
5, 2019), https://www.washingtonpost.com/technology/2019/09/05/how-apple-uses-its-app-
store-copy-best-ideas/.
2303
Competitors Hearing at 53 (statement of Kirsten Daru, Chief Priv. Officer & Gen. Couns.,
Tile, Inc.).
2304
See id. at 87; Guilherme Rambo, Apple Revamping Find My Friends & Find My iPhone
in Unified App, Developing Tile-Like Personal Item Tracking, 9
TO
5M
AC
(Apr. 17, 2019), https://
9to5mac.com/2019/04/17/find-my-iphone-revamp/.
2305
Amended Complaint at 4, Blix Inc. v. Apple, Inc., No. 1:19–cv–1869–LPS (D. Del. Dec.
20, 2019).
2306
Submission from Source 736, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 736–00000243 (Oct.
23, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
2307
Interview with Phillip Shoemaker, former Senior Dir., App Store Review, Apple, Inc.
(Sept. 21, 2020).
2308
Id.
2309
Id.
opers ‘‘as an R&D arm.’’
2301
The Washington Post reported on the
phenomenon, explaining:
Developers have come to accept that, without warning, Apple can make their
work obsolete by announcing a new app or feature that uses or incorporates their
ideas. Some apps have simply buckled under the pressure, in some cases shut-
ting down. They generally don’t sue Apple because of the difficulty and expense
in fighting the tech giant—and the consequences they might face from being de-
pendent on the platform.
2302
At the Subcommittee’s fifth hearing, Subcommittee Vice Chair
Joe Neguse (D–CO) asked Ms. Daru of Tile about how Apple used
competitively sensitive information it collects as the owner of the
iOS ecosystem to compete against third-party apps. She explained
that, as an operating system provider and App Store operator,
Apple knows who Tile’s customers are, the types of apps those cus-
tomers preferred, and the demographics of iOS users that look at
Tile’s app or search for similar apps—information that would give
Apple a competitive advantage against Tile.
2303
Ms. Daru testified
that Apple had harmed Tile’s service and user experience while si-
multaneously introducing a rival app and preparing to launch a
rival hardware product.
2304
Blix, the developer of email manage-
ment app BlueMail, has sued Apple in federal court. They claim
that Apple has engaged in Sherlocking and infringed the patents
underlying BlueMail:
Apple frequently takes other companies’ innovative features, adds those ideas to
Apple’s own software products without permission, and then either ejects the
original third-party application from the App Store (as it did with Blix’s soft-
ware) or causes the third-party software developer to close its doors entirely.
2305
In response to the requests for information, Match Group told
the Subcommittee that Apple has a history of ‘‘closely monitoring
the success of apps in the App Store, only to copy the most success-
ful of them and incorporate them in new iPhones’’ as a pre-in-
stalled app.
2306
Phillip Shoemaker, Apple’s former Senior Director
of App Store Review, similarly told the Subcommittee that during
his time at Apple, an app developer proposed an innovative way to
wirelessly sync the iPhone and Mac.
2307
The app did not violate
any of Apple’s Guidelines, but it was rejected from the App Store
nonetheless.
2308
Apple then appropriated the rejected app’s feature
for its own offerings.
2309
During the Subcommittee’s sixth hearing, Vice Chair Neguse
asked Mr. Cook about Tile’s testimony. In particular, he asked if
Apple has access to the confidential information of app developers,
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00312 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
307
2310
CEO Hearing at 162 (question of Rep. Joe Neguse (D–CO), Vice Chair, Subcomm. on
Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary).
2311
Id. at 162–63 (statement of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple, Inc.) (‘‘[Apple] run[s] the App Store
to help developers, not hurt them. We respect innovation. It’s what our company was built on.
We would never steal somebody’s IP.’’).
2312
Reed Albergotti, How Apple Uses Its App Store to Copy the Best Ideas, W
ASH
. P
OST
(Sept.
5, 2019), https://www.washingtonpost.com/technology/2019/09/05/how-apple-uses-its-app-
store-copy-best-ideas/.
2313
Apple Developer Agreement, A
PPLE
: D
EV
. 4, https://developer.apple.com/terms/apple-de-
veloper-agreement/Apple-Developer-Agreement-English.pdf (last visited Sept. 27, 2020) (Clause
11: Apple Independent Development).
2314
Id.
2315
App Store Review Guidelines: Introduction, A
PPLE
: D
EV
., https://developer.apple
.com/app-store/review/guidelines/#introduction (last visited Sept. 27, 2020).
2316
App Store Review Guidelines 4.1: Copycats, A
PPLE
: D
EV
., https://developer.apple
.com/app-store/review/guidelines/#copycats (last visited Sept. 27, 2020).
2317
Id.; App Store Review Guidelines 5.2: Intellectual Property, A
PPLE
: D
EV
., https://
developer.apple.com/app-store/review/guidelines/#intellectual-property (last visited Sept. 27,
2020).
and whether Apple’s Developer Agreement explicitly authorizes
Apple to use developers’ information to build apps to compete
against them.
2310
Mr. Cook’s answer was non-responsive regarding
allegations of Sherlocking. Instead, he said that Apple does not vio-
late other companies’ intellectual property rights.
2311
In contrast, Apple cofounder and former CEO Steve Jobs once
noted that, ‘‘[w]e have always been shameless about stealing great
ideas.’’
2312
The Apple Developer Agreement, which Apple requires
every app developer to agree to, appears to warn developers that,
in exchange for access to the App Store, Apple is free to build apps
that ‘‘perform the same or similar functions as, or otherwise com-
pete with,’’ apps in the App Store.
2313
Additionally, ‘‘Apple will be
free to use any information, suggestions or recommendations you
provide to Apple pursuant to this Agreement for any purpose, sub-
ject to any applicable patents or copyrights.’’
2314
Mr. Cook’s statement that Apple’s apps play by the same rules
as other apps appears contrary to Apple’s stated policies. While the
Apple Developer Agreement provides Apple the right to replicate
third-party apps, Apple’s Guidelines direct developers not to ‘‘copy
another developer’s work’’ and threaten removal of apps and expul-
sion from the Developer Program for those that do.
2315
Further, the
Guidelines instruct developers to ‘‘[c]ome up with your own ideas’’
and admonish them to not ‘‘simply copy the latest popular app on
the App Store, or make some minor changes to another app’s name
or UI and pass it off as your own.’’
2316
Lastly, Apple differentiates
between—rather than conflates or confuses—copycat apps and in-
tellectual property infringement, which are both prohibited in the
App Store.
2317
(v) Excluding Rival Apps. During the Subcommittee’s sixth hear-
ing, Representatives Val Demings (D–FL) and Lucy McBath (D–
GA) asked questions regarding Apple’s removal of parental control
apps from the App Store in 2018 and 2019. In 2018, Apple an-
nounced its Screen Time app, a new feature bundled with iOS 12
that helped iOS users limit the time they and their children spent
on the iPhone. Thereafter, Apple began to purge many of the lead-
ing rival parental control apps from the App Store. Apple explained
the apps were removed because they used a technology called Mo-
bile Device Management (MDM). MDM technology allowed parents
to remotely take over their children’s phones and block content.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00313 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
308
2318
See Jack Nicas, Apple Cracks Down on Apps that Fight iPhone Addiction, N.Y. T
IMES
(Apr. 27, 2019), https://www.nytimes.com/2019/04/27/technology/apple-screen-time-trackers
.html. See also Sarah Perez, Apple Puts Third-Party Screen Time Apps on Notice, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Dec. 5, 2018), https://techcrunch.com/2018/12/05/apple-puts-third-party-screen-time-apps-on-
notice/.
2319
Jack Nicas, Apple Cracks Down on Apps that Fight iPhone Addiction, N.Y. T
IMES
(Apr.
27, 2019), https://www.nytimes.com/2019/04/27/technology/apple-screen-time-trackers.html.
See also Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJC–APPLE–012255 to
–012259 (Apr. 28, 2019); id. at HJC–APPLE–013251 to –013253 (Apr. 28, 2019).
2320
See, e.g., Nick Kuh, Mute App: Startup to Shutdown, M
EDIUM
(Oct. 22, 2018), https://
medium.com/@nick.kuh/mute-app-startup-to-shutdown-a1db01440c56; Georgie Powell, In the
Kill Zone—Update for Space on iOS, S
PACE
(Nov. 6, 2018), https://findyourphonelife
balance.com/news/2018/11/6/in-the-kill-zone-an-update-for-space-on-ios; Is Apple Systemati-
cally Destroying the Time Management Industry?, K
IDS
L
OX
(Nov. 8, 2018), https://kidslox.com/
blog/apple-destroying-screen-time-industry/; OurPact, There Used To Be an App for That, M
E
-
DIUM
(May 1, 2019), https://medium.com/@ourpactapp/there-used-to-be-an-app-for-that-
41344f61fb6f; Justin Payeur, Letter to Users About Apple Parental Controls, B
OOMERANG
(Jan.
31, 2020), https://useboomerang.com/2020/01/31/letter-users-apple-parental-controls/.
2321
See Nick Kuh, Apple Called, M
EDIUM
(Oct. 27, 2018), https://medium.com/@nick.kuh/
apple-called-a229d86ece30; Georgie Powell, Space Is Back! An Update on Our Discussions with
Apple, S
PACE
(Nov. 7, 2018), https://findyourphonelifebalance.com/news/2018/11/7/space-
versus-apple.
2322
Press Release, Qustodio Techs. SL, Qustodio & Kidslox File a Complaint Against Apple
with the European Commission over Abuse of Dominant Position (Apr. 30, 2019), https://
www.globenewswire.com/news-release/2019/04/30/1812192/0/en/Qustodio-Kidslox-File-a-
Complaint-Against-Apple-with-the-European-Commission-over-Abuse-of-Dominant-Position
.html#.
2323
See, e.g., Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJC–APPLE–012242 to
–012243 (May 6, 2019), HJC–APPLE–012245 to –012246 (May 6, 2019), HJC–APPLE–
012247 to –012248 (June 5, 2019), HJC–APPLE–013220 (May 14, 2019), HJC–APPLE–013219
(May 5, 2019), HJC–APPLE–013251 to –013253 (Apr. 28, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
2324
Jack Nicas, Apple Cracks Down on Apps that Fight iPhone Addiction, N.Y. T
IMES
(Apr.
27, 2019), https://www.nytimes.com/2019/04/27/technology/apple-screen-time-trackers.html.
2325
See, e.g., Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJC–APPLE–013210 to
–013211 (Apr. 27, 2019), HJC–APPLE–013215 (May 17, 2019), HJC–APPLE–013216 (May 6,
2019),HJC–APPLE–013221 to –013223 (Apr. 29, 2019), HJC–APPLE–013265 to –013266 (Apr.
27, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
2326
See, e.g., id. at HJC–APPLE–013210 to –013211 (Apr. 27, 2019), HJC–APPLE–013217
(Apr. 27, 2019), HJC–APPLE–013221 to –013223 (Apr. 29, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
Apple noted that MDM could allow the app developer to access sen-
sitive content on the device.
2318
According to The New York Times, the parental control apps
using MDM had been offered in the App Store for years, and hun-
dreds of updates to those apps had been approved by Apple.
2319
As
a result, many apps were forced to shut down,
2320
although some
were given a reprieve.
2321
Two parental control apps filed a com-
plaint with the European Commission, alleging Apple’s App Store
policies were anticompetitive. The complaint alleged that Apple
purged competitors when it introduced Screen Time, pre-installed
Screen Time on iOS 12 and activated it by default, and gave Screen
Time access to iOS functionalities it denied to competing third-
party apps.
2322
The Subcommittee reviewed emails from parents who contacted
Apple to complain about the removal of one of the purged parental
control apps.
2323
They said that Screen Time was a comparably
worse option for consumers—and described it as ‘‘more com-
plicated’’ and ‘‘less restrictive’’ than competitors.
2324
In emails to
the company reviewed by the Subcommittee, parents complained
about Apple’s monopoly power over app distribution on iOS and
claimed that self-interest in promoting Screen Time motivated Ap-
ple’s actions.
2325
In response, Apple’s Senior Vice President, World-
wide Marketing, Phil Schiller, explained that Screen Time was ‘‘de-
signed to help parents manage their children’s access to tech-
nology.’’
2326
He added that Apple would ‘‘work with developers to
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00314 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
309
2327
Id. at HJC–APPLE–013221 to –013223 (Apr. 29, 2019).
2328
Id. at HJC–APPLE–013175 (Apr. 27, 2019).
2329
Id. at HJC–APPLE–012223 (June 2, 2019). See also CEO Hearing at 134 (statement of
Tim Cook, CEO, Apple, Inc.) (‘‘It was that the use of technology called MDM, mobile device man-
agement, placed kids’ data at risk, and so we were worried about the safety of kids.’’); id. at
141 (‘‘We were concerned, Congresswoman, about the privacy and security of kids.’’).
2330
See, e.g., Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJC–APPLE–012255 to
–012259 (Apr. 28, 2019), HJC–APPLE–012275 to –012279 (Jan. 17, 2019), HJC–APPLE–
012286 to –012287 (Jan. 17, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
2331
Id. at HJC–APPLE–012286 to –012287 (Jan. 17, 2019) (on file with Comm.).,
2332
Jack Nicas, Apple Cracks Down on Apps that Fight iPhone Addiction, N.Y. T
IMES
(Apr.
27, 2019), https://www.nytimes.com/2019/04/27/technology/apple-screen-time-trackers.html.
2333
Id. See also App Store Review Guidelines 5.5: Mobile Device Management, A
PPLE
, https://
developer.apple.com/app-store/review/guidelines/#mobile-device-management (last visited Sept.
27, 2020).
2334
S
CREEN
T
IME
API, https://screentimeapi.com/ (last visited Sept. 27, 2020).
2335
See Joe Rossignol, Apple Reverses Course and Allows Parental Control Apps to Use MDM
Technology with Stricter Privacy Requirements, M
AC
R
UMORS
(June 4, 2019), https://
www.macrumors.com/2019/06/04/apple-lets-parental-apps-use-mdm-strict-privacy/.
2336
See, e.g., Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJC–APPLE–012275 to
–012279 (Jan. 17, 2019), HJC–APPLE–013210 to –013211 (Apr. 27, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
2337
Id. at HJC–APPLE–012273 to –012274 (June 4, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
offer many great apps on the App Store for these uses, using tech-
nologies that are safe and private for us and our children.’’
2327
Internally, Apple’s Vice President of Marketing Communications,
Tor Myhren, stated, ‘‘[t]his is quite incriminating. Is it true?’’ in re-
sponse to an email with a link to The New York Times’s report-
ing.
2328
Apple’s communications team asked CEO Tim Cook to ap-
prove a ‘‘narrative’’ that Apple’s clear-out of Screen Time’s rivals
was ‘‘not about competition, this is about protecting kids [sic] pri-
vacy.’’
2329
Developers of the purged apps also contacted Apple, outraged
that they had been removed from the App Store while other apps
that used MDM remained.
2330
One developer explained it had in-
vested more than $200,000 building its parental control app, then
another $30,000 to fix the problem Apple identified, only to be told
that Apple would no longer support parental control apps in the
App Store.
2331
Although Apple claimed its conduct was motivated to protect pri-
vacy and not intended to clear out competitors to Screen Time,
Apple reinstated many of the apps the same day that it was re-
ported the Department of Justice was investigating Apple for po-
tential antitrust violations.
2332
Apple’s solution to address privacy
concerns was to ask the apps to promise not to sell or disclose user
data to third parties, which could have been achieved through less
restrictive means and without removing those apps from the App
Store.
2333
Developers of parental control apps asked Apple to ‘‘release a
public API granting developers access to the same functionalities
that Apple’s native ‘Screen Time’ uses.’’
2334
Eventually, Apple did
grant some apps access to APIs,
2335
but only after rival app devel-
opers were accused of being a risk to children’s privacy, removed
from the App Store, and forced to incur significant costs.
2336
As one
developer noted, Apple’s new MDM privacy policies resulted in
‘‘really nothing much changing from the developer side as far as
the technology goes.’’
2337
Here, Apple’s monopoly power over app distribution enabled it to
exclude rivals to the benefit of Screen Time. Apple could have
achieved its claimed objective—protecting user privacy—through
less restrictive means, which it ultimately did only after significant
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00315 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
310
2338
See Damien Geradin & Dimitrios Katsifis, The Antitrust Case Against the Apple App
Store 55–56 (Tilberg Univ. Law & Econ. Ctr. Discussion Paper, Paper No. DP2020–039, 2000),
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstractlid=3583029.
2339
Interview with Phillip Shoemaker, former Senior Dir., App Store Review, Apple, Inc.
(Sept. 21, 2020).
2340
App Store Review Guidelines: Introduction, A
PPLE
: D
EV
., https://developer.apple
.com/app-store/review/guidelines/#introduction (last visited Sept. 27, 2020).
2341
Id.
2342
Id.
2343
Competitors Hearing at 34 (statement of David Heinemeier Hansson, Cofounder & Chief
Tech. Officer, Basecamp).
2344
Submission from Source 247, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 247l0000000002
(Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
outcry from the public and a prolonged period of harm to rivals.
2338
Apple’s conduct here is a clear example of Apple’s use of privacy
as a sword to exclude rivals and a shield to insulate itself from
charges of anticompetitive conduct.
The Subcommittee learned that Apple has engaged in conduct to
exclude rivals to benefit Apple’s services in other instances. For ex-
ample, Mr. Shoemaker explained that Apple’s senior executives
would find pretextual reasons to remove apps from the App Store,
particularly when those apps competed with Apple services.
2339
(vi) Opaque Guidelines and Arbitrary Enforcement. At the Sub-
committee’s sixth hearing, Representative Henry C. ‘‘Hank’’ John-
son, Jr. (D–GA) asked Mr. Cook about how the App Store Devel-
oper Guidelines are interpreted and applied to developers in the
App Store. Subcommittee Chair David N. Cicilline (D–RI) re-
quested similar information about the Guidelines as well, including
how they have evolved and whether there are ‘‘unwritten rules’’ de-
velopers must comply with.
The Guidelines are the rules with which more than 20 million
iOS app developers and more than 1.8 million apps in the App
Store must comply to reach ‘‘hundreds of millions of people around
the world.’’
2340
Apple notes that the App Store is ‘‘highly curated’’
and that ‘‘every app is reviewed by experts.’’
2341
The introductory
section of the Guidelines warns that Apple can create new rules at
any time, and explains that ‘‘[w]e will reject apps for any content
or behavior that we believe is over the line. What line, you ask?
Well as a Supreme Court Justice once said, ‘I’ll know it when I see
it.’ And we think that you will also know it when you cross it.’’
2342
App developers the Subcommittee spoke with expressed frustra-
tion with Apple’s curation of the App Store. Cofounder and Chief
Technology Officer of Basecamp, David Heinemeier Hansson, testi-
fied before the Subcommittee and explained:
It’s complete tyranny, and the rules are often interpreted differently by different
reviewers because they’re intentionally left vague. So we live in constant fear we
may have violated these vague rules, and that the next update to our applica-
tions will be blocked by Apple. There are countless examples where developers
large and small have been denied access to publish their applications without ex-
planation for days or even weeks at a time. It’s insufferable.
2343
One social media platform expressed concern that Apple has ab-
solute discretion about whether to approve apps or accept up-
dates.
2344
Developers are frustrated that Apple’s interpretation and
enforcement of the Guidelines have changed over time, despite
prior precedents and the fact developers rely on understanding the
Guidelines to operate their businesses. One developer described Ap-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00316 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
311
2345
Submission from Source 736, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 736l00000236 (Oct.
23, 2019) (on file with Comm.); Interview with Source 88 (May 12, 2020).
2346
Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJC–APPLE–014848 (May 30,
2018) (on file with Comm.).
2347
Michael Nunez, ‘‘Finder for AirPods’’ App Mysteriously Disappears from App Store With-
out Much Explanation from Apple, G
IZMODO
(Jan. 9, 2017), https://gizmodo.com/finder-for-
airpods-app-mysteriously-disappears-from-app-1790999059.
2348
Id.
2349
See Dieter Bohn, Apple’s App Store Policies Are Bad, but Its Interpretation and Enforce-
ment Are Worse, V
ERGE
(June 17, 2020), https://www.theverge.com/2020/6/17/21293813/
apple-app-store-policies-hey-30-percent-developers-the-trial-by-franz-kafka (‘‘The key thing to
know is that the text of this policy is not actually the policy. Or rather, as with any law, the
text is only one of the things you need to understand. You also need to know how it is enforced
and how the enforcers interpret that text.’’).
2350
Kara Swisher, Is It Finally Hammer Time for Apple and Its App Store, N.Y. T
IMES
(June
19, 2020), https://www.nytimes.com/2020/06/19/opinion/apple-app-store-hey.html?referring
Source=articleShare.
2351
Submission from ProtonMail, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Aug. 22, 2020) (on file
with Comm.).
ple’s Guidelines as ‘‘arbitrarily interpreted,’’ and another party
called them ‘‘opaque and arbitrary.’’
2345
Internally, after an app
was rejected from the App Store, an Apple employee wrote to the
leadership of the App Store that Apple’s decision ‘‘still isn’t obvious
to people inside the company that work directly on the App
Store.’’
2346
In 2017, Gizmodo reported that iOS app maker Deucks saw its
Finder for the AirPods app removed from the App Store. The app
used the iPhone’s Bluetooth signal to locate lost AirPods, helping
its users find a missing earbud and save money by not having to
purchase replacements. After the app was reviewed and approved,
it disappeared from the App Store. Deucks told Gizmodo that Ap-
ple’s app review team ‘‘didn’t find anything wrong with the app
itself, but rather they didn’t like the ‘concept’ of people finding
their AirPods and hence [the app] was deemed ‘not appropriate for
the App Store.’ ’’
2347
At the time, Deucks had several other finder
apps, such as Finder for Fitbit and Finder for Jawbone, that re-
mained available in the App Store.
2348
Developers also say that Apple uses its power over the App Store
to change the Guidelines when convenient in ways that benefit
Apple. The Guidelines—along with their interpretation and en-
forcement—all change over time in ways that always appear to
benefit Apple.
2349
Spotify noted that ‘‘[t]he reality is Apple con-
tinues to move the goal posts and change the rules to its advantage
and the detriment of developers,’’ and that the company’s ‘‘selective
and capricious enforcement [of its App Store policies] is designed
to put companies like [Spotify] at an untenable competitive dis-
advantage.’’
2350
ProtonMail explained that it offered a free version
of its app in the App Store for years, but then Apple abruptly
changed the way it applied its IAP requirement and demanded the
app add the ability for consumers to purchase upgraded
functionality through the app—giving Apple a 30 percent cut from
those subscriptions. ProtonMail noted that its app competes with
an Apple service and that requiring it to implement IAP would in-
crease its customer acquisition costs and make it less competitive,
benefitting Apple.
2351
Another third party the Subcommittee spoke
with said that when Apple introduces a new app, developers with
rival apps know they may be targeted for a violation of a Rule
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00317 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
312
2352
Interview with Source 88 (May 12, 2020).
2353
Interview with Source 766 (July 2, 2020).
2354
See J
OHN
B
ERGMAYER
, P
UB
. K
NOWLEDGE
, T
ENDING THE
G
ARDEN
: H
OW TO
E
NSURE
T
HAT
A
PP
S
TORES
P
UT
U
SERS
F
IRST
27 (2020), https://www.publicknowledge.org/wp-content/
uploads/2020/06/TendinglthelGarden.pdf; Bapu Kotapati et al., The Antitrust Case Against
Apple 22 (Yale Univ. Thurman Arnold Project Digital Platform Theories of Harm Paper Series,
Paper No. 2, 2020), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstractlid=3606073.
2355
See Ben Thompson, Xscale and ARM in the Cloud, Hey Versus Apple, Apple’s IAP Cam-
paign, S
TRATECHERY
(June 17, 2020), https://stratechery.com/2020/xscale-and-arm-in-the-
cloud-hey-versus-apple-apples-iap-campaign/; John Gruber, The Flimsiness of ‘‘Business vs. Con-
sumer’’ as a Justification for Apple’s Rejection of Hey from the App Store for Not Using In-App
Purchases, D
ARING
F
IREBALL
(June 16, 2020), https://daringfireball.net/2020/06/heyl
applstorelrejectionlflimsiness; Sarah Perez & Anthony Ha, Apple Revises App Store Rules to
Permit Game Streaming Apps, Clarify In-App Purchases and More, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Sept. 11,
2020), https://techcrunch.com/2020/09/11/apple-revises-app-store-rules-to-permit-game-stream-
ing-apps-clarify-in-app-purchases-and-more/.
2356
CEO Hearing at 402 (response to Questions for the Record of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple,
Inc.).
2357
Interview with Source 77 (Sept. 10, 2020).
2358
CEO Hearing at 80 (statement of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple, Inc.).
2359
Id.
Apple has suddenly decided to interpret or enforce differently.
2352
Another app developer that competes with Apple services noted
that the Guidelines are constantly shifting, that Apple arbitrarily
decides when an app no longer complies with the rules, and those
decisions always favor Apple’s interests.
2353
Others have noted that Apple unilaterally determines if, how,
and when to apply its Guidelines, and that it also freely makes up
‘‘unwritten rules’’ when convenient.
2354
For example, Apple’s dis-
tinction between ‘‘business’’ and ‘‘consumer’’ apps to justify its June
2020 decision to require Basecamp to redesign its app to permit in-
app signups—and attempt to require implementation of IAP—was
not a distinction that appeared in Apple’s Guidelines until an up-
date on September 11, 2020.
2355
Apple said that it has a ‘‘set of
standard terms for Amazon, and every other video-streaming serv-
ice that met the criteria, to launch their service on Apple TV and
iOS.’’
2356
One of Apple’s business partners told the Subcommittee
that it suspects Amazon receives preferential treatment by being
exempt from sharing revenue for some categories of trans-
actions.
2357
The Subcommittee reviewed communications between Apple CEO
Tim Cook and an executive from Baidu regarding whether Apple
would provide Baidu with preferential treatment. At the Sub-
committee’s sixth hearing, Representative Henry C. ‘‘Hank’’ John-
son, Jr. (D–GA) questioned Mr. Cook about whether Apple differen-
tiates in its treatment of app developers. Representative Johnson
also asked if it was true that Apple assigned Baidu two employees
to help it navigate the App Store bureaucracy, and whether other
app developers receive the same access to Apple personnel. Mr.
Cook responded, ‘‘we treat every developer the same,’’ and ex-
plained the App Store Guidelines ‘‘apply evenly to everyone.’’
2358
He also said, ‘‘I don’t know about that, sir,’’ in response to Rep-
resentative Johnson’s inquiry about Baidu, adding, ‘‘We do a lot of
things with developers including looking at their beta test apps re-
gardless of whether they’re large or small.’’
2359
Communications reviewed by the Subcommittee show that, in
2014, Baidu requested, among other things, that Apple ‘‘set up a
fast track for the review process for Baidu APPs,’’ along with set-
ting Baidu as the default search and mapping services on ‘‘all
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00318 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
313
2360
Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJC–APPLE–011082 (June 3,
2015) (on file with Comm.).
2361
Id. at HJC–APPLE–011081 (Aug. 3, 2014).
2362
Id. at HJC–APPLE–011079 to –011080.
2363
Id. at HJC–APPLE–011083 (June 3, 2015).
2364
Id. at HJC–APPLE–011084.
2365
Id.
2366
CEO Hearing at 402 (response to Questions for the Record of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple,
Inc.).
2367
Id. at 403.
2368
Interview with Phillip Shoemaker, former Senior Dir., App Store Review, Apple, Inc.
(Sept. 21, 2020).
2369
Phillip Shoemaker, A Modern Content Store, M
EDIUM
(Dec. 12, 2017), https://
medium.com/@phillipshoemaker/a-modern-content-store-3344bbe79edc.
2370
Phillip Shoemaker, Apple v. Everybody, M
EDIUM
(Mar. 29, 2019), https://medium.com/
@phillipshoemaker/apple-v-everybody-5903039e3be.
Apple devices in China.’’
2360
Mr. Cook solicited feedback from Ap-
ple’s senior executives regarding these and other requests from
Baidu, also noting, ‘‘I think we should have someone focus on them
as we have done with Facebook. Thoughts?’’
2361
Responding to the
email thread with Mr. Cook’s request that Apple focus on Baidu as
it had with Facebook, one executive explained, ‘‘Engineering pro-
posal is for extensions to be our path for integration,’’ and re-
sponded to Baidu’s app review fast track request, ‘‘I believe we put
a lot of work into having a fast review process for all apps.’’
2362
Within two weeks, Mr. Cook responded to the Baidu executive’s
requests. ‘‘I’d like Apple to have a deeper relationship with Baidu,’’
Cook wrote, noting that ‘‘some of’’ the Baidu executive’s requests
were ‘‘great starts.’’
2363
In response to the Baidu executive’s re-
quest for ‘‘APP Review Fast Track,’’ Mr. Cook wrote, ‘‘We can set
up a process where Baidu could send us a beta app for review and
this can often speed up the process.’’
2364
Mr. Cook then noted he
had assigned Baidu two employees from App Store chief Phil Schil-
ler’s team to ‘‘help manage through Apple.’’
2365
When asked about these issues in questions submitted for the
record following the hearing, Mr. Cook explained his view that
‘‘There is no ‘fast track’ for App Review special to Baidu,’’ that ‘‘any
developer can request expedited review from App Review by sub-
mitting a formal expedite request,’’ and ‘‘[t]he beta app review proc-
ess I referenced in my email has been available to developers since
2009.’’
2366
Mr. Cook also noted, ‘‘The key contacts referenced in my
email were focused on other strategic opportunities outlined by
Baidu. Neither individual had responsibility for App Store re-
view.’’
2367
In a subsequent interview with Phillip Shoemaker, Apple’s
former Senior Director of App Store Review, the Subcommittee
asked about Apple’s treatment of app developers. Mr. Shoemaker
responded that Apple ‘‘was not being honest’’ when it claims it
treats every developer the same.
2368
Mr. Shoemaker has also writ-
ten that the App Store rules were often ‘‘arbitrary’’ and ‘‘arguable,’’
and that ‘‘Apple has struggled with using the App Store as a weap-
on against competitors.’’
2369
He has noted that ‘‘Apple has com-
plete and unprecedented power over their customers’ devices. The
decisions they make with regards to third-party apps needs to be
above reproach, and currently are not.’’
2370
Mr. Shoemaker also admitted that Apple advantages its own
apps over third-party apps. In an interview with the Subcommittee,
he described it as inaccurate to say Apple does not favor its own
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00319 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
314
2371
Interview with Phillip Shoemaker, former Senior Dir., App Store Review, Apple, Inc.
(Sept. 21, 2020).
2372
Phillip Shoemaker, Apple v. Everybody, M
EDIUM
(Mar. 29, 2019), https://medium.com/
@phillipshoemaker/apple-v-everybody-5903039e3be.
2373
Interview with Phillip Shoemaker, former Senior Dir., App Store Review, Apple, Inc.
(Sept. 21, 2020).
2374
United States v. Apple, Inc., 952 F. Supp. 2d 638, 662 (S.D.N.Y. 2013), aff’d, 791 F.3d
290 (2d Cir. 2015).
2375
See, e.g., Neth. Auth. for Consumers & Mkts. Study at 5–6, 68, 79; Killian Bell, Apple
Rejects Samsung Pay App for iOS, C
ULT OF
M
AC
(Dec. 12, 2016), https://www.cultofmac.com/
457916/apple-rejects-samsung-pay-app-ios/; Gil Jaeshik & Park Sora, Apple Rejects Samsung
Pay Mini To Be Registered on Its App Store, K
OREA
IT N
EWS
(Dec. 12, 2016), http://english
.etnews.com/20161212200003.
2376
CEO Hearing at 80 (statement of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple, Inc.).
2377
Id. at 399 (response to Questions for the Record of Tim Cook, CEO, Apple, Inc.).
2378
See Sarah Perez & Anthony Ha, Apple Revises App Store Rules to Permit Game Stream-
ing Apps, Clarify In-App Purchases and More, T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(Sept. 11, 2020), https://tech
crunch.com/2020/09/11/apple-revises-app-store-rules-to-permit-game-streaming-apps-clarify-in-
app-purchases-and-more/.
apps over third-party apps.
2371
He has previously noted that apps
that compete against Apple’s services often have problems getting
through the App Store’s review process. For example, Apple’s gam-
ing service, Apple Arcade, is a type of app that was ‘‘consistently
disallowed from the store’’ when offered by third-party developers,
but Apple allowed its own app in the store, ‘‘even though it violates
existing [App Store] guidelines.’’
2372
Mr. Shoemaker explained to
the Subcommittee that Apple’s new Guideline 3.1.2a, related to
streaming game services, was likely written to ‘‘specifically exclude
Google Stadia,’’ describing the decision as ‘‘completely arbi-
trary.’’
2373
Similar conduct has been commented on by the
courts,
2374
as well as international antitrust authorities.
2375
Apple disputes that its rules are opaque and arbitrarily applied.
In response to questions from Representative Henry C. ‘‘Hank’’
Johnson, Jr. (D–GA), Mr. Cook insisted the Guidelines are ‘‘open
and transparent’’ and that Apple ‘‘treat[s] every developer the
same.’’
2376
In response to Questions for the Record from Sub-
committee Chair David N. Cicilline (D–RI), Mr. Cook reiterated
that ‘‘[t]he Guidelines provide transparency and act as a practical
guide to help developers better understand the app approval proc-
ess .... Apple attempts to apply the Guidelines uniformly to all de-
velopers and all types of apps.’’
2377
Apple appears to have recently revised some of its App Store
policies under the scrutiny of the Subcommittee, the Department of
Justice, and global competition authorities. In June 2020, Apple
announced new policies for its App Store review that will allow app
developers to appeal decisions by app reviewers and even challenge
the Guidelines governing the App Store. Apple also announced that
app updates with bug fixes would no longer be held up due to a
violation of an App Store guideline. Additionally, on September 11,
2020, Apple changed its App Developer Guidelines to address some
of the questions which arose from recent controversies described
earlier in this Report.
2378
3. Siri Intelligent Voice Assistant
(a) Market Power. Apple describes Siri as ‘‘an intelligent assist-
ant that offers a faster, easier way to get things done on Apple de-
vices,’’ helping users to ‘‘make calls, send text messages or email,
schedule meetings and reminders, make notes, search the Internet,
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00320 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
315
2379
Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJC–APPLE–000007 (Oct. 14,
2019) (on file with Comm.).
2380
Press Release, Apple, HomePod Arrives February 9, Available to Order This Friday (Jan.
13, 2018), https://www.apple.com/newsroom/2018/01/homepod-arrives-february-9-available-to-
order-this-friday/.
2381
Submission from Apple, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, HJC–APPLE–000011 (Oct. 14,
2019) (on file with Comm.).
2382
Press Release, FutureSource Consulting, Virtual Assistants to Exceed 2.5 Billion Ship-
ments in 2023 (Dec. 18, 2019), https://www.futuresource-consulting.com/press-release/con-
sumer-electronics-press/virtual-assistants-to-exceed-25-billion-shipments-in-2023/.
2383
Submission from Source 918, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 918–0001578 (Nov.
4, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
2384
See, e.g., Press Release, FutureSource Consulting, Virtual Assistants to Exceed 2.5 Bil-
lion Shipments in 2023 (Dec. 18, 2019), https://www.futuresource-consulting.com/press-release/
consumer-electronics-press/virtual-assistants-to-exceed-25-billion-shipments-in-2023/; Submis-
sion from Source 918, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 918–0001578 (Nov. 4, 2019) (on
file with Comm.).
2385
See Press Release, FutureSource Consulting, Virtual Assistants to Exceed 2.5 Billion
Shipments in 2023 (Dec. 18, 2019), https://www.futuresource-consulting.com/press-release/con-
sumer-electronics-press/virtual-assistants-to-exceed-25-billion-shipments-in-2023/; Juli Clover,
Siri: Everything You Need to Know, M
AC
R
UMORS
(July 27, 2020), https://www.macrumors
.com/guide/siri/.
2386
Daniel Wroclawski, How to Use Siri and Apple HomeKit to Control Your Smart Home,
C
ONSUMER
R
EPS
. (Oct. 5, 2019), https://www.consumerreports.org/home-automation-systems/
how-to-use-siri-to-control-smart-home/.
2387
Catherine Clifford, Here’s How Siri Made It Onto Your iPhone, CNBC (June 29, 2017),
https://www.cnbc.com/2017/06/29/how-siri-got-on-the-iphone.html.
2388
Jenna Wortham, Apple Buys a Start-Up for Its Voice Technology, N.Y. T
IMES
(Apr. 29,
2010), https://www.nytimes.com/2010/04/29/technology/29apple.html.
2389
Jeremy Horwitz, Apple Acquires Laserlike, an ML Startup that Might Make Siri Smarter,
V
ENTURE
B
EAT
(Mar. 13, 2019), https://venturebeat.com/2019/03/13/apple-bought-laserlike-an-
ml-startup-that-might-make-siri-smarter/.
find local businesses, get directions, get answers, find facts, and
more just by asking.’’
2379
Apple integrated Siri into iPhone 4S at
its release in October 2011. As of January 2018, Apple said Siri
was active on over 500 million devices, making Siri one of the most
widely used voice assistants in the world.
2380
In a production to the Committee, Apple stated that it neither
creates market share data for Siri nor tracks third-party market
share data for integrated voice assistants.
2381
Market research firm
FutureSource Consulting found that, as of December 2019, Siri was
the leading intelligent virtual assistant with a 35 percent market
share globally.
2382
A third party supplied the Subcommittee with
additional market research showing that, in the first half of 2018,
Apple’s Siri was built into 42 percent of virtual-assistant-enabled
devices sold worldwide.
2383
Apple, Google, Amazon, and Microsoft
are the leading providers of intelligent virtual assistants.
2384
Siri’s
success reflects its integration into the iPhone and other Apple
hardware, such as the iPad, Mac, Apple Watch, Apple TV, and
HomePod.
2385
Siri is the hub of Apple’s ecosystem of smart-home
devices. Users can control Apple HomeKit-compatible devices using
Siri on an Apple device.
2386
(b) Merger Activity. The startup Siri, Inc launched the Siri app
for iOS in February 2010 based on a prototype developed by Adam
Cheyer while working at SRI International Research Lab.
2387
Apple acquired the company two months later.
2388
Apple has fol-
lowed up on its acquisition of Siri with a series of additional acqui-
sitions to strengthen Siri’s underlying technology and natural lan-
guage processing. For example, in 2019, Apple acquired Laserlike,
technology to help Siri improve at delivering personalized results
for users.
2389
In 2020, Apple acquired Inductiv, an AI technology
for correcting data flaws; Xnor.ai, which specializes in low-power,
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00321 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
316
2390
See Lisa Eadicicco, Apple Just Bought Another AI Startup to Help Siri Catch Up to Rivals
Amazon and Google, B
US
. I
NSIDER
(May 28, 2020), https://www.businessinsider.com/apple-
buys-ai-startup-inductiv-siri-catch-up-amazon-google-2020-5; Mark Gurman, Apple Acquires AI
Startup to Better Understand Natural Language, B
LOOMBERG
(Apr. 3, 2020), https://www.
bloomberg.com/news/articles/2020-04-03/apple-acquires-ai-startup-to-better-understand-nat-
ural-language; Charlie Wood, Apple Has Acquired the Artificial-Intelligence Startup Xnor.ai for
a Reported $200 Million, B
US
. I
NSIDER
(Jan. 16, 2020), https://www.businessinsider.com/apple-
reportedly-buys-xnor-ai-200-million-2020-1.
2391
See, e.g., Ben Lovejoy, Alexa iPhone App Can Now Operate Hands-Free—with a Little
Help from Siri, 9
TO
5M
AC
(July 8, 2020), https://9to5mac.com/2020/07/08/alexa-iphone-
app/; Chris Welch, Google Assistant Just Got Much Better and More Convenient on iOS Thanks
to Siri Shortcuts, V
ERGE
(Nov. 20, 2018), https://www.theverge.com/2018/11/20/18105693/
google-assistant-siri-shortcuts-feature-iphone-ios.
2392
How ‘‘Hey Siri’’ Works with Multiple Devices, A
PPLE
, https://support.apple.com/en-us/
HT208472 (last visited Sept. 27, 2020).
2393
HomeKit, A
PPLE
, https://developer.apple.com/homekit/ (last visited Oct. 3, 2020).
2394
E.g., Use Siri to Play Music or Podcasts, A
PPLE
, https://support.apple.com/en-us/
HT208279 (last visited Sept. 27, 2020); David Phelan, Apple Mulls Letting You Choose Default
iOS 14 Apps: Why It Matters, F
ORBES
(Feb. 21, 2010), https://www.forbes.com/sites/
davidphelan/2020/02/21/apple-mulls-letting-you-switch-default-iphone-apps-in-ios-14/#70330
c9c11f8.
2395
Kate Kozuch, How to Use Siri to Control Spotify in iOS 13, T
OM
S
G
UIDE
(Oct. 7, 2019),
https://www.tomsguide.com/how-to/how-to-use-siri-to-control-spotify-ios-13.
2396
Jason Cross, iOS 13 Enables Siri Support in Third Party Media Apps: Spotify, Pandora,
Overcast, and Much More, M
AC
W
ORLD
(June 7, 2019), https://www.macworld.com/article/
3400881/ios-13-enables-siri-support-in-third-party-media-apps.html.
2397
See Submission from Source 301, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 301–00000080,
at 23 (Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
edge-based artificial-intelligence tools needed for smart home de-
vices; and Voysis, to increase Siri’s speech recognition accuracy.
2390
(c) Conduct. As with many of Apple’s other products and services,
Apple has taken a walled garden approach to the intelligent voice
assistant market by, among other tactics, limiting interoperability
by restricting how digital voice assistants work on Apple devices
and how Siri works with non-Apple devices, and by using Siri to
guide users to its own products and services.
Apple does not allow competing digital voice assistants to replace
Siri as the default on Apple devices. On iOS devices, the user must
download the app for a competing digital voice assistant and then
either use Siri to access that voice assistant or use that app di-
rectly.
2391
Additionally, Apple does not allow third-party device
manufacturers to install a speaker that receives Siri commands;
only Apple devices can respond to the ‘‘Hey Siri’’ prompt.
2392
While
third-party hardware manufacturers can make their products Siri-
compatible through the Works with Apple HomeKit, the voice com-
mands needed to control the smart devices must still be directed
to Siri on an Apple device, such as an iPhone or iPad.
2393
In addition to keeping Siri closely tied to Apple hardware, Apple
has used its voice-enabled devices to strengthen consumer engage-
ment with its own services and apps. For example, as of October
2020, by default, requests to Siri to play music open the Apple
Music app, requests for directions open the Apple Maps app, and
requests for web searches open the Safari app.
2394
To use a com-
peting service through Siri, a user must adjust the device’s settings
and identify the service in the command to Siri—for example, ‘‘Hey
Siri, play the National Anthem on Spotify.’’
2395
For streaming
music services, this integration only became possible with the in-
troduction of iOS 13 in 2019.
2396
Previously, even when a user said
the name of a third-party streaming service in the voice command,
Apple opened an Apple-branded alternative.
2397
In June 2020,
Apple announced that it would update its HomePod smart speaker
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00322 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
317
2398
Kif Leswing, Apple Will Let iPhone Users Change Default Mail and Browser Apps, Ad-
dressing Antitrust Concerns, CNBC (June 22, 2020), https://www.cnbc.com/2020/06/22/apple-
allows-users-to-change-default-mail-and-browser-apps-at-wwdc.html.
2399
Filipe Esposito, iOS 14 Includes Option to Change Default Services on HomePod for Each
User, 9
TO
5M
AC
(July 7, 2020), https://9to5mac.com/2020/07/07/ios-14-includes-option-to-
change-default-services-on-homepod-for-each-user/.
2400
Submission from Source 711, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Source 711–00000080, at 6–
7 (Oct. 15, 2019) (on file with Comm.).
2401
Id.
2402
Thomas Ricker, Apple To Be Formally Investigated over Spotify’s Antitrust Complaint,
Says Report, V
ERGE
(May 6, 2019), https://www.theverge.com/2019/5/6/18530894/apple-
music-monopoly-spotify-app-store-europe.
2403
Margrethe Vestager, Exec. Vice President, Eur. Comm’n, Statement by Executive Vice
President Margrethe Vestager on the Launch of a Sector Inquiry on the Consumer Internet of
Things (July 16, 2020), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/speechl20l
1367.
2404
Id.
system to support third-party music services.
2398
It remains un-
clear how seamless the integration will be and if Apple Music will
remain the pre-installed default service.
2399
One app developer that spoke with the Subcommittee described
Siri as a ‘‘closed’’ intelligent virtual assistant that limits the types
of voice interactions that voice app developers have access to.
2400
The app developer explained that SiriKit, which allows iOS apps
to work with Siri, relies on a pre-designed list of basic interactions
that third parties can use, such as messaging, calling, or payments.
The very limited set of interactions permitted by Apple can make
it impossible to launch an app for the third party’s services, includ-
ing those that compete with an Apple service.
2401
These practices have recently come under scrutiny by antitrust
authorities. In March 2019, Spotify filed a complaint against Apple
before the European Commission, reportedly alleging, among other
things, that Apple is restricting Spotify’s access to Siri.
2402
In July
2020, the European Commission’s antitrust authority announced
that it had opened an inquiry into the use of digital assistants and
smart home products by Apple, Google, and Amazon, among other
companies.
2403
In her statement accompanying the announcement,
Margrethe Vestager, the Commission’s Executive Vice President,
identified interoperability and self-preferencing as areas of con-
cern.
2404
VI. RECOMMENDATIONS
As part of its top-to-bottom review of competition in digital mar-
kets, the Subcommittee examined whether current laws and en-
forcement levels are adequate to address the market power con-
cerns identified through this investigation. In pursuit of this goal,
on March 13, 2020, the Subcommittee requested submissions from
antitrust and competition policy experts. These experts were cho-
sen on a careful, bipartisan basis to ensure the representation of
a full range of views.
Throughout the investigation, the Subcommittee received addi-
tional submissions and written statements from antitrust enforcers
and other leading experts, including Margrethe Vestager, the Exec-
utive Vice President of the European Commission, and Rod Sims,
the Chair of the Australian Competition and Consumer Commis-
sion. Most recently, the Subcommittee held an oversight hearing on
October 1, 2020 regarding ‘‘Proposals to Strengthen the Antitrust
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00323 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
318
2405
Hon. David N. Cicilline, Chair, Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of
the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, Keynote Address at American Antitrust Institute’s 20th Annual
Policy Conference (June 20, 2019), https://cicilline.house.gov/press-release/cicilline-delivers-key-
note-address-american-antitrust-institute%E2%80%99s-20th-annual-policy.
2406
Due to separation of powers concerns and other relevant considerations, we do not take
a position on the outcome of any individual matter before the Justice Department or the Federal
Trade Commission.
2407
See, e.g., S
UBCOMM
.
ON
S
TUDY OF
M
ONOPOLY
P
OWER OF THE
H. C
OMM
.
ON THE
J
UDICIARY
,
81
ST
C
ONG
. 2
D
S
ESS
., T
HE
A
NTITRUST
L
AWS
: A B
ASIS FOR
E
CONOMIC
F
REEDOM
iii (1950) (identi-
fying an extensive list of statutes ‘‘dealing directly with the preservation of the American com-
petitive economy’’ and reflecting the legislative policy that ‘‘under no circumstances should
[laws] foster the growth of monopoly’’).
Laws and Restore Competition Online,’’ its seventh and final hear-
ing as part of the investigation.
Subcommittee Chair David N. Cicilline (D–RI) requested that
staff provide Members of the Subcommittee with a series of rec-
ommendations, informed by this investigation, on how to strength-
en the antitrust laws and restore competition online. As he noted
in remarks to the American Antitrust Institute in June 2019:
No doubt, other branches of government have a key role to play in the develop-
ment of antitrust law. But Congress—not the courts, agencies, or private compa-
nies—enacted the antitrust laws, and Congress ultimately decides what the law
should be and whether the law is working for the American people. As such, it
is Congress’ responsibility to conduct oversight of our antitrust laws and com-
petition system to ensure that they are properly working and to enact changes
when they are not. While I do not have any preconceived ideas about what the
right answer is, as Chair of the Antitrust Subcommittee, I intend to carry out
that responsibility with the sense of urgency and serious deliberation that it de-
mands.
2405
In response to this request, the Subcommittee identified a broad
set of reforms for further examination by the Members of the Sub-
committee for purposes of crafting legislative and oversight re-
sponses to the findings of this Report. These reforms include pro-
posals to: (1) promote fair competition in digital markets; (2)
strengthen laws relating to mergers and monopolization; and (3) re-
store vigorous oversight and enforcement of the antitrust laws.
The Subcommittee intends for these recommendations to serve as
a complement, not a substitute, to strong enforcement of the anti-
trust laws. This is particularly true for acquisitions by dominant
firms that may have substantially lessened competition or tended
to create a monopoly in violation of the Clayton Act. In these cases,
the Subcommittee supports as a policy matter the examination of
the full range of remedies—including unwinding consummated ac-
quisitions or divesting business lines—to fully restore competition
that was harmed as a result of these acquisitions and to prevent
future violations of the antitrust laws.
2406
A. Restoring Competition in the Digital Economy
For more than a century, Congress has addressed the market
power of dominant intermediaries using a robust antitrust and
antimonopoly toolkit.
2407
The antitrust laws prohibit anticompeti-
tive mergers and monopolistic conduct in order to promote open
markets and prevent undue concentration of economic power. In
many critical sectors of the economy—including financial services,
telecommunications, and transportation—Congress has also relied
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00324 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
319
on a broad set of policies to create the conditions necessary for fair
competition, even when economies of scale may favor concentration.
In a similar vein, the remedies identified in this Section seek to
restore competition online by addressing harmful business prac-
tices as well as certain features of digital markets that tend to tip
the market towards concentration.
1. Reduce Conflicts of Interest Through Structural Separations and
Line of Business Restrictions
In addition to controlling one or multiple key channels of dis-
tribution, the dominant firms investigated by the Subcommittee
are integrated across lines of business. When operating in adjacent
markets, these platforms compete directly with companies that de-
pend on them to access users, giving rise to a conflict of interest.
As discussed earlier in this Report, the Subcommittee’s investiga-
tion uncovered several ways in which Amazon, Apple, Facebook,
and Google use their dominance in one or more markets to advan-
tage their other lines of business, reducing dynamism and innova-
tion.
First, the investigation revealed that the dominant platforms
have misappropriated the data of third parties that rely on their
platforms, effectively collecting information from customers only to
weaponize it against them as rivals. For example, the investigation
produced documents showing that Google used the Android oper-
ating system to closely track usage trends and growth patterns of
third-party apps—near-perfect market intelligence that Google can
use to gain an edge over those same apps. Facebook used its plat-
form tools to identify and then acquire fast-growing third-party
apps, thwarting competitive threats at key moments. A former
Amazon employee told the Subcommittee that Amazon has used
the data of third-party merchants to inform Amazon’s own private
label strategy, identifying which third-party products were selling
well and then introducing copycat versions. These and other exam-
ples detailed in this Report demonstrate a dangerous pattern of
predatory conduct that, if left unchecked, risk further concentrating
wealth and power.
Some have suggested that there is little difference between the
dominant platforms’ access to and use of this data and the way
that brick-and-mortar retailers track popular products. The Sub-
committee’s investigation, however, produced evidence that the
platforms’ access to competitively significant market data is
unique. Specifically, the dominant platforms collect real-time data
which, given the scale of their user-base, is akin to near-perfect
market intelligence. Whereas firms with a choice among business
partners might seek to protect their proprietary data, the plat-
forms’ market power lets them compel the collection of this data in
the first place.
Second, dominant platforms can exploit their integration by
using their dominance in one market as leverage in negotiations in
an unrelated line of business. For example, evidence produced dur-
ing the investigation showed that Amazon has leveraged its domi-
nance in online commerce as pressure during negotiations with
firms in a separate line of business. Market participants that de-
pend on Amazon’s retail platform are effectively forced to accept its
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00325 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
320
2408
See Submission from Sally Hubbard, Dir. of Enf’t Strategy, Open Mkts. Inst., et al., to
H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 7–8 (Apr. 17, 2020) (on file with Comm.) [hereinafter Hubbard Sub-
mission]; Submission from Stacy Mitchell, Co-Dir., Inst. for Local Self-Reliance, to H. Comm.
on the Judiciary, 4 (May 4, 2020) (on file with Comm.) [hereinafter Mitchell Submission]; Sub-
mission from Zephyr Teachout, Assoc. Prof. of Law, Fordham Univ. Sch. of Law, to H. Comm.
on the Judiciary, 6 (Apr. 23, 2020) (on file with Comm.) [hereinafter Teachout Submission]; Sub-
mission from Ams. for Fin. Reform, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3–4 (Apr. 17, 2020) (on file
with Comm.).
2409
Mitchell Submission at 4.
demands—even in markets where Amazon would otherwise lack
the power to set the terms of commerce.
Third, dominant platforms have used their integration to tie
products and services in ways that can lock in users and insulate
the platform from competition. Google, for example, required that
smartphone manufacturers seeking to use Android also pre-install
and give default status to certain Google apps—enabling Google to
maintain its search monopoly and crowd out opportunities for
third-party developers.
And fourth, these firms can use supra-competitive profits from
the markets they dominate to subsidize their entry into other mar-
kets. Documents uncovered during the Subcommittee’s investiga-
tion indicate that the dominant platforms have relied on this strat-
egy to capture markets, as startups and non-platform businesses
tend to lack the resources and capacity to bleed billions of dollars
over multiple years in order to drive out rivals. For dominant plat-
forms, meanwhile, this strategy appears to be a race to capture eco-
systems and control interlocking products that funnel data back to
the platforms, further reinforcing their dominance.
By using market power in one area to advantage a separate line
of business, dominant firms undermine competition on the merits.
By functioning as critical intermediaries that are also integrated
across lines of business, the dominant platforms face a core conflict
of interest. The surveillance data they collect through their inter-
mediary role, meanwhile, lets them exploit that conflict with
unrivaled precision. Their ability both to use their dominance in
one market as negotiating leverage in another, and to subsidize
entry to capture unrelated markets, have the effect of spreading
concentration from one market into others, threatening greater and
greater portions of the digital economy.
To address this underlying conflict of interest, the Subcommittee
recommends that Congress consider legislation that draws on two
mainstay tools of the antimonopoly toolkit: structural separation
and line of business restrictions.
2408
Structural separations pro-
hibit a dominant intermediary from operating in markets that
place the intermediary in competition with the firms dependent on
its infrastructure. Line of business restrictions, meanwhile, gen-
erally limit the markets in which a dominant firm can engage.
Congress has relied on both policy tools as part of a standard
remedy for dominant intermediaries in other network industries,
including railroads and telecommunications services.
2409
In the
railroad industry, for example, a congressional investigation found
that the expansion of common carrier railroads into the coal mar-
ket undermined independent coal producers, whose wares the rail-
roads would deprioritize in order to give themselves superior access
to markets. In 1893, the Committee on Interstate and Foreign
Commerce wrote that ‘‘[n]o competition can exist between two pro-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00326 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
321
2410
H.R. R
EP
. N
O
. 52–2278, at vii–viii (1893).
2411
Hepburn Act, Pub. L. No. 59–337, § 1, 34 Stat. 584, 585 (1906).
2412
Bank Holding Company Act of 1956, Pub. L. No. 84–511, § 4(a), 70 Stat. 133, 135 (codi-
fied as amended at 12 U.S.C. 1843(a)).
2413
Report and Order, Amendment of Rules Regarding Competition and Responsibility in
Network Television Broadcasting, 23 F.C.C.2d 382, 398 ¶ 30 (1970).
2414
Mitchell Submission at 4.
2415
John Kwoka & Tommaso Valletti, Scrambled Eggs and Paralyzed Policy: Breaking Up
Consummated Mergers and Dominant Firms (forthcoming Oct. 2020) (manuscript at 22) (on file
with Comm.).
2416
OECD, S
TRUCTURAL
S
EPARATION IN
R
EGULATED
I
NDUSTRIES
: R
EPORT ON
I
MPLEMENTING
THE
OECD R
ECOMMENDATION
9 (2016), https://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/Structural-sepa-
ration-in-regulated-industries-2016report-en.pdf (‘‘[S]eparation limits the need for regulation that
is difficult and costly to devise and implement, and may be only partly effective; it improves
information; and it eliminates the risk of cross-subsidies by the incumbent from its non-competi-
tive to its competitive segments.’’).
2417
See, e.g., Submission from Maureen K. Ohlhausen, Partner, Baker Botts L.L.P., to H.
Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Apr. 17, 2020) (on file with Comm.).
ducers of a commodity when one of them has the power to pre-
scribe both the price and output of the other.’’
2410
Congress subsequently enacted a provision to prohibit railroads
from transporting any goods that they had produced or in which
they held an interest.
2411
Congress has legislated similar prohibi-
tions in other markets. The Bank Holding Company Act of 1956
broadly prohibited bank holding companies from acquiring non-
banking companies.
2412
Vertically integrated television networks,
meanwhile, were subject to ‘‘fin-syn’’ rules, which prohibited net-
works from entering production and syndication markets.
2413
Both structural separations and line of business restrictions seek
to eliminate the conflict of interest faced by a dominant inter-
mediary when it enters markets that place it in competition with
dependent businesses. In certain cases, structural separations have
also been used to prevent monopolistic firms from subsidizing entry
into competitive markets and to promote media diversity.
2414
At a general level, there are two forms of structural separation:
(1) ownership separations, which require divestiture and separate
ownership of each business; and (2) functional separations, which
permit a single corporate entity to engage in multiple lines of busi-
ness but prescribe the particular organizational form it must
take.
2415
Importantly, both forms of structural limits apply on a
market-wide basis, while divestitures in antitrust enforcement gen-
erally apply to a single firm or merging party.
A benefit of these proposals is their administrability. By setting
rules for the underlying structure of the market—rather than polic-
ing anticompetitive conduct on an ad hoc basis—structural rules
are easier to administer than conduct remedies, which can require
close and continuous monitoring.
2416
The challenges of crafting and implementing structural solutions
vary by market and market participants. In response to the Sub-
committee’s requests for comments on potential reforms, some anti-
trust experts have cautioned that crafting separations can pose a
major cost and challenge, especially in dynamic markets.
2417
Oth-
ers have responded by identifying certain principles that can make
identifying the fault lines easier. In the case of separations undoing
vertical mergers, the fault lines designating the separate compa-
nies are likely to still be apparent, even in the new struc-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00327 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
322
2418
John Kwoka & Tommaso Valletti, Scrambled Eggs and Paralyzed Policy: Breaking Up
Consummated Mergers and Dominant Firms (forthcoming Oct. 2020) (manuscript at 11) (on file
with Comm.).
2419
Id. at 15.
2420
Id.; Rory Van Loo, In Defense of Breakups: Administering a ‘‘Radical’’ Remedy, 105 C
OR
-
NELL
L. R
EV
. (forthcoming 2020), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3646630.
2421
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 405–06.
2422
OECD, S
TRUCTURAL
S
EPARATION IN
R
EGULATED
I
NDUSTRIES
: R
EPORT ON
I
MPLEMENTING
THE
OECD R
ECOMMENDATION
9 (2016), https://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/Structural-
separation-in-regulated-industries-2016report-en.pdf.
2423
Id. at 3.
ture.
2418
In cases where a firm grew through internal expansion or
when the constituent parts are no longer clearly distinguishable,
scholars have suggested identifying distinct business oper-
ations.
2419
Experts have also noted that business-initiated cor-
porate restructuring and divestitures may in some cases also pro-
vide a guide to designing and implementing successful break-
ups.
2420
Several enforcement bodies around the world are exploring the
use of structural separations in digital markets. In July 2020, the
United Kingdom’s Competition and Markets Authority rec-
ommended that its digital regulatory body have powers to ‘‘imple-
ment ownership separation or operational separation,’’ concluding
that ‘‘there could be significant benefits if there were more formal
separation between businesses with market power’’ in digital ad-
vertising markets in particular.
2421
Meanwhile, the OECD in 2001
adopted recommendations to structurally separate vertically inte-
grated regulated firms that operate in concentrated mar-
kets.
2422
In its 15-year overview, the OECD concluded that ‘‘struc-
tural separation remains a relevant remedy’’ and identified other
market areas where it might be adopted.
2423
2. Implement Rules to Prevent Discrimination, Favoritism, and
Self-Preferencing
As discussed throughout this Report, the Subcommittee identi-
fied numerous instances in which dominant platforms engaged in
preferential or discriminatory treatment. In some cases, the domi-
nant platform privileged its own products or services. In others, the
dominant platform gave preferential treatment to one business
partner over others. Because the dominant platform was, in most
instances, the only viable path to market, its discriminatory treat-
ment had the effect of picking winners and losers in the market-
place.
Google, for example, engaged in self-preferencing by systemati-
cally ranking its own content above third-party content, even when
its content was inferior or less relevant for users. Web publishers
of content that Google demoted suffered economic losses and had
no way of competing on the merits. Over the course of the inves-
tigation, numerous third parties also told the Subcommittee that
self-preferencing and discriminatory treatment by the dominant
platforms forced businesses to lay off employees and divert re-
sources away from developing new products and towards paying a
dominant platform for advertisements or other ancillary services.
They added that some of the harmful business practices of the plat-
forms discouraged investors from supporting their business and
made it challenging to grow and sustain a business even with high-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00328 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
323
2424
See, e.g., Submission from Harry First, Charles L. Denison Prof. of Law, N.Y.U. Sch. of
Law & Eleanor Fox, Walter J. Derenberg Prof. of Trade Reg., N.Y.U. Sch. of Law, to H. Comm.
on the Judiciary, 5 (Aug. 6, 2020) [hereinafter First & Fox Submission] (‘‘[Google, Amazon,
Facebook, and Apple] are akin to essential facilities for many smaller businesses. Many busi-
nesses, to do business, must use the platform. They have almost no choice. The GAFA compete
with the businesses on their platforms.’’) (on file with Comm.); Submission from Albert A. Foer,
Founder & Senior Fellow, Am. Antitrust Inst., to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 1–2 (Apr. 14,
2020) (on file with Comm.) [hereinafter Foer Submission]; Hubbard Submission at 5–7; Rem-
edies Hearing 6–7 (statement of K. Sabeel Rahman, President, Demos).
2425
Hubbard Submission at 4–5.
2426
Report and Order on Remand, Protecting and Promoting the Open Internet, 30 FCC Rcd.
5601, 5603 ¶ 4 (2015) (‘‘[C]arefully-tailored rules that would prevent specific practices we know
are harmful to Internet openness—blocking, throttling, and paid prioritization—as well as a
strong standard of conduct designed to prevent the deployment of new practices that would
harm Internet openness.’’).
2427
Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Fines Google Ö2.42 Billion for Abus-
ing Dominance as Search Engine by Giving Illegal Advantage to Own Comparison Shopping
Service (June 27, 2017), https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/MEMOl17l
1785.
2428
Hubbard Submission at 5.
2429
See, e.g., Submission from Hal Singer, Managing Dir., Econ One Research, to H. Comm.
on the Judiciary, 4–5 (Mar. 30, 2020) (on file with Comm.) [hereinafter Singer Submission].
2430
Id.
ly popular products. Without the opportunity to compete fairly,
businesses and entrepreneurs are dissuaded from investing and,
over the long term, innovation suffers.
In response to these concerns, the Subcommittee recommends
that Congress consider establishing nondiscrimination rules to en-
sure fair competition and to promote innovation online. Non-
discrimination rules would require dominant platforms to offer
equal terms for equal service and would apply to price as well as
to terms of access. As several experts noted, nondiscrimination has
been a mainstay principle for governing network intermediaries,
especially those that play essential roles in facilitating transpor-
tation and communications.
2424
The 1887 Interstate Commerce Act, for example, prohibited dis-
criminatory treatment by railroads.
2425
In the years since, Con-
gress and policymakers have continued to apply nondiscrimination
principles to network monopolies, even as technologies have rapidly
evolved. Most recently, the Open Internet Order written by the
Federal Communications Commission (FCC) in 2015 was effectively
a nondiscrimination regime, prohibiting internet service providers
from picking winners and losers among content providers and other
users.
2426
Other jurisdictions have begun to apply nondiscrimina-
tion principles to digital markets. For example, after determining
that Google had engaged in illegal self-preferencing, the European
Commission required that Google follow ‘‘the simple principle of
equal treatment.’’
2427
Historically, Congress has implemented nondiscrimination re-
quirements in a variety of markets. With railroads, the Interstate
Commerce Commission oversaw obligations and prohibitions ap-
plied to railroads designated as common carriers.
2428
More re-
cently, the Cable Act of 1992 included a provision requiring the
Federal Communications Commission to oversee a nondiscrimina-
tion requirement for cable operators.
2429
Some experts have pro-
posed establishing a similar venue to adjudicate discrimination dis-
putes between dominant platforms and the third parties that de-
pend on them.
2430
Others note that the Federal Trade Commission
could also use its existing competition rulemaking authority to ‘‘re-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00329 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
324
2431
First & Fox Submission at 12.
2432
See United States v. AT&T Co., 552 F. Supp. 131 (D.D.C. 1982).
2433
Mitchell Submission at 4 (‘‘It’s important to note here that applying this kind of [non-
discrimination-based] regulatory oversight to the big tech firms will not be effective unless it’s
done in conjunction with breakups. In the case of Amazon, it’s my view that several factors
make it virtually impossible to establish a system of oversight and adjudication that would be
robust enough to protect competition and fair market access, absent spinning off its shopping
platform from its other divisions. These factors include the enormous number of sellers and
transactions, the low dollar value of most transactions, and the many subtle and hard-to-detect
ways that Amazon can skew outcomes to favor its own interests. Therefore, oversight must be
combined with structural separation, which would do much of the work by removing the under-
lying conflicts of interest, thus allowing for an effective and less bureaucratic system of over-
sight.’’).
2434
Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 10–11.
2435
See Stigler Report at 29; Michael Kades & Fiona Scott Morton, Interoperability as a Com-
petition Remedy for Digital Networks 1 (Wash. Ctr. for Equitable Growth Working Paper Series,
2020), https://equitablegrowth.org/working-papers/interoperability-as-a-competition-remedy-for-
digital-networks/ (‘‘The monopolist operates in a market with significant network effects, scale
and scope economies, and low distribution costs. Therefore, the competition that matters most
is often for the market not within the market. Anticompetitive conduct is more likely to succeed.
And, the harm to consumers greater because the market tends to be winner-take-all, or most,
(it ‘tips’).’’).
quire dominant gatekeepers to apply a rule of neutrality in oper-
ating their platforms.’’
2431
Finally, on several occasions, nondiscrimination rules have been
treated as an important complement to divestitures in antitrust en-
forcement. For example, the Justice Department combined AT&T’s
divestiture of the Regional Bell Operating Companies with an
equal access obligation, requiring AT&T to offer independent long-
distance providers access to its network on equal terms of quality
and price.
2432
The DOJ argued that requiring equal access without
mandating divestiture would be insufficient due to AT&T’s incen-
tive and ability to discriminate against local carriers.
2433
3. Promote Innovation Through Interoperability and Open Access
As discussed elsewhere in the Report, digital markets have cer-
tain characteristics—such as network effects, switching costs, and
other entry barriers—that make them prone to tipping in favor of
a single dominant firm. As a result, these markets are no longer
contestable by new entrants,
2434
and the competitive process shifts
from ‘‘competition in the market to competition for the mar-
ket.’’
2435
This dynamic is particularly evident in the social networking
market. As discussed earlier in the Report, Facebook’s internal doc-
uments and communications indicate that, due to strong network
effects and market tipping, the most significant competitive pres-
sure to Facebook is from within its own family of products—
Facebook, Instagram, Messenger, and WhatsApp—rather than
from other social apps in the market, such as Snapchat or Twitter.
In the case of messaging apps, Facebook’s documents show that
network effects can be even more extreme. And because Facebook
is not interoperable with other social networks, its users face high
costs to switch to other platforms, locking them into Facebook’s
platform.
High switching costs are also present in other markets. In the
smartphone market, switching costs include learning a new oper-
ating system, which can discourage users from leaving Google or
Apple due to familiarity with their distinct operating systems, as
well as the inability to easily port all of their data, such as mes-
sages, call history, and photos. In online commerce, sellers have
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00330 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
325
2436
Chris Riley, A Framework for Forward-Looking Tech Competition Policy 10 (Mozilla
Working Paper, 2019), https://blog.mozilla.org/netpolicy/files/2019/09/Mozilla-Competition-
Working-Paper.pdf.
2437
See generally id. at 18–24.
2438
Michael Kades & Fiona Scott Morton, Interoperability as a Competition Remedy for Dig-
ital Networks 14 (Wash. Ctr. for Equitable Growth Working Paper Series, 2020), https://
equitablegrowth.org/working-papers/interoperability-as-a-competition-remedy-for-digital-net-
works/.
2439
Becky Chao & Ross Schulman, Promoting Platform Interoperability, N
EW
A
M
. F
OUND
.
(May 13, 2020), https://www.newamerica.org/oti/reports/promoting-platform-interoperability/.
2440
Chris Riley, A Framework for Forward-Looking Tech Competition Policy 18 (Mozilla
Working Paper, 2019), https://blog.mozilla.org/netpolicy/files/2019/09/Mozilla-Competition-
Working-Paper.pdf.
2441
Becky Chao & Ross Schulman, Promoting Platform Interoperability, N
EW
A
M
. F
OUND
.
(May 13, 2020), https://www.newamerica.org/oti/reports/promoting-platform-interoperability/.
2442
Michael Kades & Fiona Scott Morton, Interoperability as a Competition Remedy for Dig-
ital Networks 13–14 (Wash. Ctr. for Equitable Growth Working Paper Series, 2020), https://
equitablegrowth.org/working-papers/interoperability-as-a-competition-remedy-for-digital-net-
works/.
2443
Id.
2444
Competition in Digital Technology Markets: Examining Self-Preferencing by Digital Plat-
forms: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Competition Policy and Consumer Rights of
the S. Comm. on the Judiciary, 116th Cong. 21 (2020) (statement of Sally Hubbard, Dir. of Enf’t
Strategy, Open Mkts. Inst.) (‘‘Interoperability is an anti-monopoly tool that has been used suc-
cessfully many times to promote innovation by reducing barriers to entering markets.’’).
2445
Michael Kades & Fiona Scott Morton, Interoperability as a Competition Remedy for Dig-
ital Networks 13–14 (Wash. Ctr. for Equitable Growth Working Paper Series, 2020), https://
equitablegrowth.org/working-papers/interoperability-as-a-competition-remedy-for-digital-net-
works/.
high switching costs associated with their reputation. Sellers can
be locked into an incumbent platform for online commerce if they
are unable to transfer their reputation—ratings and customer re-
views accrued over a long period of time—to a different platform.
Switching costs involving data for other services, such as email,
can also contribute to user lock-in.
2436
In response to these con-
cerns, the Subcommittee recommends that Congress consider data
interoperability and portability to encourage competition by low-
ering entry barriers for competitors and switching costs for con-
sumers. These reforms would complement vigorous antitrust en-
forcement by spurring competitive entry.
(a) Interoperability. Interoperability is fundamental to the open
internet.
2437
It is present in email, which is an open, interoperable
protocol for communicating online regardless of a person’s email
service or the type of device they use to send the email.
2438
It has
also been built into numerous other services online
2439
and is a
‘‘core technical structure of the Internet.’’
2440
Interoperability
standards are also present in other communications systems, from
telephones to telegraphs.
2441
Telecommunications would not work
without the ability of users on one carrier’s network to interconnect
with other carriers.
2442
And in the absence of interoperability, dom-
inant carriers could foreclose new entrants from offering lower
prices or better services, reinforcing their monopoly power while
harming consumers and competition.
2443
An interoperability requirement would allow competing social
networking platforms to interconnect with dominant firms to en-
sure that users can communicate across services.
2444
Foremost,
interoperability ‘‘breaks the power of network effects’’ by allowing
new entrants to take advantage of existing network effects ‘‘at the
level of the market, not the level of the company.’’
2445
It would
also lower switching costs for users by ensuring that they do not
lose access to their network as a result of switching.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00331 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
326
2446
Id. at 15 (‘‘Unlike the familiar AT&T example, there would be no cost to interconnection
in the digital platform context. The standard is simply a way to present and transfer informa-
tion that is already being presented and transferred. No wire needs to be connected to achieve
it, nor do machines need to be co-located, or special workers employed. Transferring digital files
has almost zero cost, but regardless of that cost, Facebook would be transferring those files to
serve its users in any case. Facebook might need to pay some costs to redesign the format in
which it transfers text and images, but if it has been found liable for monopolization by a court,
it is expected that a remedy will have costs. The real cost of ongoing interoperability to
Facebook.com is the possibility that it loses customers once the barriers to entry fall. But that
risk is what every firm faces in a competitive market and represents a benefit to consumers.’’).
2447
Id. at 10 (‘‘A divestiture may reduce the existing market power of the dominant network
but not eliminate the market power due to network effects that was achieved through anti-
competitive conduct. And, alone, divestiture may not prevent future tipping. Thus, on their own,
they risk being insufficient to fully restore the lost competition.’’).
2448
See J
OSHUA
G
ANS
, T
HE
H
AMILTON
P
ROJECT
, E
NHANCING
C
OMPETITION WITH
D
ATA AND
I
DENTITY
P
ORTABILITY
5 (2018), http://www.hamiltonproject.org/assets/files/Gansl20180611
.pdf.
2449
See id.
2450
See Josh Constine, Friend Portability Is the Must-Have Facebook Regulation,
T
ECH
C
RUNCH
(May 12, 2019), https://technologycrunch.com/2019/05/12/friends-wherever;
Chris Dixon, The Interoperability of Social Networks, B
US
. I
NSIDER
(Nov. 10, 2010), https://
www.businessinsider.com/the-interoperability-of-social-networks-2011-2; Data and Privacy Hear-
ing at 134 (statement of Dina Srinivasan, Fellow, Yale Thurman Arnold Project).
2451
Submission from Charlotte Slaiman, Competition Policy Dir., Pub. Knowledge, to H.
Comm. on the Judiciary (May 14, 2020) (on file with Comm.) [hereinafter Slaiman Submission];
id., app. I, at 3–4 (statement of Gene Kimmelman, Senior Advisor, Pub. Knowledge).
2452
Competition in Digital Technology Markets: Examining Self-Preferencing by Digital Plat-
forms: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Competition Policy and Consumer Rights of
the S. Comm. on the Judiciary, 116th Cong. 21 (2020) (statement of Sally Hubbard, Dir. of Enf’t
Strategy, Open Mkts. Inst.) (on file with Comm.). Last year, Senators Mark R. Warner (D–VA),
Josh Hawley (R–MO), and Richard Blumenthal (D–CT) introduced S.2658, the ‘‘Augmenting
Continued
The implementation cost of requiring interoperability by domi-
nant firms would be relatively low. Unlike interconnecting in tradi-
tional communications markets, there is little direct cost associated
with interoperating with dominant platforms.
2446
Finally, interoperability is an important complement, not sub-
stitute, to vigorous antitrust enforcement. As discussed in this Re-
port, Facebook has tipped the social network toward a monopoly,
and due to its strong network effects, does not face competitive
pressure. On its own, interoperability is unlikely to fully restore
competition in the social networking market due to the lack of
meaningful competition in the market today. On the other hand, in
the absence of procompetitive policies like interoperability, it is
also possible that enforcement alone may provide incomplete relief
due to future market tipping.
2447
(b) Data Portability. Data portability is also a remedy for high
costs associated with leaving a dominant platform. These costs
present another barrier to entry for competitors and a barrier to
exit for consumers. Dominant platforms can maintain market
power in part because consumers experience significant frictions
when moving to a new product.
2448
Users contribute data to a plat-
form, for example, but can find it hard to migrate that data to a
rival platform.
2449
The difficulty of switching tends to keep users
on incumbent platforms.
2450
Providing consumers and businesses
with tools to easily port or rebuild their social graph, profile, or
other relevant data on a competing platform would help address
these concerns.
2451
Although complementary to interoperability,
data portability alone would not fully address concerns related to
network effects since consumers would still need to recreate their
networks on a new platform and would not be able to communicate
with their network on the incumbent platform.
2452
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00332 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
327
Compatibility and Competition by Enabling Service Switching (ACCESS) Act of 2019,’’ bipar-
tisan legislation to require that dominant platforms make user data portable and their services
interoperable. Additionally, this proposal would also allow users to delegate management of
their privacy preferences to a third-party service. Press Release, Sen. Mark R. Warner, Senators
Introduce Bipartisan Bill to Encourage Competition in Social Media (Oct. 22, 2019), https://
www.warner.senate.gov/public/index.cfm/2019/10/senators-introduce-bipartisan-bill-to-encour-
age-competition-in-social-media.
2453
Chaim Gartenberg, Google Buys Fitbit for $2.1 Billion, V
ERGE
(Nov. 1, 2019), https://
www.theverge.com/2019/11/1/20943318/google-fitbit-acquisition-fitness-tracker-announcement;
Lauren Feiner & Jordan Novet, Google Cloud Boss Thomas Kurian Makes His First Big Move—
Buys Looker for $2.6 Billion, CNBC (June 6, 2019), https://www.cnbc.com/2019/06/06/google-
buys-cloud-company-looker-for-2point6-billion.html; Karen Weise & Erin Griffith, Amazon to Buy
Zoox, in a Move Toward Self-Driving Cars, N.Y. T
IMES
(June 26, 2020), https://www.
nytimes.com/2020/06/26/business/amazon-zoox.html; Kurt Wagner & Sarah Frier, Facebook
Buys Animated Image Library Giphy for $400 Million, B
LOOMBERG
(May 15, 2020), https://
www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2020-05-15/facebook-buys-animated-image-library-giphy-to-
boost-messaging.
2454
See infra Appendix.
4. Reduce Market Power Through Merger Presumptions
The firms investigated by the Subcommittee owe part of their
dominance to mergers and acquisitions. Several of the platforms
built entire lines of business through acquisitions, while others
used acquisitions at key moments to neutralize competitive threats.
Although the dominant platforms collectively engaged in several
hundred mergers and acquisitions between 2000–2019, antitrust
enforcers did not block a single one of these transactions. The Sub-
committee’s investigation revealed that several of these acquisi-
tions enabled the dominant platforms to block emerging rivals and
undermine competition.
Despite a significant number of ongoing antitrust investigations,
the dominant platforms have continued to pursue significant deal-
making. Over the last year, for example, Google purchased Fitbit
for $2.1 billion and Looker for $2.6 billion; Amazon purchased Zoox
for $1.3 billion; and Facebook acquired Giphy for an undisclosed
amount.
2453
Meanwhile, all four of the firms investigated by the
Subcommittee have recently focused on acquiring startups in the
artificial intelligence and virtual reality spaces.
2454
Ongoing acquisitions by the dominant platforms raise several
concerns. Insofar as any transaction entrenches their existing posi-
tion, or eliminates a nascent competitor, it strengthens their mar-
ket power and can close off market entry. Furthermore, by pur-
suing additional deals in artificial intelligence and in other emerg-
ing markets, the dominant firms of today could position themselves
to control the technology of tomorrow.
It is unclear whether the antitrust agencies are presently
equipped to block anticompetitive mergers in digital markets. The
record of the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) and the Justice De-
partment in this area shows significant missteps and repeat en-
forcement failures. While both agencies are currently pursuing re-
views of pending transactions, it is not yet clear whether they have
developed the analytical tools to challenge anticompetitive deals in
digital markets. For example, the Justice Department in February
permitted Google’s acquisition of Looker, a data analytics and busi-
ness intelligence startup, despite serious risks that the deal would
eliminate an independent rival and could allow Google to cut off ac-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00333 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
328
2455
Letter from Diana L. Moss, President, Am. Antitrust Inst., to Hon. Makan Delrahim, As-
sistant Att’y Gen., U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Antitrust Div. (July 8, 2019), https://www.antitrust
institute.org/wp-content/uploads/2019/07/AAI-Ltr-to-DOJlGoogle-Lookerl7.8.19.pdf.
2456
Free and Diverse Press Hearing at 21 (statement of David Chavern, President & CEO,
News Media All.) (‘‘In effect, a couple of dominant tech platforms are acting as regulators of
the digital news industry.’’).
2457
Submission of Source 52, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 12 (Oct. 30, 2019) (on file with
Comm.).
2458
Submission from Source 53, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 7 (Oct. 14, 2019) (on file with
Comm.). Although Apple News and Apple News Plus are increasingly popular news aggregators,
most market participants that the Subcommittee received evidence from during the investiga-
tion do not view Apple as a critical intermediary for online news at this time. Some publishers
raised competition concerns about the tying of payment inside Apple’s news product.
2459
Press Release, Rep. David N. Cicilline, Cicilline, Collins Introduce Bill to Provide Lifeline
to Local News (Apr. 3, 2019), https://cicilline.house.gov/press-release/cicilline-collins-introduce-
bill-provide-lifeline-local-news.
cess to rivals.
2455
These concerns are especially acute today, given
the combined national health and economic crises, which have wid-
ened the gap between the dominant platforms and businesses
across the rest of the economy.
To address this concern, the Subcommittee recommends that
Congress consider shifting presumptions for future acquisitions by
the dominant platforms. Under this change, any acquisition by a
dominant platform would be presumed anticompetitive unless the
merging parties could show that the transaction was necessary for
serving the public interest and that similar benefits could not be
achieved through internal growth and expansion. This process
would occur outside the current Hart-Scott-Rodino Act (HSR) proc-
ess, such that the dominant platforms would be required to report
all transactions and no HSR deadlines would be triggered. Estab-
lishing this presumption would better reflect Congress’s preference
for growth through ingenuity and investment rather than through
acquisition.
5. Create an Even Playing Field for the Free and Diverse Press
The free and diverse press—particularly local press—is the back-
bone of a healthy and vibrant democracy. But as discussed in this
Report, the rise of market power online has corresponded with a
significant decline in the availability of trustworthy sources of
news.
2456
Through dominating both digital advertising and key
communication platforms, Google and Facebook have outsized
power over the distribution and monetization of trustworthy
sources of news online,
2457
creating an uneven playing field in
which news publishers are beholden to their decisions.
2458
To address this imbalance of bargaining power, we recommend
that the Subcommittee consider legislation to provide news pub-
lishers and broadcasters with a narrowly tailored and temporary
safe harbor to collectively negotiate with dominant online plat-
forms.
In April 2019, Subcommittee Chair Cicilline and Doug Collins
(R–GA), the former Ranking Member of the Committee on the Ju-
diciary, introduced H.R. 2054, the ‘‘Journalism Competition and
Preservation Act of 2019.’’
2459
H.R. 2054 would allow coordination
by news publishers under the antitrust laws if it: (1) directly re-
lates to the quality, accuracy, attribution or branding, or interoper-
ability of news; (2) benefits the entire industry, rather than just a
few publishers, and is non-discriminatory to other news publishers;
and (3) directly relates to and is reasonably necessary for these ne-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00334 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
329
2460
Id.
2461
Id.
2462
See generally Submission from Sanjukta Paul, Assistant Prof. of Law, Wayne State Univ.,
to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2–4 (Apr. 21, 2020) (on file with Comm.) [hereinafter Paul Sub-
mission].
2463
See, e.g., Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 17 (1914); Capper-Volstead Act, Pub. L. No. 67–146, ch.
57, 42 Stat. 388 (1922) (codified as amended at 7 U.S.C. 291–292).
2464
Aviv Nevo, Deputy Assistant Att’y Gen. for Econ., U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Antitrust Div.,
Mergers that Increase Bargaining Leverage, Remarks at the Stanford Institute for Economic
Policy Research 7 (Jan. 22, 2014), https://www.justice.gov/atr/file/517781/download (‘‘[A]s a
matter of economic theory and case law bargaining leverage is a source of market power.’’).
gotiations, instead of being used for other purposes. As Sub-
committee Chair Cicilline noted at the time of the bill’s introduc-
tion:
The free press is a cornerstone of our democracy. Journalists keep the public in-
formed, root out corruption, and hold the powerful accountable. This bill will pro-
vide a much-needed lifeline to local publishers who have been crushed by Google
and Facebook. It’s about time we take a stand on this issue.
2460
Mr. Collins added that the proposed legislation would allow ‘‘com-
munity newspapers to more fairly negotiate with large tech plat-
forms that are operating in an increasingly anticompetitive space,’’
which would ‘‘help protect journalism, promote competition and
allow communities to stay informed.’’
2461
We recommend the consideration of this legislation as part of a
broader set of reforms to address the rise of market power online.
This proposed legislation follows a long congressional tradition of
allocating coordination rights to individuals or entities that lack
bargaining power in a marketplace.
2462
Although antitrust exemp-
tions have been disfavored, at various times lawmakers have cre-
ated exemptions in order to rectify imbalances of power or to pro-
mote non-competition values.
2463
In this instance, the risk associ-
ated with antitrust exemptions to preserve the free and diverse
press—a bedrock constitutional value—is low, while the benefits of
preserving access to high-quality journalism are difficult to over-
state. As discussed earlier in the Report, the bill would follow steps
that other jurisdictions are similarly taking to rebalance the power
between news publishers and the dominant platforms.
6. Prohibit Abuse of Superior Bargaining Power and Require Due
Process
By virtue of functioning as the only viable path to market, domi-
nant platforms enjoy superior bargaining power over the third par-
ties that depend on their platforms to access users and markets.
Their bargaining leverage is a form of market power,
2464
which the
dominant platforms routinely use to protect and expand their domi-
nance.
Through its investigation, the Subcommittee identified numerous
instances in which the dominant platforms abused this power. In
several cases, dominant platforms used their leverage to extract
greater money or data than users would be willing to provide in a
competitive market. While a firm in a competitive market would
lose business if it charged excessive prices for its goods or services
because the customer would switch to a competitor, dominant plat-
forms have been able to charge excessive prices or ratchet up their
prices without a significant loss of business. Similarly, certain dom-
inant platforms have been able to extort an ever-increasing amount
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00335 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
330
2465
See, e.g., Dig. Competition Expert Panel Report at 45 (noting how a report commissioned
by the UK’s Department for Digital, Culture, Media & Sport found that, as ‘‘a consequence of
their high market share, ownership of key technologies and strong user data assets, Google and
Facebook are, to some extent, able to set their own terms to advertisers and publishers’’).
2466
Foer Submission at 2–3; Submission from Marshall Steinbaum, Assistant Prof. of Econ.,
Univ. of Utah, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 8 (Apr. 2020) (on file with Comm.) [hereinafter
Steinbaum Submission]. See generally Austl. Competition & Consumer Comm’n Report at 205–
79; Competition & Mkts. Auth. Report at 328–49.
2467
See generally First & Fox Submission at 10–11; Steinbaum Submission; Submission from
Robert H. Lande, Venable Prof. of Law, Univ. of Balt. Sch. of Law, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary
(Apr. 16, 2020) (on file with Comm.) [hereinafter Lande Submission]; Paul Submission at 2–4;
Submission from Maurice Stucke, Douglas A. Blaze Distinguished Prof. of Law, Univ. of Ten-
nessee, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Mar. 13, 2020) (on file with Comm.) [hereinafter
Stucke Submission].
2468
Thomas J. Horton, Rediscovering Antitrust’s Lost Values, 16 U.N.H. L. R
EV
. 179 (2018).
2469
See generally Submission from Tim Wu, Julius Silver Prof. of Law, Columbia Law Sch.,
to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Apr. 25, 2020) (on file with Comm.) [hereinafter Wu Submission];
Continued
of data from their customers and users, ranging from a user’s per-
sonal data to a business’s trade secrets and proprietary content. In
the absence of an alternative platform, users effectively have no
choice but to accede to the platform’s demands for payment wheth-
er in the form of dollars or data.
The Subcommittee’s investigation found that dominant platforms
have also leveraged their market power in negotiations with busi-
nesses and individuals to dictate the terms of the relationship. The
dominant platforms frequently impose oppressive contractual provi-
sions or offer ‘‘take-it-or-leave-it’’ terms in contract negotiations—
even when dealing with relatively large companies represented by
sophisticated counsel.
2465
Lacking bargaining power, dependent
third parties often find themselves at the whims of the platform’s
arbitrary decisions. The Subcommittee encountered numerous in-
stances in which a third party had been abruptly delisted or de-
moted from a platform, without notice or explanation, and often
without a clear avenue for recourse.
The dominant platforms’ ability to abuse their superior bar-
gaining power in these ways can cause long-term and far-reaching
harm. To address these issues, the Subcommittee recommends that
Congress consider prohibiting the abuse of superior bargaining
power, including by targeting potentially anticompetitive contracts
and introducing due process protections for individuals and busi-
nesses dependent on the dominant platforms.
2466
B. Strengthening the Antitrust Laws
1. Restore the Antimonopoly Goals of the Antitrust Laws
The antitrust laws that Congress enacted in 1890 and 1914—the
Sherman Act, the Clayton Act, and the Federal Trade Commission
Act—reflected a recognition that unchecked monopoly power poses
a threat to our economy as well as to our democracy.
2467
Congress
reasserted this vision through subsequent antitrust laws, including
the Robinson-Patman Act of 1936, the Celler-Kefauver Act of 1950,
and the Hart-Scott-Rodino Act of 1976.
2468
In the decades since Congress enacted these foundational stat-
utes, the courts have significantly weakened these laws and made
it increasingly difficult for federal antitrust enforcers and private
plaintiffs to successfully challenge anticompetitive conduct and
mergers.
2469
By adopting a narrow construction of ‘‘consumer wel-
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00336 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
331
Submission from Spencer Weber Waller, John Paul Stevens Chair in Competition Law, Loyola
Univ. Chi. Sch. of Law, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Apr. 28, 2020) (on file with Comm.) [here-
inafter Waller Submission].
2470
Jonathan Sallet, Protecting the ‘‘Competitive Process’’—The Evolution of Antitrust Enforce-
ment in the United States, W
ASH
. C
TR
.
FOR
E
QUITABLE
G
ROWTH
(Oct. 31, 2018), https://
equitablegrowth.org/competitive-edge-protecting-the-competitive-process-the-evolution-of-antitrust-
enforcement-in-the-united-states/.
2471
Submission from John Newman, Assoc. Prof. of Law, Univ. of Miami Sch. of Law, to the
Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 2 (Apr.
1, 2020) (on file with Comm.) [hereinafter Newman Submission]; Stucke Submission at 2.
2472
21 C
ONG
. R
EC
. 3146 (1890) (statement of Sen. George F. Hoar).
2473
See Wu Submission at 2 (‘‘If read broadly, the prohibitions on ‘monopolization,’ ‘unfair
means of competition,’ and ‘restraints on trade’ could be used to handle the challenges of our
time. But ‘broadly’ is manifestly not how the laws are read by the judiciary at this point. For
the courts have grafted onto these laws burdens of proof, special requirements and defenses that
are found nowhere in the statutes, and that have rendered the laws applicable only to the nar-
rowest of scenarios, usually those involving blatant price effects. And it is this that makes the
laws inadequate for the challenges presented by digital markets.’’).
2474
See generally First & Fox Submission at 10–11; Stucke Submission at 2; Wu Submission;
Waller Submission.
2475
15 U.S.C. 18; accord Clayton Antitrust Act of 1914, Pub. L. No. 63–212, § 7, ch. 323, 38
Stat. 730, 731–32 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. 18).
2476
Celler-Kefauver Anti-Merger Act, Pub. L. No. 81–899, ch. 1184, 64 Stat. 1125, 1125–26
(1950) (amending 15 U.S.C. 18).
fare’’ as the sole goal of the antitrust laws, the Supreme Court has
limited the analysis of competitive harm to focus primarily on price
and output rather than the competitive process
2470
—contravening
legislative history and legislative intent.
2471
Simultaneously, courts
have adopted the view that underenforcement of the antitrust laws
is preferable to overenforcement, a position at odds with the clear
legislative intent of the antitrust laws, as well as the view of Con-
gress that private monopolies are a ‘‘menace to republican institu-
tions.’’
2472
In recent decades, the Justice Department and the FTC
have contributed to this problem by taking a narrow view of their
legal authorities and issuing guidelines that are highly permissive
of market power and its abuse. The overall result is an approach
to antitrust that has significantly diverged from the laws that Con-
gress enacted.
In part due to this narrowing, some of the anticompetitive busi-
ness practices that the Subcommittee’s investigation uncovered
could be difficult to challenge under current law.
2473
In response to
this concern, this Section identifies specific legislative reforms that
would help renew and rehabilitate the antitrust laws in the context
of digital markets. In addition to these specific reforms, the Sub-
committee recommends that Congress consider reasserting the
original intent and broad goals of the antitrust laws by clarifying
that they are designed to protect not just consumers, but also
workers, entrepreneurs, independent businesses, open markets, a
fair economy, and democratic ideals.
2474
2. Invigorate Merger Enforcement
Section 7 of the Clayton Act, as amended, prohibits any trans-
action where ‘‘the effect of such acquisition may be substantially to
lessen competition, or to tend to create a monopoly.’’
2475
In 1950,
Congress passed the Celler-Kefauver Anti-Merger Act to broaden
the types of transactions covered by the Clayton Act, specifically to
include vertical mergers, conglomerate mergers, and purchases of
assets.
2476
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00337 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
332
2477
See infra Appendix.
2478
Stipulation and Order, United States v. Google Inc. & ITA Software Inc., No. 1:11–cv–
00688 (D.D.C. Apr. 12, 2011).
2479
Michael A. Carrier, The Rule of Reason: An Empirical Update for the 21st Century, 16
G
EO
. M
ASON
L. R
EV
. 827 (2009).
2480
J
OHN
K
WOKA
, M
ERGERS
, M
ERGER
C
ONTROL
,
AND
R
EMEDIES
155 (2014).
2481
For support for codifying the structural presumption, see Submission from John Kwoka,
Finnegan Prof. of Econ., Northeastern Univ., to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Apr. 17, 2020)
(on file with Comm.) [hereinafter Kwoka Submission]; Submission from Michael Kades, Dir.,
Mkts. & Competition Pol’y, Wash. Ctr. for Equitable Growth, et al., to H. Comm. on the Judici-
ary, 9 (Apr. 30, 2020) (on file with Comm.) [hereinafter Kades Submission]; Lande Submission
at 5; Slaiman Submission at 3; Foer Submission at 9. See also Herbert Hovenkamp & Carl Sha-
piro, Horizontal Mergers, Market Structure, and Burdens of Proof, 127 Y
ALE
L.J. 1996 (2018);
Steven C. Salop, The Evolution and Vitality of Merger Presumptions: A Decision-Theoretic Ap-
proach, 80 A
NTITRUST
L.J. 269 (2015).
As noted above, since 1998, Amazon, Apple, Facebook, and
Google collectively have purchased more than 500 companies.
2477
The antitrust agencies did not block a single acquisition. In one in-
stance—Google’s purchase of ITA—the Justice Department re-
quired Google to agree to certain terms in a consent decree before
proceeding with the transaction.
2478
The Subcommittee’s review of the relevant documents revealed
that several of these acquisitions lessened competition and in-
creased market power. In several cases, antitrust enforcers per-
mitted dominant platforms to acquire a competitive threat. For ex-
ample, documents produced during the investigation demonstrate
that Facebook acquired Instagram to neutralize an emerging rival,
while Google purchased Waze to eliminate an independent provider
of mapping data. In other instances, the platform engaged in a se-
ries of acquisitions that enabled it to gain a controlling position
across an entire supply chain or ecosystem. Google’s acquisitions of
DoubleClick, AdMeld, and AdMob, for example, let Google achieve
a commanding position across the digital ad tech market.
In light of this, the Subcommittee recommends that Congress
consider a series of reforms to strengthen merger enforcement.
(a) Codify Bright-Line Rules and Structural Presumptions in
Concentrated Markets. A major change in antitrust enforcement
over the last few decades has been the shift away from bright-line
rules in favor of ‘‘rule of reason’’ case-by-case analysis. Although
the rule of reason approach is said to reduce errors in enforcement
through fact-specific analysis, in practice the standard tilts heavily
in favor of defendants.
2479
The departure from bright-line rules and
presumptions has especially affected merger enforcement, where
enforcers seeking to challenge a merger must fully prove that it
will have anticompetitive effects, even in cases where the merging
parties are dominant firms in highly concentrated markets. Schol-
arship by Professor John Kwoka of Northeastern University shows
that the antitrust agencies acted in only 38 percent of all mergers
that led to price increases, suggesting that the current approach to
merger review is resulting in significant underenforcement.
2480
To respond to this concern, the Subcommittee recommends that
Members consider codifying bright-line rules for merger enforce-
ment, including structural presumptions.
2481
Under a structural
presumption, mergers resulting in a single firm controlling an out-
sized market share, or resulting in a significant increase in con-
centration, would be presumptively prohibited under Section 7 of
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00338 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
333
2482
Although some courts still follow the structural presumption adopted by the Supreme
Court in United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U.S. 321 (1963), it is not universally
followed, especially given the D.C. Circuit’s decision in United States v. Baker Hughes Inc., 908
F.2d 981 (D.C. Cir. 1990).
2483
Wu Submission at 4–5; see also C. Scott Hemphill & Tim Wu, Nascent Competitors, 168
U. P
A
. L. R
EV
. 1879 (2020); Kades Submission at 14.
2484
Wu Submission at 6; Kwoka Submission at 6.
2485
See, e.g., United States v. Marine Bancorporation, Inc., 418 U.S. 602 (1974).
2486
Submission from Mark Lemley, William H. Neukom Prof. of Law, Stanford Law Sch., to
H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 7–8 (Apr. 8, 2020) (on file with Comm.) [hereinafter Lemley Submis-
sion].
the Clayton Act.
2482
This structural presumption would place the
burden of proof upon the merging parties to show that the merger
would not reduce competition. A showing that the merger would re-
sult in efficiencies should not be sufficient to overcome the pre-
sumption that it is anticompetitive. It is the view of the Sub-
committee that the 30 percent threshold established by the Su-
preme Court in Philadelphia National Bank is appropriate, al-
though a lower standard for monopsony or buyer power claims may
deserve consideration by the Subcommittee.
By shifting the burden of proof to the merging parties in cases
involving concentrated markets and high market shares, codifying
the structural presumption would help promote the efficient alloca-
tion of agency resources and increase the likelihood that anti-
competitive mergers are blocked.
(b) Protect Potential Rivals, Nascent Competitors, and Startups.
The Subcommittee’s investigation produced evidence that several of
the dominant platforms acquired potential rivals and nascent com-
petitors. Potential rivals are firms that are planning to enter or
could plausibly enter the acquirer’s market. Nascent competitors
are firms whose ‘‘prospective innovation represents a serious future
threat to an incumbent.’’
2483
In digital markets, potential rivals
and nascent competitors play a critical role in driving innovation,
as their prospective entry may dislodge incumbents or spur com-
petition. For this reason, incumbents may view potential rivals and
nascent competitors as a significant threat, especially as their suc-
cess could render the incumbent’s technologies obsolete.
To strengthen the law relating to potential rivals and nascent
competitors, the Subcommittee recommends strengthening the
Clayton Act to prohibit acquisitions of potential rivals and nascent
competitors. This could be achieved by clarifying that proving harm
on potential competition or nascent competition grounds does not
require proving that the potential or nascent competitor would
have been a successful entrant in a but-for world.
2484
Given the
patchwork of cases that are unfavorable to potential and nascent
competition-based theories of harm, this amendment should also
make clear that Congress intends to override this case law.
2485
Since startups can be an important source of potential and nas-
cent competition, the antitrust laws should also look unfavorably
upon incumbents purchasing innovative startups. One way that
Congress could do so is by codifying a presumption against acquisi-
tions of startups by dominant firms, particularly those that serve
as direct competitors, as well as those operating in adjacent or re-
lated markets.
2486
Lastly, the Subcommittee’s review of relevant documents pro-
duced by the FTC and Justice Department demonstrated that the
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00339 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
334
2487
Submission from Consumer Reps., to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 5 (Apr. 17, 2020) (on
file with Comm.) [hereinafter Consumer Reports Submission]; Submission from Richard M.
Steuer, Adjunct Prof., Fordham Univ. Sch. of Law, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary (Apr. 8, 2020)
(on file with Comm.) [hereinafter Steuer Submission]; Peter C. Carstensen & Robert H. Lande,
The Merger Incipiency Doctrine and the Importance of ‘‘Redundant’’ Competitors, 2018 W
IS
. L.
R
EV
. 783 (2018).
2488
S. R
EP
. N
O
. 63–698, at 1 (1914); see also E
ARL
W. K
INTNER
, T
HE
L
EGISLATIVE
H
ISTORY
OF THE
F
EDERAL
A
NTITRUST
L
AWS AND
R
ELATED
S
TATUTES
1744–52 (1978) (noting that the Sen-
ate Judiciary Committee report stated that the purpose of the bill was to supplement the Sher-
man Act ‘‘by making these practices illegal, to arrest the creation of trusts, conspiracies, and
monopolies in their incipiency and before consummation’’).
2489
Kades Submission at 5; Jonathan Baker et al., Five Principles for Vertical Merger Enforce-
ment Policy, 33 A
NTITRUST
3 (2019).
2490
15 U.S.C. 2; accord Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890, Ch. 647, § 2, 26 Stat. 209, 209 (codi-
fied as amended at 15 U.S.C. 2).
antitrust agencies consistently underestimated—by a significant
margin—the degree to which an acquisition would undermine com-
petition and impede entry. In light of this tendency, the Sub-
committee recommends that Congress consider strengthening the
incipiency standard by amending the Clayton Act to prohibit acqui-
sitions that ‘‘may lessen competition or tend to increase market
power.’’
2487
Revising the law would ‘‘arrest the creation of trusts,
conspiracies, and monopolies in their incipiency and before con-
summation.’’
2488
(c) Strengthen Vertical Merger Doctrine. The Subcommittee’s in-
vestigation identified several ways in which vertical integration of
dominant platforms enabled anticompetitive conduct. For this rea-
son, the Subcommittee recommends that Congress examine pro-
posals to strengthen the law relating to vertical mergers. The cur-
rent case law disfavors challenges to vertical mergers. Specifically,
courts tend to defer to claims from the merging parties that the
transaction will yield efficiencies through the ‘‘elimination of double
marginalization’’ and are skeptical about claims that the merger
will result in foreclosure.
To address this concern, the Subcommittee recommends that
Congress explore presumptions involving vertical mergers, such as
a presumption that vertical mergers are anticompetitive when ei-
ther of the merging parties is a dominant firm operating in a con-
centrated market, or presumptions relating to input foreclosure
and customer foreclosure.
2489
3. Rehabilitate Monopolization Law
Section 2 of the Sherman Act makes it illegal to ‘‘monopolize, or
attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other per-
son or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce
among the several States.’’
2490
Over recent decades, courts have
significantly heightened the legal standards that plaintiffs must
overcome in order to prove monopolization. Several of the business
practices the Subcommittee’s investigation uncovered should be il-
legal under Section 2. This Section briefly identifies the relevant
business practices and the case law that impedes effective enforce-
ment of Section 2 of the Sherman Act.
(a) Abuse of Dominance. The Subcommittee’s investigation found
that the dominant platforms have the incentive and ability to
abuse their dominant position against third-party suppliers, work-
ers, and consumers. Some of these business practices are a det-
riment to fair competition, but they do not easily fit the existing
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00340 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
335
2491
First & Fox Submission at 2; Foer Submission at 2–4; Newman Submission at 7–8;
Stucke Submission at 14; Waller Submission at 13.
2492
Waller Submission at 12.
2493
Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447 (1993).
2494
Id. See also Alaska Airlines, Inc. v. United Airlines, Inc., 948 F.2d 536 (9th Cir. 1991).
categories identified by the Sherman Act, namely ‘‘monopolization’’
or ‘‘restraint of trade.’’ Since courts have shifted their interpreta-
tion of the antitrust law to focus primarily on the formation or en-
trenchment of market power, and not on its exploitation or exer-
cise, many of the business practices that the Subcommittee identi-
fied as undermining competition in digital markets could be dif-
ficult to reach under the prevailing judicial approach.
To address this concern, the Subcommittee recommends that
Congress consider extending the Sherman Act to prohibit abuses of
dominance.
2491
Furthermore, the Subcommittee should examine
the creation of a statutory presumption that a market share of 30
percent or more constitutes a rebuttable presumption of dominance
by a seller, and a market share of 25 percent or more constitute
a rebuttable presumption of dominance by a buyer.
2492
(b) Monopoly Leveraging. The Subcommittee’s investigation found
that the dominant platforms have engaged in ‘‘monopoly
leveraging,’’ where a dominant firm uses its monopoly power in one
market to boost or privilege its position in another market. For ex-
ample, Google’s use of its horizontal search monopoly to advantage
its vertical search offerings is a form of monopoly leveraging. Al-
though monopoly leveraging was previously a widely cognizable
theory of harm under antitrust law, courts now require that use of
monopoly power in the first market ‘‘actually monopolize’’ the sec-
ondary market or ‘‘dangerously threaten[] to do so.’’
2493
The Sub-
committee’s investigation identified several instances in which use
of monopoly power in one market to privilege the monopolist’s posi-
tion in the second market injured competition, even though the
conduct did not result in monopolization of the second market. For
this reason, the Subcommittee recommends overriding the legal re-
quirement that monopoly leveraging ‘‘actually monopolize’’ the sec-
ond market, as set out in Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan.
2494
(c) Predatory Pricing. The Subcommittee’s investigation identified
several instances in which a dominant platform was pricing goods
or services below-cost in order to drive out rivals and capture the
market. For example, documents produced during the investigation
revealed that Amazon had been willing to lose $200 million in a
single quarter in order to pressure Diapers.com, a firm it had rec-
ognized as its most significant rival in the category. Amazon cut
prices and introduced steep promotions, prompting a pricing war
that eventually weakened Diapers.com. Amazon then purchased
the company, eliminating its competitor and subsequently cutting
back the discounts and promotions it had introduced.
Predatory pricing is a particular risk in digital markets, where
winner-take-all dynamics incentivize the pursuit of growth over
profits, and where the dominant digital platforms can cross-sub-
sidize between lines of business. Courts, however, have introduced
a ‘‘recoupment’’ requirement, necessitating that plaintiffs prove
that the losses incurred through below-cost pricing subsequently
were or could be recouped. Although dominant digital markets can
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00341 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
336
2495
Hubbard Submission at 20; Stucke Submission at 7; Teachout Submission at 12; Chris-
topher R. Leslie, Predatory Pricing and Recoupment, 113 C
OLUM
. L. R
EV
. 1695 (2013).
2496
475 U.S. 574 (1986).
2497
509 U.S. 209 (1993).
2498
549 U.S. 312 (2007).
2499
Submission from the Am. Antitrust Inst., to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 4 (Apr. 17, 2020)
(on file with Comm.) [hereinafter AAI Submission]; Waller Submission at 13.
2500
Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 (2004); Pac.
Bell Tel. Co. v. LinkLine Commc’ns, Inc., 555 U.S. 438 (2009).
2501
466 U.S.C. 2 (1984).
recoup these losses through various means over the long term,
recoupment is difficult for plaintiffs to prove in the short term.
Since the recoupment requirement was introduced, successful pred-
atory pricing cases have plummeted.
2495
The Subcommittee recommends clarifying that proof of
recoupment is not necessary to prove predatory pricing or preda-
tory buying, overriding the Supreme Court’s decisions in
Matsushita Electric Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp.,
2496
Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp.,
2497
and
Weyerhaeuser Co. v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co.
2498
(d) Essential Facilities and Refusals to Deal. The Subcommittee’s
investigation uncovered several instances in which a dominant
platform used the threat of delisting or refusing service to a third
party as leverage to extract greater value or more data or to secure
an advantage in a distinct market. Because the dominant platforms
do not face meaningful competition in their primary markets, their
threat to refuse business with a third party is the equivalent of de-
priving a market participant of an essential input. This denial of
access in one market can undermine competition across adjacent
markets, undermining the ability of market participants to compete
on the merits.
To address this concern, the Subcommittee recommends that
Congress consider revitalizing the ‘‘essential facilities’’ doctrine, the
legal requirement that dominant firms provide access to their
infrastructural services or facilities on a nondiscriminatory
basis.
2499
To clarify the law, Congress should consider overriding
judicial decisions that have treated unfavorably essential facilities-
and refusal to deal-based theories of harm.
2500
(e) Tying. The Subcommittee’s investigation identified several in-
stances in which a dominant platform conditioned access to a good
or service that the dominant platform controlled on the purchase
or use of a separate product or service. This business practice un-
dermines competition on the merits by enabling a firm with market
power in one market to privilege products or services in a distinct
market.
Although antitrust law has long treated tying by a monopolist as
anticompetitive, in recent decades, courts have moved away from
this position. The Subcommittee recommends that Congress con-
sider clarifying that conditioning access to a product or service in
which a firm has market power to the purchase or use of a sepa-
rate product or service is anticompetitive under Section 2, as held
by the Supreme Court in Jefferson Parish Hospital District No. 2
v. Hyde.
2501
(f) Self-Preferencing and Anticompetitive Product Design. The
Subcommittee’s investigation uncovered several instances in which
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00342 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
337
2502
This would require overriding Allied Orthopedic Appliances, Inc. v. Tyco Health Care Grp.
LP, 592 F.3d 991 (9th Cir. 2010).
2503
AAI Submission at 4; Submission from Herbert Hovenkamp, James G. Dinan Univ. Prof.,
Univ. of Pa. Law Sch., to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (Apr. 17, 2020) (on file with Comm.)
[hereinafter Hovenkamp Submission]; Hubbard Submission at 20; Kades Submission at 8.
2504
United States v. Sabre Corp., 452 F. Supp. 3d 97 (D. Del. 2020). See also Kades Submis-
sion at 10.
2505
Hovenkamp Submission at 3–4; Newman Submission at 5–6.
2506
The Subcommittee believes that Congress could clarify that the views set out by then-
Professor Frank Easterbrook in The Limits of Antitrust, 63 T
EX
. L. R
EV
. 1 (1984), do not reflect
the views of the Congress in enacting the antitrust laws. See also Submission from Bill Baer,
Visiting Fellow, Brookings Inst., to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 3 (May 19, 2020) (on file with
Comm.) [hereinafter Baer Submission] (‘‘That is my fundamental concern with the state of anti-
trust enforcement today. It is too cautious, too worried about adverse effects of ‘over enforce-
ment’ (so called Type I errors).’’).
2507
See generally Marc Winerman, The Origins of the FTC: Concentration, Cooperation, Con-
trol, and Competition, 71 A
NTITRUST
L.J. 1 (2003).
2508
Clayton Antitrust Act of 1914, Pub. L. No. 63–212, ch. 323, 38 Stat. 730 (codified as
amended at 15 U.S.C. 12–27); Fed. Trade Comm’n Act of 1914, Pub. L. No. 63–203, ch. 311,
38 Stat. 717 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. 41–58).
a dominant platform used the design of its platform or service to
privilege its own services or to disfavor competitors. This practice
undermines competition by enabling a firm that controls an essen-
tial input to distort competition in separate markets. The Sub-
committee recommends that Congress consider whether making a
design change that excludes competitors or otherwise undermines
competition should be a violation of Section 2, regardless of wheth-
er the design change can be justified as an improvement for con-
sumers.
2502
4. Additional Measures to Strengthen the Antitrust Laws
In response to the Subcommittee’s requests for submissions, ex-
perts identified other proposals that the Subcommittee believes
warrant review by Congress. These include:
Overriding Ohio v. American Express by clarifying that cases involving plat-
forms do not require plaintiffs to establish harm to both sets of customers;
2503
Overriding United States v. Sabre Corp., clarifying that platforms that are
‘‘two-sided,’’ or serve multiple sets of customers, can compete with firms that
are ‘‘one-sided’’;
2504
Clarifying that market definition is not required for proving an antitrust viola-
tion, especially in the presence of direct evidence of market power;
2505
and
Clarifying that ‘‘false positives’’—or erroneous enforcement—are not more cost-
ly than ‘‘false negatives’’—or erroneous non-enforcement—and that, in relation
to conduct or mergers involving dominant firms, ‘‘false negatives’’ are cost-
lier.
2506
C. Strengthening Antitrust Enforcement
1. Congressional Oversight
As discussed earlier in the Report, Congress has a strong tradi-
tion of performing vigorous oversight of the enforcement and ade-
quacy of the antitrust laws. Over the last century, Congress at key
moments responded forcefully to the courts’ narrowing of antitrust
laws, the rising tide of economic concentration, or other challenges
to the sound and effective Administration of the antitrust laws.
2507
This tradition includes the creation of the FTC and concurrent
enactment of the Clayton Antitrust Act in 1914, as both a response
to the Supreme Court’s narrow construction of the Sherman Act in
1911 and an effort to limit the discretion of the courts.
2508
It also
includes Congress’s broadening of merger enforcement to cover
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00343 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
338
2509
Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act (Tunney Act), Pub. L. No. 93–528, § 2, 88 Stat.
1706, 1706–08 (1974) (amending 15 U.S.C. 16). See also Consent Decree Program of the Dep’t
of Justice: Hearings Before the Subcomm. on Antitrust of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 85th
Cong. (1957); S
UBCOMM
.
ON
A
NTITRUST OF THE
H. C
OMM
.
ON THE
J
UDICIARY
, 86
TH
C
ONG
., 1
ST
S
ESS
., R
EPORT ON THE
C
ONSENT
D
ECREE
P
ROGRAM OF THE
D
EPARTMENT OF
J
USTICE
(1959).
2510
In the 1990s, the Committee on the Judiciary conducted significant oversight of competi-
tion in the telecommunications market in the wake of the breakup of Ma Bell, including through
oversight of the 1982 consent decree. These efforts culminated in the passage of H.R. 3626, the
‘‘Antitrust and Communications Reform Act,’’ by the House of Representatives in 1994 by a vote
of 423 to 5. Chair Jack B. Brooks introduced this bill—a precursor to the Telecommunications
Act of 1996—to address monopolization in the telecommunications market. See generally H. R
EP
.
N
O
. 103–559 (1994); Robert M. Frieden, The Telecommunications Act of 1996: Predicting the
Winners and Losers, 20 H
ASTINGS
C
OMMC
NS &
E
NT
. L.J. 11, 57 n.8 (1997).
2511
Submission from Alison Jones & William E. Kovacic, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 4
(Apr. 17, 2020) (on file with Comm.) [hereinafter Jones & Kovacic Submission].
2512
Harry First & Spencer Weber Waller, Antitrust’s Democracy Deficit, 81 F
ORDHAM
L. R
EV
.
2543, 2556 (2013) (‘‘[D]espite a history of bipartisan congressional support for the importance
of the antitrust laws and their enforcement, of late Congress has done little. And when it has
done something, it has focused on the micro rather than the macro changes that have occurred
in the field.’’).
2513
Id. at 2559.
2514
Jones & Kovacic Submission at 4 (‘‘The miscalculation of Congress (and the agencies)
about the magnitude of implementation tasks in this earlier period came at a high price. Imple-
mentation weaknesses undermined many investigations and cases that the federal agencies
launched in response to congressional guidance. The litigation failures raised questions about
the competence of the Federal agencies, particularly their ability to manage large cases dealing
with misconduct by dominant firms and oligopolists. The wariness of the federal agencies since
the late 1970s to bring cases in this area—a wariness that many observers today criticize as
unwarranted—is in major part the residue of bitter litigation experiences from this earlier pe-
riod.’’).
2515
Id. at 6.
non-horizontal acquisitions and other transactions in the Celler-
Kefauver Anti-Merger Act of 1950 as well as establishing a mecha-
nism for judicial oversight of consent decrees in response to polit-
ical interference in merger enforcement with the Tunney Act of
1974.
2509
Additionally, Congress has regularly investigated the rise
and abuse of market power in important markets.
2510
In support
of these efforts, Congress dedicated substantial congressional and
agency resources to perform the task of identifying and responding
to anticompetitive conduct.
2511
In recent decades, Congress has departed from this tradition, de-
ferring largely to the courts and to the antitrust agencies in the
crafting of substantive antitrust policy.
2512
Its inaction has been
read as acquiescence in the narrowing of the antitrust laws and
has contributed to antitrust becoming ‘‘overly technical and pri-
marily dependent on economics.’’
2513
In other cases, congressional attention has fallen short as law-
makers tried to address competition problems without sustained ef-
forts to implement enforcement changes, leading some reform ef-
forts in recent decades to misfire.
2514
Responding to these concerns,
Congress has increased appropriations and provided modest im-
provements to the FTC’s budget and remedial authority during this
period. But these efforts were insufficient without sustained sup-
port in the face of ‘‘ferocious opposition’’ from large defendants and
businesses lobbying Congress.
2515
To remedy these broader trends, the Subcommittee recommends
that Congress revive its long tradition of robust and vigorous over-
sight of the antitrust laws and enforcement, along with its commit-
ment to ongoing market investigations and legislative activity. Ad-
ditionally, greater attention to implementation challenges will en-
able Congress to better see its reform efforts through.
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00344 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
339
2516
See S. R
EP
. N
O
. 63–597, at 13 (1914) (‘‘The committee gave careful consideration to the
question as to whether it would attempt to define the many and variable unfair practices which
prevail in commerce and to forbid [them] . . . or whether it would, by a general declaration con-
demning unfair practices, leave it to the commission to determine what practices were unfair.
It concluded that the latter course would be better, for the reason . . . that there were too many
unfair practices to define, and after writing 20 of them into the law it would be quite possible
to invent others.’’).
2517
Neil W. Averitt, The Meaning of ‘‘Unfair Methods of Competition’’ in Section 5 of the Fed-
eral Trade Commission Act, 21 B.C. L. R
EV
. 227 (1980); see also Marc Winerman, The Origins
of the FTC: Concentration, Cooperation, Control, and Competition, 71 A
NTITRUST
L.J. 1 (2003).
2518
15 U.S.C. 46.
2519
Neil W. Averitt, The Meaning of ‘‘Unfair Methods of Competition’’ in Section 5 of the Fed-
eral Trade Commission Act, 21 B.C. L. R
EV
. 227, 251 (1980) (‘‘Section 5 is not confined to con-
duct that actually violates, or that threatens to violate, one of the other antitrust statutes. If
it were limited to this extent it would be a largely duplicative provision. The legislative purpose
instead assigned to Section 5 a broader role. It was to be an interstitial statute: it was to fill
in the gaps in the other antitrust laws, to round them out and make their coverage complete.
In addition to overt violations, therefore, Section 5 would reach closely similar conduct that vio-
lates the policy or ‘spirit’ of the antitrust laws, even though it may not come technically within
its terms.’’).
2520
Discriminatory Practices in Men’s and Boys’ Tailored Clothing Industry, 16 C.F.R. pt. 412
(1968).
2. Agency Enforcement
Over the course of the investigation, the Subcommittee uncov-
ered evidence that the antitrust agencies consistently failed to
block monopolists from establishing or maintaining their domi-
nance through anticompetitive conduct or acquisitions. This institu-
tional failure follows a multi-decade trend whereby the antitrust
agencies have constrained their own authorities and advanced nar-
row readings of the law. In the case of the FTC, the agency has
been reluctant to use the expansive set of tools with which Con-
gress provided it, neglecting to fulfill its broad legislative mandate.
Restoring the agencies to full strength will require overcoming
these trends.
As a general matter, Congress created the FTC to police and pro-
hibit ‘‘unfair methods of competition,’’
2516
and to serve as an ‘‘ad-
ministrative tribunal’’ that carefully studied ongoing business prac-
tices and economic conditions.
2517
To enable the agency to carry out
these functions, Congress assigned the Commission powers to
‘‘make rules and regulations for the purpose of carrying out the
[FTC Act’s] provisions,’’ as well as broad investigative authority to
compel business information and conduct market studies.
2518
Nota-
bly, Congress established the provision prohibiting ‘‘unfair methods
of competition’’ to reach beyond the other antitrust statutes, ‘‘to fill
in the gaps in the other antitrust laws, to round them out and
make their coverage complete.’’
2519
Lawmakers delegated to the
FTC the task of defining what constituted an ‘‘unfair method of
competition,’’ recognizing that an expert agency equipped to con-
tinuously monitor business practices would be best positioned to
ensure the legal definition kept pace with business realities.
In practice, however, the Commission has neglected to play this
role. In its first hundred years, the FTC promulgated only one rule
defining an ‘‘unfair method of competition.’’
2520
In 2015, the Com-
mission adopted a set of ‘‘Enforcement Principles,’’ stating that the
FTC’s targeting of ‘‘unfair methods of competition’’ would be guided
by the ‘‘promotion of consumer welfare,’’ a policy goal absent from
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00345 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
340
2521
Fed. Trade Comm’n, Statement of Enforcement Principles Regarding ‘‘Unfair Methods of
Competition’’ Under Section 5 of the FTC Act (Aug. 13, 2015), https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/
documents/publiclstatements/735201/150813section5enforcement.pdf.
2522
The one exception is the FTC’s recent suit against Qualcomm. Fed. Trade Comm’n v.
Qualcomm Inc., 411 F. Supp. 3d 658 (N.D. Cal. 2019) (No. 5:17–cv–00220).
2523
F
ED
. T
RADE
C
OMM
N
, B
UR
.
OF
E
CON
., A
NNUAL
L
INE OF
B
USINESS
R
EPORT
1977 (1985),
https://www.ftc.gov/reports/us-federal-trade-commission-bureau-economics-annual-line-business
-report-1977-statistical.
2524
In a memo submitted on behalf of the United States to the OECD, the Justice Depart-
ment stated that ‘‘a shift in emphasis based on economic analysis resulted in a significant reduc-
tion in enforcement actions brought by the Agencies under the Robinson-Patman Act. As a re-
sult, current enforcement of the Act occurs mainly through private treble damages actions.’’
Note by the United States, Roundtable on ‘‘Price Discrimination,’’ OECD Doc. No. DAF/COMP/
WD(2016)69, at 6 (Nov. 2016), https://www.justice.gov/atr/case-document/file/979211/
download.
2525
Thomas O. Barnett & Hill B. Wellford, The DOJ’s Single-Firm Conduct Report: Pro-
moting Consumer Welfare Through Clearer Standards for Section 2 of the Sherman Act, U.S.
D
EP
TOF
J
USTICE
(Sept. 8, 2008), https://www.justice.gov/sites/default/files/atr/legacy/2009/
05/11/238599.pdf.
2526
Sandeep Vaheesan, Accommodating Capital and Policing Labor: Antitrust in the Two
Gilded Ages, 78 M
D
. L. R
EV
. 766 (2019). See also Brief for the United States & the Federal
Trade Commission as Amicus Curiae in Support of Appellant & in Favor of Reversal, Chamber
of Commerce of the United States v. City of Seattle, 890 F.3d 769 (9th Cir. 2018) (No. 17–35640).
2527
M
ICHAEL
K
ADES
, W
ASH
. C
TR
.
FOR
E
QUITABLE
G
ROWTH
, T
HE
S
TATE OF
U.S. F
EDERAL
A
NTITRUST
E
NFORCEMENT
(2019), https://equitablegrowth.org/wp-content/uploads/2019/09/
091719-antitrust-enforcement-CRPT117hrpt.pdf.
2528
Mitchell Submission at 9–10.
any legislative directive given to the Commission.
2521
Since the
adoption of this framework, the FTC has brought only one case
under its standalone Section 5 authority.
2522
The agency has also
failed to regularly produce market-wide studies, having halted reg-
ular data collection in the 1980s.
2523
Together with the DOJ, the FTC has also chosen to stop enforc-
ing certain antitrust laws entirely. For two decades, neither agency
has filed a suit under the Robinson-Patman Act, which Congress
passed in order to limit the power of large chain retailers to extract
concessions from independent suppliers.
2524
In 2008, the Justice
Department issued a report recommending that Section 2 of the
Sherman Act be curbed dramatically.
2525
Although the report was
subsequently rescinded, the Justice Department has not filed a sig-
nificant monopolization case in two decades. Meanwhile, both agen-
cies have targeted their enforcement efforts on relatively small
players—including ice skating teachers and organists—raising
questions about their enforcement priorities.
2526
The agencies have also been hamstrung by inadequate budgets.
In 1981, FTC Chair Jim Miller won steep budget cuts at the Com-
mission, a drastic rollback from which the agency has not yet re-
covered. Prior to this Congress, appropriations for both agencies
have reached historic lows.
2527
To restore the antitrust agencies to
full strength, the Subcommittee recommends that Congress con-
sider the following:
Triggering civil penalties and other relief for violations of ‘‘unfair methods of
competition’’ rules, creating symmetry with violations of ‘‘unfair or deceptive
acts or practices’’ rules;
Requiring the Commission to regularly collect data and report on economic
concentration and competition in sectors across the economy, as permitted
under Section 6 of the FTC Act;
Enhancing the public transparency and accountability of the antitrust agen-
cies, by requiring the agencies to solicit and respond to public comments for
merger reviews, and by requiring the agencies to publish written explanations
for all enforcement decisions;
2528
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00346 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
341
2529
See Submission from Source 17, to H. Comm. on the Judiciary, 13–14 (Sept. 22, 2020).
2530
See Baer Submission at 7–8; Kades Submission at 12–13.
2531
See, e.g., 51 Cong. Rec. 9073 (1914) (remarks of Rep. Edwin Y. Webb) (stating that pri-
vate Section 7 remedies ‘‘open the door of justice to every man, whenever he may be injured
by those who violate the antitrust laws, and give the injured party ample damages for the wrong
suffered’’).
2532
Joshua P. Davis & Robert H. Lande, Toward an Empirical and Theoretical Assessment
of Private Antitrust Enforcement, 36 S
EATTLE
U. L. R
EV
. 1269, 1276 (2013).
2533
Justice Denied: Forced Arbitration and the Erosion of our Legal System: Hearing Before
the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Commercial and Admin. Law of the H. Comm. on the Judiciary,
116th Cong. 51 (2019) (statement of Myriam Gilles, Paul R. Verkuil Rsch. Chair in Pub. Law
& Prof. of Law, Benjamin N. Cardozo Sch. of Law).
2534
Id. at 12 (statement of Deepak Gupta, Founding Principal, Gupta Wessler PLLC).
2535
Innovation and Entrepreneurship Hearing at 545 (response to Questions for the Record
of Nate Sutton, Assoc. Gen. Couns., Competition, Amazon.com, Inc.).
2536
Judith Resnik, Diffusing Disputes: The Public in the Private of Arbitration, the Private
in Courts, and the Erasure of Rights, 124 Y
ALE
L.J. 2804 (2015).
Requiring the agencies to conduct and make publicly available merger
retrospectives on significant transactions consummated over the last three dec-
ades;
Codifying stricter prohibitions on the revolving door between the agencies and
the companies that they investigate, especially with regards to senior offi-
cials;
2529
and
Increasing the budgets of the Federal Trade Commission and the Antitrust Di-
vision.
2530
3. Private Enforcement
Private enforcement plays a critical role in the nation’s antitrust
system. The Sherman Act and Clayton Act both include a private
right of action. This reflected lawmakers’ desire to ensure that
those abused by monopoly power have an opportunity for direct re-
course.
2531
It also reflected a recognition that public enforcers
would be susceptible to capture by the very monopolists that they
were supposed to investigate, necessitating other means of enforce-
ment.
Empirical surveys of trends in antitrust enforcement indicate
that private enforcement deters anticompetitive conduct and
strengthens enforcement overall.
2532
In recent decades, however,
courts have erected significant obstacles for private antitrust plain-
tiffs, both through procedural decisions and substantive doctrine.
One major obstacle is the rise of forced arbitration clauses, which
undermine private enforcement of the antitrust laws by allowing
companies to avoid legal accountability for their actions.
2533
These
clauses allow firms to evade the public justice system—where
plaintiffs have far greater legal protections—and hide behind a
one-sided process that is tilted in their favor.
2534
For example, al-
though Amazon has over two million sellers in the United States,
Amazon’s records reflect that only 163 sellers initiated arbitration
proceedings between 2014 and 2019.
2535
This data seems to con-
firm studies showing that forced arbitration clauses often fail to
provide a meaningful forum for resolving disputes and instead tend
to suppress valid claims and shield wrongdoing.
2536
Several other trends in judicial decisions have hampered private
antitrust plaintiffs, including in cases involving dominant plat-
forms. To address these concerns, the Subcommittee recommends
that Congress consider:
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00347 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
342
2537
Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477 (1977).
2538
Assoc. Gen. Contractors of Cal., Inc. v. Cal. State Council of Carpenters, 459 U.S. 519
(1983).
2539
15 U.S.C. 15; accord Clayton Antitrust Act of 1914, Pub. L. No. 63–212, § 4, ch. 323, 38
Stat. 730, 731 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. 15).
2540
American Express Co. v. Italian Colors Rest., 570 U.S. 228 (2013); AT&T Mobility LLC
v. Concepcion, 563 U.S. 333 (2011).
2541
Comcast Corp. v. Behrend, 569 U.S. 27 (2013).
2542
550 U.S. 544 (2007).
Eliminating court-created standards for ‘‘antitrust injury’’
2537
and ‘‘antitrust
standing,’’
2538
which undermine Congress’s grant of enforcement authority to
‘‘any person . . . injured . . . by reason of anything forbidden in the antitrust
laws’’;
2539
Reducing procedural obstacles to litigation, including through eliminating
forced arbitration clauses
2540
and undue limits on class action formation;
2541
and
Lowering the heightened pleading requirement introduced in Bell Atlantic
Corp. v. Twombly.
2542
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00348 Fmt 6633 Sfmt 6633 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
VII. APPENDIX: MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS
BY DOMINANT PLATFORMS
2543
2543
Prepared by the Subcommittee based on The Acquisition Takeover by the 5 Tech
Giants, U
NIV
.
OF
C
AL
., B
ERKELEY
, S
CH
.
OF
I
NFO
., http://people.ischool.berkeley.edu/
neha01mittal/infoviz/dashboard/ (last visited Sept. 28, 2020). See also Big Tech
Mergers, A
M
. E
CON
. L
IBERTIES
P
ROJECT
, https://www.economicliberties.us/big-tech-
merger-tracker/ (last visited Oct. 4, 2020); Search Results: ‘‘acquisitions’’,
C
RUNCHBASE
, https://www.crunchbase.com/ (last visited Oct. 4, 2020).
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00349 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6621 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
344
A. Amazon
Amazon
Company Year Acquired Categories
Acquisition Value
(USD)
Zoox 2020 Autonomous Vehicles, Robotics, Transportation 1,200,000,000
Health Navigator 2019 Health Care
Internet Gaming
Database (IGDB)
2019 Video Games, Content, Media and Entertainment
INLT 2019 Enterprise Applications, Freight Service, Logistics, SaaS,
Shipping, Transportation
E8 Storage 2019 Cloud Computing, Enterprise Software, Flash Storage,
Software
50,000,000
Bebo 2019 Internet, Video Games 25,000,000
Sizmek Ad Server 2019 Advertising, Marketing
CANVAS Technology 2019 Robotics
Eero 2019 Internet, IoT, Wireless 97,000,000
CloudEndure 2019 Cloud Computing, Cloud Storage, Enterprise Software,
SaaS
200,000,000
TSO Logic 2019 Analytics, Cloud Computing, Cloud Management, Data
Center, Software
Tapzo 2018 E-Commerce, Mobile, Software 40,000,000
PillPack 2018 Pharmacy, E-Commerce 753,000,000
Ring 2018 Consumer Electronics, Security, Smart Home
Immedia 2018 Semiconductors
Sqrrl 2018 Cybersecurity 40,000,000
Dispatch 2017 Robotics
Blink 2017 Consumer Electronics, Electronics, Hardware, Security 90,000,000
Goo Technologies 2017 3D Technology, Internet, Software, Web Development
Body Labs 2017 3D Technology, Artificial Intelligence, Computer Vision,
Developer APIs, Machine Learning
50,000,000
Wing 2017 Information Technology, Logistics, Mobile, SaaS
GameSparks 2017 E-Commerce, Mobile, Software 10,000,000
Graphiq 2017 Artificial Intelligence, Big Data, Data Visualization, Mar-
ket Research, Search Engine, Semantic Web
50,000,000
Souq.com 2017 Consumer Electronics, E-Commerce, Shopping 580,000,000
Whole Foods 2017 Food and Beverage, Grocery, Organic Food 13,700,000,000
Do.com 2017 Internet, Meeting Software, Software
Thinkbox Systems 2017 Software
Colis Prive
´
2017 Shipping & Delivery, Logistics
Harvest.ai 2017 Artificial Intelligence, Cloud Security, Cyber Security, Pre-
dictive Analytics
19,000,000
Biba Systems 2016 Apps, Messaging, Mobile
Partpic 2016 Photo Recognition
Westland 2016 Publishing
Curse Inc. 2016 Digital Media, Gaming, Video Games
Cloud9 IDE 2016 Cloud Computing, Enterprise Software, Mobile, Open
Source, Software
Orbeus 2016 Artificial Intelligence, Photo Recognition
NICE 2016 Cloud Infrastructure, Enterprise Software, Power Grid
Emvantage Pay-
ments
2016 Mobile Payments, Payments
Elemental Tech-
nologies
2015 Content Delivery Network, Enterprise Software, Video,
Video Streaming
500,000,000
Safaba Translation
Systems
2015 Software
AppThwack 2015 Android, Cyber Security, iOS, Mobile, SaaS, Test and
Measurement
Shoefitr 2015 E-Commerce, Fashion, Personalization, Software
ClusterK 2015 Software
Amiato 2015 Analytics, Real Time, Service Industry
2lemetry 2015 Cloud Computing, IoT, Software
Annapurna Labs 2015 Cloud Computing, Cloud Storage, Data Storage 350,000,000
GoodGame 2014 Video Games, Social Media
Rooftop Media 2014 Content, Digital Entertainment, Audio
ComiXology 2014 Cloud Data Services, Comics, Digital Entertainment, Dig-
ital Media, Reading Apps
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00350 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6602 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
345
Amazon
Company Year Acquired Categories
Acquisition Value
(USD)
Twitch 2014 Social Media, Video, Video Games, Video Streaming 970,000,000
Double Helix Games 2014 Developer Platform, PC Games, Video Games
TenMarks Education 2013 E-Learning, EdTech, Education
Liquavista 2013 Electronics, Hardware, Manufacturing, Software
Goodreads 2013 E-Learning, Social Media
INOVA Software 2013 Software
UpNext 2012 3D Mapping
Evi 2012 Mobile, Search Engine 26,000,000
Avalon Books 2012 Books, Education
Kiva Systems 2012 Hardware, Mobile, Robotics, Software 775,000,000
Teachstreet 2012 Charter Schools, Education
Yap 2011 Artificial Intelligence, Audio, Messaging, Mobile, Speech
Recognition, Telecommunications
Pushbutton 2011 Content, Digital Entertainment, TV
The Book Depository 2011 E-Commerce, Retail
Toby Press 2010 Books
Quidsi 2010 Beauty, Child Care, E-Commerce 545,000,000
BuyVIP 2010 E-Commerce, Marketing, Shopping 96,500,000
Amie Street 2010 Media and Entertainment, Music, Music Streaming
Woot.com 2010 Electronics, Fashion, Wine and Spirits 110,000,000
Touchco 2010 Hardware, Software
Zappos 2009 E-Commerce, Retail, Shoes 1,200,000,000
SnapTell 2009 Advertising, Marketing, Mobile
Lexcycle 2009 iOS, Mobile, Software
AbeBooks 2008 E-Commerce, Marketplace, Shopping
Reflexive Entertain-
ment
2008 Gaming, Mobile, Video Games
Shelfari 2008 Social Media
Box Office Mojo 2008 Analytics, Film, Media and Entertainment
Fabric.com 2008 E-Commerce, Fashion, Retail
LoveFilm 2008 Digital Entertainment, Gaming, Internet 312,000,000
Without A Box 2008 Video
Audible 2008 Audio, Audiobooks, Digital Entertainment, E-Commerce,
Media and Entertainment
300,000,000
Brilliance Audio 2007 E-Commerce
Digital Photography
Review
2007 E-Commerce, News, Publishing
Text Pay Me 2006 Messaging, Payments
Shopbop.com 2006 E-Commerce, Lifestyle, Shopping
CustomFlix 2005 Digital Media, DVDs
Small Parts Inc. 2005 3D Printing, E-Commerce, Manufacturing, Retail
MobiPocket 2005 Shopping
Createspace 2005 Digital Media, Printing, Publishing
Joyo.com 2004 E-Commerce, Internet, Music, Video 75,000,000
Egghead.com 2002 E-Commerce, Retail 6,100,000
OurHouse 2001 E-Commerce, Retail
Leep Technology 1999 CRM, Information Technology, Software
Back to Basics 1999 Internet, Toys, Video Games
Tool Crib 1999 Tools, E-Commerce
Convergence Corp. 1999 Enterprise Software, Internet, Wireless 23,000,000
Accept.com 1999 E-Commerce Platforms, Photography, Retail 101,000,000
Alexa 1999 Digital Marketing, SEO, Web Development 250,000,000
LiveBid 1999 Auctions
Exchange.com 1999 Books, Music
MindCorps 1999 Web Development, Consulting
Bookpages 1998 E-Commerce, Internet
Internet Movie Data-
base (IMDb)
1998 Content, Media and Entertainment, TV 55,000,000
Junglee 1998 E-Commerce, Retail, Shopping 250,000,000
PlanetAll 1998 Internet, Social Media, Web Development
Telebook 1998 E-Commerce, Internet
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00351 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6602 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
346
B. Apple
Apple
Company Year Acquired Categories
Acquisition Value
(USD)
Spaces 2020 AR/VR
Mobeewave 2020 Software 100,000,000
Fleetsmith 2020 Software, Security
NextVR 2020 AR/VR 100,000,000
Inductiv 2020 AI, Machine Learning, Software
Voysis 2020 AI, Machine Learning, Software
Dark Sky 2020 Software, Apps
Xnor.ai 2020 AI, Machine Learning, Software 200,000,000
Spectral Edge 2019 Photography, Software, Artificial Intelligence
iKinema 2019 Graphics, 3D Animation, Digital Media
Intel Smartphone
Modem Business
2019 Hardware 1,000,000,000
Drive.ai 2019 Autonomous Vehicles
Tueo Health 2019 Health Care, Information Technology
Laserlike 2019 Machine Learning
Stamplay 2019 Cloud Computing, Data Integration, Developer Tools,
SaaS, Sales Automation
5,600,000
DataTiger 2019 Marketing
PullString 2019 Voice Recognition
Platoon 2018 Talent Search/Acquisition
Silk Labs 2018 AI, Machine Learning, Software
Dialog 2018 Semiconductors 300,000,000
Shazam 2018 Android, iOS, Music, Audio Recognition 400,000,000
Akonia 2018 Glasses, AR
Texture 2018 Content, Digital Entertainment, Digital Media
Buddybuild 2018 Developer Tools, Mobile, Software
Pop Up Archive 2017 Audio, Podcasts, Software
Spektral 2017 Photography, Software, AR 30,000,000
InVisage 2017 Photography, Software
Vrvana 2017 Computer, Hardware, Information Technology, Virtual Re-
ality
30,000,000
Init.ai 2017 Artificial Intelligence, B2B, Developer Platform, Developer
Tools, Machine Learning, Messaging, Natural Lan-
guage Processing, Virtual Assistant
PowerbyProxi 2017 Consumer Electronics, Industrial, Wireless
Regaind 2017 Artificial Intelligence, Computer Vision, Photo Sharing,
Photography
SensoMotoric Instru-
ments
2017 Computer Vision, Image Recognition, Psychology, Soft-
ware
Beddit 2017 Fitness, Health Care, Wellness
Lattice Data 2017 Big Data, Information Technology, Machine Learning 200,000,000
Workflow 2017 Mobile, Productivity Tools, Software
RealFace 2017 Facial Recognition
Indoor.io 2016 Mapping Services, Navigation, Service Industry, Internet
Tuplejump 2016 Analytics, Artificial Intelligence, Big Data, Data Visualiza-
tion, Machine Learning, Software
Turi 2016 Analytics, Artificial Intelligence, Big Data, Machine
Learning, Software
200,000,000
Gliimpse 2016 Health Care, Information Technology
Emotient 2016 Artificial Intelligence, Machine Learning, Software, Video
LearnSprout 2016 Analytics, Big Data, EdTech, Education, Predictive Ana-
lytics
Flyby Media 2016 Augmented Reality, Computer Vision, Internet, Location
Based Services, Mobile, Social Media, Video
Faceshift 2015 Broadcasting, Content Creators, Digital Media, Facial
Recognition, Information Technology, Video Confer-
encing
LegbaCore 2015 Consulting, Information Technology, Security
VocalIQ 2015 Artificial Intelligence, Audio, Automotive, Machine Learn-
ing, Mobile, Wearables
Perceptio 2015 Artificial Intelligence, Digital Media, Machine Learning
Mapsense 2015 Geospatial, Location Based Services, Web Hosting 25,000,000
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00352 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6602 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
347
Apple
Company Year Acquired Categories
Acquisition Value
(USD)
Coherent Navigation 2015 Apps, Software
Metaio 2015 Advertising, Augmented Reality, Mobile, Software
LinX 2015 Mobile, Social Media 20,000,000
Dryft 2015 Hardware, Software
FoundationDB 2015 Analytics, Database, Enterprise Software
Camel Audio 2015 Audio, Music
Semetric 2015 Analytics, Content Discovery, Predictive Analytics 50,000,000
Prss 2014 iOS, Publishing
Beats Electronics 2014 Consumer Electronics, Hardware, Manufacturing, Media
and Entertainment, Music, Software
3,000,000,000
BookLamp 2014 Content Discovery, Reading Apps, Software
Spotsetter 2014 Big Data, Social Media
Swell 2014 Content Discovery, Machine Learning, Mobile, Personal-
ization
30,000,000
LuxVue Technologies 2014 Consumer Electronics, Hardware, Software
Burstly 2014 Advertising, Analytics, iOS, Mobile Advertising
SnappyLabs 2014 Photography
Acunu 2013 Analytics, Big Data, Software
Topsy 2013 Analytics, Internet, Real Time, Search Engine, Social
Media
200,000,000
BroadMap 2013 Geospatial, Software
PrimeSense 2013 3D Technology, Consumer Electronics, Hardware 345,000,000
Cue 2013 Internet, Mobile Apps 35,000,000
Passif Semicon-
ductor
2013 Manufacturing, Semiconductor, Wireless
Matcha 2013 Content, Online Portals, Video
Embark 2013 Mobile, Mobile Apps, Public Transportation
AlgoTrim 2013 Mobile
Catch.com 2013 Android, iOS, Mobile
Locationary 2013 Analytics, Crowdsourcing, Location Based Services
HopStop.com 2013 Android, iOS, Navigation
OttoCat 2013 Apps, Internet, Mobile
WiFiSlam 2013 Location Based Services, Mobile, Wireless 20,000,000
Novauris Tech-
nologies
2013 Information Services, Mobile, VoIP
Anobit 2012 Electronics, Flash Storage, Semiconductor 390,000,000
Chomp 2012 Mobile 50,000,000
AuthenTec 2012 Biometrics, Cyber Security, Identity Management, NFC,
Security, Semiconductor, Sensors
356,000,000
Particle 2012 Developer Platform, Mobile, Web Development
Redmatica 2012 Music, Music Streaming
C3 Technologies 2011 Assistive Technology, Enterprise Software, Information
Technology
240,000,000
Quattro Wireless 2010 Ad Network, Advertising, Advertising Platforms, Mobile,
Publishing
275,000,000
Intrinsity 2010 Manufacturing, Mobile, Semiconductor 121,000,000
Siri 2010 Consumer Electronics, iOS, Software, Virtualization
Gipsy Moth Studios 2010 App Localization
Poly9 2010 Geospatial, Software
Polar Rose 2010 Internet, Browser Extensions, Image Recognition, Photog-
raphy
22,000,000
IMSense 2010 Image Recognition, Photography, Software
Placebase 2009 Database, Developer APIs, Developer Tools
Lala 2009 Internet, Music, Music Streaming 17,000,000
P.A. Semi 2008 Electronics, Manufacturing, Semiconductor 278,000,000
Silicon Color 2006 Film, Software, Video
Proximity 2006 Media Asset Management
SchemaSoft 2005 Software
FingerWorks 2005 Hardware, Human Computer Interaction, Software
Nothing Real 2002 Software
Zayante 2002 Software 13,000,000
Emagic 2002 Software 30,000,000
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00353 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6602 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
348
Apple
Company Year Acquired Categories
Acquisition Value
(USD)
Prismo Graphics 2002 Robotics, Software, Video 20,000,000
Silicon Grail Corp-
Chalice
2002 Software 20,000,000
Propel Software 2002 Computer, Internet, Software
PowerSchool 2001 EdTech, Education, SaaS, Software 62,000,000
Spruce Technologies 2001 Information Technology 15,000,000
Bluebuzz 2001 Internet Service Provider
Bluefish Labs 2001 Database, Mobile Apps, Web Apps
Astarte 2000 DVD Authoring
NetSelector 2000 Information Technology, Internet, Software
SoundJam MP 2000 MP3 Player, Audio Player, Software
Raycer Graphics 1999 3D Technology, Graphic Design, Information Technology 15,000,000
Xemplar Education 1999 Education 5,000,000
NeXT 1997 Education, Hardware, Software 404,000,000
Power Computing
Corp.
1997 Manufacturing, Software 100,000,000
Coral Software 1989 Artificial Intelligence, Information Technology, Software
Nashoba Systems 1988 Software
Network Innovations 1988 Information Technology, Software, Virtualization
Orion Network Sys-
tems
1988 Communications Infrastructure, Satellite Communication
Styleware 1988 Internet, IoT, Software, Web Hosting
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00354 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6602 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
349
C. Facebook
Facebook
Company Year Acquired Categories
Acquisition Value
(USD)
Giphy 2020 Software 400,000,000
Ready at Dawn 2020 VR, Video Games
Mapillary 2020 Software, Mapping
Sanzaru Games 2020 VR, Video Games
Scape Technologies 2020 AR/VR, Computer Vision, Software 40,000,000
PlayGiga 2019 Digital Media, Video Games
Beat Games 2019 VR, Video Games
Packagd 2019 E-Commerce, Shopping
GrokStyle 2019 Artificial Intelligence
CTRL-labs 2019 Augmented Reality
Servicefriend 2019 AI, Messaging
Chainspace 2019 Apps, Blockchain, Information Technology
Vidpresso 2018 Broadcasting, Software
Redkix 2018 Productivity, Enterprise Collaboration
Bloomsbury AI 2018 AI, Machine Learning 30,000,000
Confirm.io 2018 Identity Management
Tbh 2017 iOS, Mobile Apps, Social, Social Media
Fayteq 2017 Software
Source3 2017 Content Rights Management
Ozlo 2017 Artificial Intelligence, Computer, Information Services,
Mobile
Zurich Eye 2017 AR/VR, Computer Vision, Robotics
CrowdTangle 2016 Brand Marketing, Non-Profit, Social Media
FacioMetrics 2016 Machine Learning, Mobile Apps, Social Media, Software
InfiniLED 2016 Lighting, Hardware
Nascent Objects 2016 Manufacturing, Product Design, Software
Two Big Ears 2016 Audio, Consumer Electronics, Software, Virtual Reality
Masquerade 2016 Consumer Applications, Mobile, Photo Editing
Endaga 2015 Communications Infrastructure, Impact Investing, Infra-
structure, Mobile, Telecommunications
Pebbles Interfaces 2015 Digital Media, Hardware, Mobile 60,000,000
Surreal Vision 2015 Software
TheFind 2015 Coupons, E-Commerce, Lifestyle, Local, Mobile, Search
Engine, Shopping
QuickFire Networks 2015 Cloud Data Services, Video
Wit.ai 2015 Artificial Intelligence, Computer, Developer APIs, Machine
Learning, Software
WaveGroup Sound 2014 Music, Product Design
PRYTE 2014 Mobile Devices, Emerging Markets
PrivateCore 2014 Cyber Security, Security
LiveRail 2014 Advertising, Enterprise Software, Video 500,000,000
ProtoGeo Oy 2014 Mobile
Ascenta 2014 Aerospace, Manufacturing 20,000,000
WhatsApp 2014 Android, Messaging, Mobile, Subscription Service 19,000,000,000
Oculus VR 2014 Augmented Reality, Consumer Electronics, Hardware,
Video Games, Virtual Reality, Virtualization
2,000,000,000
Branch 2014 Internet, Messaging, Social 15,000,000
Little Eye Labs 2014 Android, Mobile, Test and Measurement 15,000,000
SportStream 2013 Consumer Electronics, Mobile, Sports
Onavo 2013 Finance, Mobile, Social Network
Jibbigo 2013 Apps, Audio, Big Data, Language Learning, Mobile
Monoidics 2013 Analytics, Enterprise Software, Information Technology
Parse 2013 Android, Cloud Computing, Enterprise Software, iOS, Mo-
bile, PaaS
85,000,000
Hot Studio 2013 Internet, Social Media, Web Design
Spaceport 2013 Gaming, Mobile, Mobile Devices, Online Games, Web De-
velopment
Atlas Solutions 2013 Advertising, Advertising Platforms, Internet 100,000,000
Osmeta 2013 Hardware, Software
Storylane 2013 Social Media
Threadsy 2012 Messaging, Social Media, Social Network
Spool 2012 Enterprise Software, Mobile, Social Bookmarking, Video
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00355 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6602 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
350
Facebook
Company Year Acquired Categories
Acquisition Value
(USD)
Acrylic Software 2012 Software
Karma 2012 Gifts, Mobile, Social
Face.com 2012 Artificial Intelligence, Cloud Storage, Facial Recognition,
Machine Learning, Photography, Social Network
100,000,000
TagTile 2012 Direct Marketing, Loyalty Programs, Mobile, Social Media
Glancee 2012 Android, Dating, iOS, Location Based Services, Mobile,
Public Relations, Search Engine
Lightbox.com 2012 Android, Mobile, Photo Sharing
Instagram 2012 Mobile, Photo Sharing, Photography, Social Media 1,000,000,000
Caffeinated Mind 2012 File Transfer, Big Data
Gowalla 2011 Location Based Services, Photography, Private Social Net-
working, Travel, Internet
Strobe 2011 iOS, Mobile, Software, Web Development
Friend.ly 2011 Blogging Platforms, Social Media
Push Pop Press 2011 Advertising, Digital Media, Marketing
MailRank 2011 Email, CRM, Information Technology, Software
DayTum 2011 Analytics, Big Data, Database
Sofa 2011 Developer Tools, Software
RecRec 2011 Computer Vision
Beluga 2011 Messaging, Mobile, Social Media
Rel8tion 2011 Advertising, Advertising Platforms
Snaptu 2011 Mobile 70,000,000
ShareGrove 2010 Real Time, Social Network, Web Hosting
Drop.io 2010 EdTech, Education, Email, File Sharing, Finance, FinTech,
Flash Storage, Mobile
10,000,000
Hot Potato 2010 Social, Social Media, Social Media Marketing 10,000,000
Nextstop 2010 Digital Entertainment, Social, Travel 2,500,000
Chai Labs 2010 Software 10,000,000
Zenbe 2010 Android, Email, Location Based Services, Messaging, Mo-
bile, Software, Web Apps
Divvyshot 2010 Photo Sharing, Social Network, Web Hosting
Octazen 2010 Enterprise Software, Social Network, Web Browsers
FriendFeed 2009 Social Media 47,500,000
ConnectU 2009 Social Media
Parakey 2007 Social Media, Web Browsers, WebOS
AboutFace 2007 Internet
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00356 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6602 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
351
D. Google
Google
Company Year Acquired Categories
Acquisition Value
(USD)
Stratozone 2020 Cloud, Platform Migration
North 2020 Hardware, Glasses 180,000,000
Looker 2020 Big Data, Analytics 2,600,000,000
Cornerstone Tech-
nology
2020 Cloud, Platform Migration
AppSheet 2020 Enterprise Software
Pointy 2020 Software, Inventory 163,000,000
Fitbit 2019 User Data, Mobile Devices, Fitness Tracking, Health Care 2,100,000,000
Typhoon Studios 2019 Video Games, Video Streaming
CloudSimple 2019 Cloud
Elastifile 2019 Cloud, Storage
Nightcorn 2019 Internet, Social Media, Video Streaming
Alooma 2019 Data Integration, Cloud, Platform Migration
Superpod 2019 Software 60,000,000
DevOps Research
and Assessment
2018 Cloud
Sigmoid Labs 2018 Software
Workbench 2018 Software, Education
Onward 2018 AI, Customer Service, Sales
GraphicsFuzz 2018 Graphics Drivers, Security
Velostrata 2018 Cloud Migration, Data Centers
Cask Data 2018 Big Data, Analytics
Lytro 2018 Photography, Film, Hardware, VR
Tenor 2018 Messaging, Social Media, Video
Socratic 2018 AI, Software
Xively 2018 Enterprise Software, IoT, SaaS
Redux 2018 Speakers, Mobile Devices
HTC Smartphone Di-
vision
2018 Consumer Electronics, Manufacturing, Mobile 1,100,000,000
Banter 2017 Mobile Software, Messaging
Relay Media 2017 Analytics
60db 2017 Audio, Media and Entertainment, Social Media, Video
Streaming
Bitium 2017 Cloud Computing, Cyber Security, Identity Management,
SaaS, Security, Software
AIMatter 2017 Artificial Intelligence, Computer Vision, Software
Senosis Health 2017 Health, Mobile Device, Software
Halli Labs 2017 Artificial Intelligence, Machine Learning, Software Engi-
neering
Owlchemy Labs 2017 Gaming, Software Engineering, Virtual Reality
Kaggle 2017 Analytics, Big Data, Data Mining, News, Predictive Ana-
lytics
AppBridge 2017 Apps, Data Storage, Google
Crashlytics 2017 Android, iOS, Mobile, SaaS
Fabric 2017 Cloud Infrastructure, Developer APIs, Developer Tools, En-
terprise Software, Mobile Apps, Real Time
Limes Audio 2017 Audio, Communication Hardware, Telecommunications
Cronologics 2016 Hardware, Software, Wearables
LeapDroid 2016 Software
Qwiklabs 2016 Cloud Computing, Information Technology, Software
FameBit 2016 Internet, Music, Video
Eyefluence 2016 Consumer Electronics, Manufacturing, Wearables
Apigee 2016 Cloud Data Services, Enterprise Software, Information
Technology
625,000,000
Urban Engines 2016 Analytics, Big Data, GovTech, Mobile, Software, Transpor-
tation
Api.ai 2016 Natural Language Processing, Voice Recognition
Orbitera 2016 Analytics, Cloud Computing, E-Commerce, Marketing Au-
tomation, SaaS, Software
100,000,000
Apportable 2016 Developer Tools, Enterprise Software, Mobile, iOS
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00357 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6602 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
352
Google
Company Year Acquired Categories
Acquisition Value
(USD)
Moodstocks 2016 Artificial Intelligence, Hardware, Image Recognition, Ma-
chine Learning, Mobile, QR Codes, Real Time, Visual
Search
Anvato 2016 Software, Video Conferencing, Video Streaming
Kifi 2016 Analytics, Artificial Intelligence, Big Data, Content Dis-
covery, Knowledge Management
LaunchKit 2016 Developer Tools, Mobile Apps
Webpass 2016 Internet, ISP, Wireless
Synergyse 2016 Apps, Search Engine, Software, Training
BandPage 2016 Consumer, Facebook, Marketplace, Music
Pie 2016 Automotive, Incubators
Fly Labs 2015 iOS
Bebop 2015 Business Development, Enterprise, Enterprise Software 380,000,000
Digisfera 2015 Images
Oyster 2015 Email, Web Design, Web Hosting
Jibe Mobile 2015 File Sharing, Messaging, Mobile, Social Media
Pixate 2015 Computer, Enterprise Software, Mobile
Timeful 2015 Analytics, Artificial Intelligence, Database, Machine
Learning, Task Management
Pulse.io 2015 Apps, Mobile
Thrive Audio 2015 Audio, 3D Technology
Skillman & Hackett 2015 Software, Virtual Reality
Launchpad Toys 2015 Apps, Education, iOS
Odysee 2015 Enterprise Software, Mobile Apps, Photo Sharing
Softcard 2015 Apps, Mobile Payments
Red Hot Labs 2015 Advertising Platforms, Apps, Mobile, Software
Granata Decision
Systems
2015 Analytics, Artificial Intelligence, Machine Learning
Vidmaker 2014 Collaboration, Social Media, Video
Lumedyne Tech-
nologies
2014 Consumer Electronics, Information Technology, Semi-
conductors
RelativeWave 2014 Apps, Developer Tools
Agawi 2014 EdTech, Gaming, Mobile Apps, Mobile Devices
Firebase 2014 Cloud Infrastructure, Developer APIs, Developer Tools, En-
terprise Software, Mobile Apps, Real Time
Dark Blue Labs 2014 Artificial Intelligence, Data Visualization, Machine Learn-
ing
Vision Factory 2014 Artificial Intelligence, Computer Vision, Machine Learning,
Search Engine, Software
Revolv 2014 Internet of Things, Smart Home, Software
Lift Labs 2014 Hardware, Health Care, Medical, Software
Polar 2014 Fitness, Health Care, Wearables
Skybox Imaging 2014 Cloud Security, Cyber Security, Enterprise Software, Net-
work Security, Security, Software
500,000,000
Emu 2014 E-Commerce
Directr 2014 Energy, Solar
Jetpac 2014 AI, ML
Gecko Design 2014 Product Design
Zync Render 2014 Digital Media, Flash Storage, Social Media
Dropcam 2014 Consumer Electronics, Hardware, SaaS 555,000,000
Songza 2014 Music
DrawElements 2014 Enterprise Software
mDialog 2014 Advertising, Information Technology, Video Streaming
Aplental Tech-
nologies
2014 Information Technology, Wireless
Baarzo 2014 Video, Search
Appurify 2014 Android, Apps, iOS, Mobile, Test and Measurement
Rangespan 2014 Analytics, E-Commerce, Supply Chain Management
Adometry 2014 Advertising, Analytics, SaaS
Appetas 2014 Network Security, Restaurants, SaaS
Stackdriver 2014 Apps, Cloud Computing, Enterprise Software, Infrastruc-
ture
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00358 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6602 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
353
Google
Company Year Acquired Categories
Acquisition Value
(USD)
Quest Visual 2014 Data Visualization, iOS, Software
Gridcentric 2014 Software, Virtualization
Divide 2014 Enterprise Software, Information Technology, Mobile,
SaaS, Software
Titan Aerospace 2014 Aerospace, Manufacturing
GreenThrottle 2014 Console Games, Consumer Electronics, Mobile
Nest Labs 2014 Sensor, Manufacturing, Smart Home 3,200,000,000
SlickLogin 2014 Mobile, Mobile Apps, Security
Spider.io 2014 Advertising, Analytics, Fraud Detection, Internet, Security
Bitspin 2014 Apps, Web Development
Impermium 2014 Security
DeepMind Tech-
nologies
2014 AI, ML 500,000,000
Flutter 2013 Content, Software 40,000,000
FlexyCore 2013 Software 23,000,000
Calico 2013 Biotech, Genetics, Health Care
Bump 2013 Mobile, Contact Sharing
WIMM Labs 2012 Hardware, Software, Wearables
Waze 2013 Mobile Apps, Navigation, Transportation 966,000,000
Makani Power 2013 Energy
MyEnergy 2013 Clean Energy, Energy Efficiency
Behavio 2013 Software
Wavii 2013 ML, AI 30,000,000
Channel Intelligence 2013 Manufacturing, Product Search, Shopping 125,000,000
DNNresearch 2013 AI
Talaria Technologies 2013 Software, Web Design, Web Development
Schaft 2013 Hardware, Robotics
Industrial Perception 2013 AI
Redwood Robotics 2013 Robotics
Meka Robotics 2013 Robotics
Holomni 2013 Mobile, Robots
Bot & Dolly 2013 Software, Robotics
Autofuss 2013 Product Design
Incentive Targeting 2012 Public Relations, Retail
BufferBox 2012 E-Commerce, Marketplace, Shopping 17,000,000
Viewdle 2012 Analytics, Augmented Reality, Computer Vision, Mobile,
Facial Recognition
45,000,000
VirusTotal.com 2012 Security
Nik Software 2012 Image Recognition, Software
Sparrow 2012 Email, Messaging 25,000,000
Wildfire Interactive 2012 Consulting, Content, Data Integration, Developer Tools 450,000,000
Cuban Council 2012 Consulting, Consumer Electronics, Search Engine
Meebo 2012 Internet, Messaging, Web Development 100,000,000
Quickoffice 2012 Enterprise Software, iOS, Mobile
TxVia 2012 Finance, FinTech, Mobile, PaaS
Milk, Inc 2012 Apps, Mobile, Software
RightsFlow 2011 Accounting, Music, Legal
Clever Sense 2011 ML, AI
Apture 2011 Advertising
Katango 2011 Social Media
Anthony’s Robots 2011 Autonomous Vehicles
510 Systems 2011 Autonomous Vehicles, Software
SocialGrapple 2011 Analytics, Social Media
Zave Networks 2011 Apps, Mobile
Zagat 2011 Consumer Reviews 151,000,000
DailyDeal 2011 Beauty, Shopping 114,000,000
Dealmap 2011 Coupons, Local, Mobile, Search Engine, Social Media
Motorola Mobility 2011 Mobile Apps 12,500,000,000
Punchd 2011 Android, iOS, Loyalty Programs, Mobile
Fridge 2011 Photo Sharing
PittPatt 2011 Facial Recognition
PostRank 2011 Analytics, Social Media, Test and Measurement
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00359 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6602 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
354
Google
Company Year Acquired Categories
Acquisition Value
(USD)
Admeld 2011 Advertising, Auctions, Software 400,000,000
SageTV 2011 Digital Entertainment, Events, Media and Entertainment
Modu 2011 Mobile, Telecommunications, Wireless
Sparkbuy 2011 Consumer Electronics, E-Commerce, Shopping
PushLife 2011 Digital Media, E-Commerce, Mobile 25,000,000
ITA Software 2011 Information Technology 676,000,000
TalkBin 2011 Messaging
BeatThatQuote.com 2011 Auto Insurance, E-Commerce, Price Comparison 65,000,000
Next New Networks 2011 Video, Video Streaming
Green Parrot Pic-
tures
2011 Digital Media, Enterprise Software, Video
Zynamics 2011 Security
eBook Technologies 2011 Content, E-Books
SayNow 2011 Messaging, Social Network, Telecommunications
Phonetic Arts 2010 Software
Widevine Tech-
nologies
2010 Digital Entertainment, Digital Media, Video
Zetawire 2010 Mobile Payments, NFC
BlindType 2010 Mobile
Plannr 2010 Mobile
Quiksee 2010 Digital Media 10,000,000
MentorWave Tech-
nologies
2010 Software, 3D Visualization
Slide.com 2010 Developer Tools, Software 228,000,000
Jambool 2010 Apps, Internet 70,000,000
Like.com 2010 Image Recognition 100,000,000
Angstro 2010 Enterprise Software, Facebook, Social Network
SocialDeck 2010 Mobile, Social Website
Metaweb 2010 Database, Infrastructure
Invite Media 2010 Advertising 81,000,000
Instantiations 2010 Software
Global IP Solutions 2010 Software 68,200,000
Simplify Media 2010 Digital Entertainment, Digital Media, Mobile
Ruba.com 2010 Guides, Internet
PinkArt 2010 Software
Agnilux 2010 Hardware
LabPixies 2010 Software
BumpTop 2010 Software 30,000,000
Picnik 2010 Photosharing
DocVerse 2010 Document Management 25,000,000
Episodic 2010 Broadcasting, Internet
reMail 2010 Email, Messaging, Mobile Apps
Aardvark 2010 Internet, Search Engine, Social 50,000,000
AdMob 2009 Ad Network, Advertising, Apps, Marketing, Mobile 750,000,000
Gizmo5 2009 Public Relations, VoIP 30,000,000
Teracent 2009 Advertising, Machine Learning
AppJet 2009 Software, Web Development
reCAPTCHA 2009 Security
On2 2009 Content, Internet, SaaS, Software, Video 133,000,000
Eluceon Research 2009 Internet, Software
TNC 2008 Google, Web Browsers, Web Hosting
Begun 2008 Advertising
Omnisio 2008 File Sharing, Video 15,000,000
Jaiku 2007 Mobile
Zingku 2007 Digital Media, Social Media, Social Network
Postini 2007 Cyber Security, Internet, Security 625,000,000
ImageAmerica 2007 Software, Document Scanning
FeedBurner 2007 Blogging Platforms, Internet, Podcast 100,000,000
PeakStream 2007 Apps, Developer APIs, GPU, Software
Zenter 2007 Content, E-Commerce, Web Hosting
GrandCentral 2007 Mobile, Telecommunications, VoIP 45,000,000
GreenBorder 2007 Computer, Internet, Software
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00360 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6602 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
355
Google
Company Year Acquired Categories
Acquisition Value
(USD)
Panoramio 2007 Photo Sharing, Photography, Social Media
Crusix 2007 Social Networking
DoubleClick 2007 Advertising 3,100,000,000
Tonic Systems 2007 Web Development
Marratech 2007 Software, Video Conferencing 15,000,000
Trendalyzer 2007 Visual Statistics, Data Visualization, Software
Adscape 2007 Advertising, Digital Media, Marketing 23,000,000
Endoxon 2006 Information Technology 28,000,000
JotSpot 2006 Collaboration, Enterprise Software, Software
YouTube 2006 Internet, Music, Video 1,650,000,000
Neven Vision 2006 Software
2Web Technologies 2006 Software
Orion 2006 Content, Search Engine, Web Hosting
Upstartle 2006 Software
@Last Software 2006 3D Technology, Developer Tools
Measure Map 2006 Advertising, Analytics, Big Data
dMarc Broadcasting 2006 Advertising, Advertising Platforms, Internet Radio 102,000,000
Phatbits 2005 XML Desktop Applications
allPAY GmbH 2005 Mobile
bruNET GmbH 2005 Digital Entertainment, Social Media
Skia 2005 Graphic Design
Akwan Information
Technologies
2005 Information Technology, IT Management, Search Engine
Android 2005 Linux, Mobile, Search Engine 50,000,000
Reqwireless 2005 Wireless
Dodgeball 2005 Mobile Devices, Software
Urchin Software Cor-
poration
2005 Software
Where 2 Tech-
nologies
2004 Software
Keyhole 2004 Geospatial, Software
ZipDash 2004 Automotive, E-Commerce, Mobile, Real Time, Travel
Picasa 2004 Photos, Photo Editing
Ignite Logic 2004 Internet, Software, Web Design
Sprinks 2003 Online Advertising
Genius Labs 2003 Developer APIs, Developer Tools, Software
Neotonic Software 2003 CRM, Software
Applied Semantics 2003 Developer APIs, Enterprise Software, Mobile Apps 102,000,000
Kaltix 2003 SEO, Web Hosting
Pyra Labs 2003 Blogging Platforms, Developer APIs, Developer Tools, En-
terprise Software, Project Management, Social Media
Outride 2001 Energy, Information Technology, Online Portals
Deja 2001 Information Technology, Internet, Web Development
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00361 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6602 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00362 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6602 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
VIII. APPENDIX: ADDITIONAL VIEWS OF
MEMBERS OF JUDICIARY COMMITTEE
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00363 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6601 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
358
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00364 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6601 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 1 here 47165.001
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
359
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00365 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6601 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 2 here 47165.002
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
360
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00366 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6601 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 3 here 47165.003
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
361
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00367 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6601 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 4 here 47165.004
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
362
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00368 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6601 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 5 here 47165.005
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
363
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00369 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6601 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 6 here 47165.006
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS
364
VerDate Sep 11 2014 03:38 Jul 02, 2022 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00370 Fmt 6601 Sfmt 6601 C:\HSE JACKETS\47832.TXT FRAN
Insert offset folio 7 here 47165.007
JDEMLAPTOP22 with LOCATORS